• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

A two-course Swiss menu: Corona and the debt brake

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Aktie "A two-course Swiss menu: Corona and the debt brake"

Copied!
33
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Research Collection

Presentation

A two-course Swiss menu: Corona and the debt brake

Author(s):

Sturm, Jan-Egbert Publication Date:

2020-12-14 Permanent Link:

https://doi.org/10.3929/ethz-b-000465777

Rights / License:

In Copyright - Non-Commercial Use Permitted

This page was generated automatically upon download from the ETH Zurich Research Collection. For more information please consult the Terms of use.

ETH Library

(2)

A two-course Swiss menu:

Corona and the Debt Brake

Prof. Dr. Jan-Egbert Sturm

Director KOF Swiss Economic Institute

14 December 2020

(3)

Prof. Dr. Jan-Egbert Sturm

Director KOF Swiss Economic Institute 14 December 2020

The Swiss Debt Brake

(4)

Public debt in Switzerland

Sources: EFV, BFS

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 Federal debt (% GDP w/o sports) Cantonal debt (% GDP w/o sports)

Municipal debt (% GDP w/o sports) Social insurance debt (% GDP w/o sports)

% GDP w/o sports

(5)

Background: Introduction of the Debt Brake

• The expansion of federal debt in 1990s

− Spending bias coupled with a pro-cyclical fiscal policy:

economic upturns not used for fiscal consolidation

− Raising federal revenues usually requires a constitutional amendment. Spending increases require only a simple majority vote in parliament

− W eak fiscal rule since 1959

• 1997: start of planning the introduction of the debt brake

− Structurally largely balanced budget as necessary condition for its introduction

− Budget target for 2001 was formulated in 1997

(temporary constitutional provision in 1998 referendum: 70.7% Yes)

• 2003: first application of the debt brake

− 2001 referendum: 84.7 % Yes

(6)

Design of the Swiss Federal Debt Brake

• Goals

1. Ensure medium- and long-term debt stabilization by avert (chronic) structural imbalances 2. Grant short-term countercyclical budget leeway

• Application

− The Swiss debt brake applies since 2003 to the ordinary budget.

Since 2010, extended to extraordinary income and expenditures but managed seperately

• Constitutional provision for the debt brake principles

− Strict implementation through the Financial Budget Act (FHG)

(7)

Features

1. Application only to the expenditure side

− The budget must be balanced given tax revenues subject to a business cycle correction

− Constitutional upper limits on main tax rates make it (almost) impossible to act on the revenue side

− No short-run economic impulses are intended to come from the expenditure side

− Tax revenues are supposed to act as automatic stabilizers 2. Management of surpluses and deficits

− Asymmetric management: Deficits and surpluses are treated differently

− Constitutional framework permits symmetrical management, but current law is more restrictive

− Parliament gave priority to debt reduction over spending increases or tax relief

− Deficits and surpluses are managed in the (notional) compensation account

− Surpluses cannot be used to increase the expenditure ceiling or to reduce taxes

− They thus lead to a reduction in debt

− A surplus in the compensation account is continued and there is no obligation to reduce it

− Balance in the compensation account increases also in case of systematic forecasting errors of

revenues, of the cyclical adjustment factor, and thus the maximum expenditure ceiling

(8)

The Federal Debt Brake Mechanism

• Rule: expenditure may not exceed receipts over an economic cycle. (Constitution)

− 𝐺 𝑡 ≤ 𝑘 𝑡 𝑇 𝑡 with 𝑘 𝑡 = 𝑌

𝑡

𝑌

𝑡

− A modified HP filter is used to calculate 𝑌 𝑡

− Tax revenues act as automatic stabilizers

• If actual expenditure differs from ceiling, this is charged to a (notional) compensation account

− Rule applied to budget forecasts and outcomes

− Second calculation determines what must be credited or debited in the compensation

account

− Deficits have to be eliminated in the following years - No rules are provided for surpluses

− The rule offers an escape clause for unexpected

situations and uncontrollable developments

(9)

Gross debt

Development Swiss central government debt, 1990-2019

Source: Federal Administration

0 25 50 75 100 125 150

90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 Level compensation account

Bln. CHF

0 5 10 15 20 25 30

Gross debt-to-GDP ratio (r.scale)

% GDP

(10)

Increasing balance in the compensation account

• Since 2006, the revenue growth was under- and the expenditure growth overestimated

• During the time period 2004-2019:

− Forecast errors for revenues explained 52% of the inflows

− whereof 44% were due to ‘Withholding Taxes’

− Forecast errors for expenditures 40%

• Are budget underruns a first-class problem?

− Systematic forecasting bias undermines the trust in the finance ministry’s forecasting abilities.

This might be detrimental in other contexts.

− From a division of power perspective, the budget authority of the parliament is undermined if forecast

errors have a systematic bias in favor of fiscal surpluses.

(11)

Budget underspending, 1994-2019

Source: Federal Administration

-2500 -2000 -1500 -1000 -500 0 500 1000

94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 Budget underspending Budget underspending (w/o interest payments and shares to third parties)

Mln. CHF

(12)

Expenditures: Difference budget and budget estimate

Ø 2004-2019 Ø 2007-2019 Ø 2004-2019 Ø 2007-2019

Ordinary expenditures 1’055 1’095 1.7% 1.7%

(621) (664) (1.0%) (1.0%)

Transfers' to third parties -194 -199 -2.5% -2.6%

(303) (333) (3.9%) (4.2%)

Interest expenditures 292 306 11.4% 12.7%

(337) (324) (13.3%) (13.6%)

Other ordinary expenditures 956 988 1.9% 1.9%

(373) (399) (0.7%) (0.8%)

thereof own expenditures 440 4.2%

(197) (1.8%)

% of the budget estimate

million CHF

(13)

Revenues: Difference budget and budget estimate

Ø 2004-2011 Ø 2012-2019 Ø 2004-2011 Ø 2012-2019

Ordinary revenues 2’504 267 4.4% 0.3%

(1’934) (1’469) (3.3%) (2.2%)

Withholding tax 1’338 973 43.4% 17.0%

(993) (797) (33.2%) (13.2%)

Other revenues 1’166 -706 2.2% -1.2%

(1’234) (1’212) (2.3%) (2.0%)

million CHF % of the budget estimate

(14)

Four reasons why budgets are not fully spend

1. Lower costs or lower demand

− Such estimation errors should be symmetrical and balanced in the medium to long term

− However, the last decade was marked by the financial crisis and franc shocks

− Interest rate, inflation and economic developments were (systematically) misjudged

(15)

Four reasons why budgets are not fully spend

1. Lower costs or lower demand 2. Shifts between fiscal years

− Article 36 FHG allows the Federal Council, in the case of delays, to transfer already granted credits to the following year

− However, this regulation presents a certain bureaucratic hurdle and may therefore not be fully exploited

− The new management model for the federal administration (NFB) allows administrative units to

create reserves that can be reused as credit overruns (introduced in 2017)

(16)

Four reasons why budgets are not fully spend

1. Lower costs or lower demand 2. Shifts between fiscal years 3. The precautionary motive

− Budgetary hurdles, or even social and cultural practices, can make it more costly for administrative units to undercut budgets

− Over-budgeting is used to cover unforeseen events or to avoid filