• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Institut für Höhere Studien (IHS), Wien Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Aktie "Institut für Höhere Studien (IHS), Wien Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna"

Copied!
43
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Institut für Höhere Studien (IHS), Wien Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna

Reihe Transformationsökonomie / Transition Economics Series No. 13

Inflation, Growth, and Credit Services

Max Gillman, Michal Kejak, Ákos Valentinyi

(2)
(3)

Inflation, Growth, and Credit Services

Max Gillman, Michal Kejak, Ákos Valentinyi

Reihe Transformationsökonomie / Transition Economics Series

*)

No. 13 December 1999

Institut für Höhere Studien Stumpergasse 56, A-1060 Wien Fax: +43/1/599 91-163 Max Gillman

Department of Economics Central European University Nador ut. 9

H-1051 Budapest, HUNGARY Phone: +36/1/327-3227 Fax: +36/1/327-3232 E-mail: Gillman@ceu.hu Michal Kejak

CERGE-EI Politickych veznu 7

CZ-111 21 Prague 1, CZECH REPUBLIC Phone: +420/2/24005-186

Fax: +420/2/2422-7143 E-mail: Michal.Kejak@cerge.cuni.cz and

Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna Ákos Valentinyi

Department of Economics

University of Southampton & CEPR Highfield

Southampton SO17 1 BJ, UNITED KINGDOM Phone: +44/1703-595000

Fax: +44/1703-593939 E-mail: A.Valentinyi@soton.ac.uk

Institut für Höhere Studien (IHS), Wien

Institute for Advanced Studies, Vienna

(4)

The Institute for Advanced Studies in Vienna is an independent center of postgraduate training and

research in the social sciences. The publication of working papers does not imply a transfer of

copyright. The authors are fully responsible for the content.

(5)

Abstract

The empirical evidence suggests that there is a significant, negative relationship between inflation and economic growth. Conventional monetary growth models, however, predict a significantly smaller growth effect. This paper proposes a monetary growth model with an explicit credit service sector to explain the observed magnitude. Since credit services are assumed costly to produce, the consumers equate the opportunity cost of holding money with the marginal cost of credit. Therefore the technology of the financial sector influences the velocity of money, and consequently, how inflation affects leisure, the time spent accumulat- ing human capital, and the growth rate of output. The calibration shows that the model generates an inflation-growth effect whose magnitude falls in the range found by the empiri- cal studies. Moreover, in contrast to previous works, we are also able to explain an inflation- growth effect that becomes increasingly weak as the inflation rate rises, as the evidence seems to suggest.

Keywords

Economic growth, inflation, costly credit

JEL Classifications

O11, E31

(6)

Comments

We are grateful to participants at the 1999 Midwest Spring Macroeconomics Conference at seminars

at the three affiliate institutions of the authors, and Andreas W` rg` tter and Michal Pakos for helpful

comments, and to Krisztina Molnár for excellent research assistance. The first two authors kindly

acknowledge support from the Institute for Advanced Studies in Vienna, and the last author from the

European Union's Phare ACE programme 1996, P96-6158-R.

(7)

Contents

1. Introduction 1

2. Inflation and Growth: Evidence and Theory 2 3. Economic Environment 7

4. Balanced Growth Path 9

4.1 Competitive Equilibrium 9

4.2 Credit Services and Money Demand 11

5. Balanced Growth Path: The Log-utility Case 12

5.1 Consumption, Leisure, and the Growth Effect of Inflation 13 5.2 Interest Elasticity and the Growth Effect of Inflation 15

5.3 The Welfare Cost of Inflation and the Cost of Credit Services 18

6. Calibration 20

7. Conclusions and Qualifications 23

Appendix A: Equivalence of Explicit and Implicit Banking Sectors 26

Appendix B: The Existence of the Balanced-growth Equilibrium 29

References 32

(8)

The empirical research on the relationship between ination and growth suggests that

there is a systematic,signicant, negative association between inationand growth. Al-

thoughtheestimates varyacrossdierentstudies,ithas beenfound thata10percentage

point increase in the average ination rate results in a decrease in the average growth

rate of somewhere between 0.2 and 0.7 percentage point, [see Chari, Jones and Manuelli

(1996)]. In contrast, existing monetary models of endogenous growth predict a signif-

icantly smaller eect of ination on long run growth. Furthermore, there is also some

evidence that the eect of inationonlong run growth isnon-linear. More precisely,the

marginal eect of ination on the growth rate appears to be decreasing with the rate of

ination. In contrast, the growth eect of ination in existing models is either close to

linear,oritsmarginaleect isincreasingwith ination. Inparticular,thereisnoobvious

mechanism in most of these models which would generate the type of non-linearity one

can nd in the data.

This paper presents a plausible mechanism that ensures that monetary policy and

hence ination aects economic growth, and the predicted eect is consistent with the

data. We build an endogenous growth model where human capital accumulation is the

engineofgrowth,and bothmoney andcreditservicesfacilitatetransactions. The novelty

ofourapproachisthatweincorporateasectorwhichsuppliescreditservicesusingalabor

input. Consequently, the consumer's demand for money and credit services depends on

their relative price. As ination rises, the consumer substitutes away from money to

credit and faces an increased cost of credit service production. This induces a lower

accumulation rate of human capital, and a stronger substitution towards leisure than

in standard monetary models of endogenous growth. We show that this eect becomes

weaker asinationrisesexplainingthenon-linearfeature ofthegrowth eectofination.

For example, a standard cash-in-advance economy lacks any balance of the marginal

exchange costs. Given a xed nominalinterest rate for the marginalcost of money, such

(9)

Aiyagari, Braunand Eckstein (1998),Bogacheva (1999a),and in our model. This added

margin iscrucial toexplain the empiricalndingsonination and growth.

OurmodelissimilartoGillmanandOtto(1998),butextended toendogenousgrowth

as in Lucas (1988) without physical capital. It lacks the cumbersomeness of a store

continuum as in Prescott (1987) and Gillman (1993), and the xity of the credit good

as in Schreft (1992) who derives the division into cash and credit goods external to

the optimization problem. Aiyagari et al. (1998) also build a banking sector implicitly

into a neoclassical growth modelto exploit the relative exchange cost feature to explain

comovementbetweentheinationrate andhoursworkedinbankingandination. Bansil

and ColemanII (1996) use such variable velocity toexplain the magnitude of the equity

premiuminpartbyhavinggovernmentbondsdemandedaccordingtothe useofexchange

credit, thereby loweringthe risk-freereal interest.

1

Therestofthepaperisorganizedasfollows. Section2reviewstheempiricalliterature

oninationand growth, presentssomedescriptivestatisticsforthe OECDcountries,and

confrontstheevidencewiththetheoreticalndings. Section3outlinesthemodel. Section

4 derivesthe conditions for the balanced growth path. Section5 discusses the log-utility

case inmore detailto obtain some insights fromanalytical solutions. Section 6 presents

the numericalresults,and section7 concludes.

2 Ination and Growth: Evidence and Theory

There is a large body of literature which investigates the empiricalrelationship between

ination and growth. In their well-known paper Kormendi and Meguire (1985)report a

negativerelationshipbetweeninationandeconomicgrowthinacrosssectionofcountries.

De Gregorio(1992, 1993) nds, in a panel using 6-year average data, that a reduction

1

Bogacheva (1999b) uses the approach to explain 9-12 month forward exchange rates better than

randomwalkmodels.

(10)

increaseinthegrowthrateofoutput. Similarly,Fischer(1991,1993)estimates withcross-

sectionalandpaneldatathata10percentagepointincreaseintheinationratedecreases

the growth rate by between 0.3 and 0.4 percentage point.

2

Using various instrumental

variablesonapaneloftenyearaverages,Barro(1996,1997)concludesthata10percentage

point increase in the ination rate lowers the economic growth by 0.2 to 0.3 percentage

point.

3

The negativeeect of ination ongrowth alsoappears to berobust to choices of

alternative policy indicators.

There is also evidence that the growth eect of ination weakens at higher ination

rate. Fischer(1993)dividescountriesintothreegroupsaccordingtotheiraverageination

rate, between 0 and 15 percent, 15 and 40 percent, and above 40 percent, he nds an

increase in the ination rate by 10 percentage point associated with decreases in the

growth rate of 1.3 percentage point, 0.75 percentage point, and 0.19 percentage point.

AlsoBarro(1997)andBrunoandEasterly (1998)bothreportthatcountrieswith annual

ination above 40% grow signicantly lower than countries with ination rates below

40%. This can also be viewed as an indication that the eect of ination on growth is

non-linear.

We also calculated some simple descriptive statistics about the relationship between

inationand growthforthe24OECDcountries forthe period1951-1997.

4

Figure1plots

the average log of inationagainst the average growth rate where averages are taken for

each year separately across all countries. The line with a slope of 0:134 indicates a

negativerelationship between inationand growth. Moreover, since weregressed the log

ofinationongrowth,theobtainedrelationshipisnon-linear. Itshouldalsobementioned

that the coeÆcient issignicantfor logof inationwhile itisnot signicant forination

implyingthattherelationshipbetweeninationandgrowthismorelikelytobenon-linear

2

Thisresultisverycloseto thoseofRoubiniand Sala-i-Martin(1992).

3

SeealsoAndres,Domenech andMolinas(1996),GhoshandPhillips(1998),andGylfasonandHer-

bertson(1996)forresults.

4

ThesourceofthedataisIMFInternationalFinancialStatistics.

(11)

Logofination

Growthrate

b

b bb

b

bb

b bbb

b b b

b b b b b

b

b b

b

b

b b

b b

b

b b b

b b b b b b

b b

b bb bb b b

0 0.05 0.10 0.15

0 0.02 0.04 0.06 0.08

Note: EachpointrepresentstheOECDaverageforagivenyear

than linear.

The next group of statistics indicates that the non-linearity of the growth eect of

ination is robust. We divide the sample period into sub-periods according to whether

the average ination in the OECD countries was increasing or decreasing.

5

In addition,

the countries are grouped into three categories by the average of the maximum ination

reached by each country over the sub-period. Figure 2 displays the value of the average

growth/average ination where the average is taken across countries and across time

within each sub-period.

6

The average growth rate per unit of average ination tends to

fall as ination rises to the next category, and this fall usually occurs with a decreasing

magnitude. This indicates both that ination-growth relationship is negative and that

the relationship is weaker at a higher rate of ination. It is also important to note

that the correlation between ination and growth is 0:30 for all increasing periods of

ination,anditis 0:23foralldecreasingperiods. Thissuggeststhattheination-growth

relationship tends tobestronger inperiods ofrising ination.

5

Asub-periodisdenedbyyearsofanearlymonotonicallyrisingordecliningaverageOECDination

rate. Inchoosingsub-periods,weallowaoneyearreverse-directionchangeintheaverageOECDination

rateoflessthan1%tobeincludedinasub-period.

6

Theresultsarerobustforarangeofalternativespecicationshowsub-periodsarebuiltandaverages

aretaken.

(12)

Periodsofdecreasinginationrate Periodsofincreasinginationrate

0 0.5 1.0 1.5

0 5 5 10 over10

Growth/ination

1951 1953

Maximumination

1 4 7

0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0

0 5 5 10 over10

Growth/ination

1953 1956

Maximumination

10 4 1

0 0.5 1.0 1.5

0 5 5 10 over10

Growth/ination

1956 1959

Maximumination

12 3 1

0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0

0 5 5 10 over10

Growth/ination

1959 1974

Maximumination

5 18

0 0.5 1.0 1.5

0 5 5 10 over10

Growth/ination

1974 1978

Maximumination

3 20

0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0

0 5 5 10 over10

Growth/ination

1978 1980

Maximumination

1 5 17

0 0.5 1.0 1.5

0 5 5 10 over10

Growth/ination

1980 1988

Maximumination

6 17

0 0.5 1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5 3.0 3.5 4.0

0 5 5 10 over10

Growth/ination

1988 1990

Maximumination

9 11 3

0 0.5 1.0 1.5

0 5 5 10 over10

Growth/ination

1990 1997

Maximumination

9 11 3

Note: Thenumbersineachcolumnindicate thenumberofobservations.

(13)

ative relationshipbetween inationand growth. Thereare many monetarygrowth mod-

els which are able to replicatethe eect qualitatively [see for exampleDe Gregorio(1992,

1993), and Roubini and Sala-i-Martin (1992)]. However, these models fail to generate

the same eect quantitatively. In particular, they generate substantially weaker growth

eect of ination. Forexample, Gomme(1993), with astochastic two-sector endogenous

growth model with elastic labor supply, human capital, and money, reports a 10.5 per-

centage point per quarter increase in ination lowers the growth rate by 0.2 percentage

pointperyear. Charietal.(1996)assess thequantitativeperformanceofanumberofen-

dogenousgrowthmodels,andconcludethatnoneareabletomatchthedataevenclosely.

7

They introduce a nancial intermediary that faces reserve requirements, and match the

data if both the growth rate of the money supply and the reserve ratio are increased at

the same time. However, as noted by Stockman (1996) in his comment on the paper,

noevidence supports sucha simultaneous changein thepolicyvariables. Moreover, they

have also to rely on a rather high labor supply elasticity to obtain the desired growth

eect.

It is alsoimportant to emphasize that there is no mechanism in most of the models

which ensures the type of non-linearity we observe inthe data. In particular, the mech-

anism in several models generate a relationship between ination and growth which is

close tolinear [for example, De Gregorio(1993), and Chari et al.(1996)], or the growth

eect of ination becomes stronger at a higher rate of ination [for example Jones and

Manuelli(1995)].

7

Thegrowtheect ofinationisalsoweekin DotseyandIreland(1996),Wu andZhang(1998). Itis

higherthaninothermodelsin Loveand Wen(1999),however,itisstillbelow0.2percentagepoint.

(14)

The representative consumer maximizesthe present value of momentaryutilitiesdened

over consumptionc

t

, and leisure x

t

U = Z

1

0 e

t (c

t x

t )

1

1

dt: (1)

It is assumed that consumption purchases can be nanced either by using money or

by usingcreditservices. Leta

t

2(0;1]bethe fractionofconsumptiongoodsboughtwith

money at time t. Then the consumer faces the cash-in-advance constraint M

t

= a

t p

t c

t

where M

t

is the money holdingsof the consumer and p

t

is the price levelat time t. The

cash-in-advance constraint in real terms can be writtenas

m

t

=a

t c

t

; (2)

where m

t

M

t

=p

t

. Note that the fraction of consumption nanced with money corre-

sponds to the inverse velocity of money.

The fraction 1 a

t

of consumption goods is nanced using credit services. These

services are produced with the technology

1 a

t

=

b

t h

t

c

t

>0; 2(0;1); (3)

where is a productivity parameter, and b

t

is the time spent producing credit services.

The assumption underlyingthis technology is that the ow of creditservices required to

buy a fraction (1 a

t

) of the consumption goodsis increasing inthe eective laborb

t h

t

relativetothe levelofconsumption. Moreover, itisassumedthatforagivenconsumption

level c

t

, the consumer as \banker" faces increasing marginal costs when increasing the

proportion of goodsthat are boughtwith credit. This is modeled by having diminishing

returnstotheeectivelaborinproducingthecreditshare(1 a

t

),thus 2(0;1)whichis

(15)

that,inaddition,tothewage,theconsumerastheproducerofcreditservicesalsoreceives

areturnonthisactivity. Inparticular,afractionoftheincomeowtothecreditservice

production can be viewed aswage income while a fraction (1 ) can be viewed as the

return tothe producer of credit services.

8

The consumptiongoodis producedwith a constant returnsto scale technology

c

t

=wh

t l

t

(4)

where w denotes the marginal product of human capital in goods production, h

t is the

stock of humancapital, and l

t

is the amountof time spent working in goodsproduction.

The consumer's budget constraintin real terms can be writtenas

_ m

t

=wh

t l

t +v

t c

t

t m

t

; (5)

where m

t

M

t

=p

t

denotes real balances, v

t V

t

=p

t

is the lump-sum money transfer

from the government in real terms, and

t p_

t

=p

t

is the rate of ination. The budget

constraintstatesthatthe incomefromeectivelaborandthelump-sumtransferfromthe

governmentisspentonconsumption,onosettingtheeect of inationonrealbalances,

and on the accumulation of real balances.

Theaccumulationofhumancapitaldependsonthetimespentinaccumulatinghuman

capital, on the level of human capital, and onthe rate of depreciation of human capital

in alinear fashion

_

h

t

=[1 l

t x

t b

t ]h

t Æh

t

; >0 Æ>0 (6)

8

AppendixAshowsformallythetotalwagebillinthesectorproducingcreditservicesisR

t (1 a

t )c

t

whiletheprotis(1 )R

t (1 a

t )c

t

whereR

t

isthenominalinterestratewhichequalstheequilibrium

relativepriceofcreditservicesintermsoftheconsumptiongoods.

(16)

1 l

t x

t b

t

is the study time,i.e. the time devoted to human capitalaccumulation.

Finally, to close the model, we assume that the government prints money at rate

=

_

M

t

=M

t

, and it uses the revenues from money creation to nance the lump-sum

transfer V

t

to the consumer, thus, V

t

=M

t , orv

t

=m

t

inreal terms.

4 Balanced Growth Path

4.1 Competitive Equilibrium

Undertheassumptionthattheconsumeroperatesalltechnologiesdirectly,wecansimplify

the consumer's problem. Let

~

~

b(a

t )

1 a

t

1

: (7)

Inspecting equation (3) reveals that this is the eective labor per unit of consumption

required to nance a fraction 1 a

t

of the consumption goods with credit services. Put

dierently, this is the cost function in the credit service sector. Now the time spent in

producing creditservices, b

t

, can be writtenas

b

t

=

~

~

b(a

t )

c

t

h

t

: (8)

Usingthis equation,we can now rewritethe lawof motion for human capital(6) as

_

h

t

=

1 l

t x

t

~

~

b(a

t )

c

t

h

t

h

t Æh

t

; >0 (6

0

)

The consumer chooses a consumption, credit service purchase, time allocation, real bal-

ances and human capital fc

t

;a

t

;x

t

;l

t

;m

t

;h

t g

1

t=0

, to maximize the life time utility (1)

subject to the cash-in-advance constraint (2), the budget constraint (5), the constraint

(17)

for the human capital accumulation (6), and the credit service technology (7).

The rst order conditions for the consumer's problem alongwith the constraints (2),

(5), (6 0

), (7)and the transversality condition, are

R

t

= w

1 a

t

1

1

(9a)

1

x

t

c

t

= 1+a

t R

t +w

~

~

b(a

t )

wh

t

(9b)

_ c

t

c

t

=

(1 x

t

) Æ

: (9c)

where R

t

isthe nominal interest rate dened by

R

t

(1 x

t

) Æ+

t

; (10)

where(1 x

t

) Æistherealinterestrate,i.e. thenetreturnonhumancapital.

9

Equation

(9a) equates the opportunity cost of holding money R

t

to the marginal cost of credit

services (similartoBaumol(1952)). Equation(9b) sets the marginalrateof substitution

between consumption and leisure time equalto the marginal cost of consumption tothe

marginalproductof workingtime. Notethatthecost ofoneunitofconsumptionconsists

oftheoneunitofresourcesrequiredfortheconsumptionitself,thecostofholdinga

t units

of money, a

t R

t

, and the cost of 1 a

t

units of credit services, w

~

~

b(a

t

), used to purchase

consumption. Equation(9c)isthestandardintertemporalEuler-equationfortheoptimal

consumption growth.

We focus on the competitive equilibrium along the balanced growth path which is a

pricefR

t g

1

t=0

,anallocationfc

t

;a

t

;x

t

;l

t

;m

t

;h

t g

1

t=0

,andasetofinitialconditionsfm

0

;h

0 g

such that given the price fR

t g

1

t=0

the allocation fc

t

;a

t

;x

t

;l

t

;m

t

;h

t g

1

t=0

solves the con-

sumer's problem, i.e it satises equations (2), (5), (6 0

), (7) and (9a)-(9c), the goods

9

ThebondmarketthatdeterminesR

t

asadeterministicFisherequationofinterestissuppressedfor

brevity.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

In einer soziologischen Variante der Argumentation des Job-Matching-An- satzes ( Sorensen, Kalleberg 1981) wird betont, dass das Zuordnungsproblem noch dadurch verschärft wird, dass

To mitigate the economic effects of the split, the Czech Republic and Slovakia retained their common currency, a customs union and a common labor market.. While the customs union

The example of Slovakia can be seen as an example for trade effects of the enlargement of the European Union by few associated countries on the ‘left-outs.’ The simulation of

(Interestingly, privatized and private firms are statistically indistinguishable from each other insofar as their willingness or propensity to repay is concerned.) These differences

A priori one might expect to find high separation and hiring rates in Moscow City where unemployment is relatively low and small business and private sector employment

We highlight the effects of preferential versus multilateral trade arrangements on the relative utilisation of skilled labour, unskilled labour, and capital.. This study adds

Results: In nine regions the regional administration supports foreign investment very well (zero points): in the Archangelsk Region, the Komi Republic, the Krasnoyarsk

This class of industrialized fast growing countries is described by high equipment investments, a high rate of liquid liabilities to GDP, a medium level of GDP in 1960, low levels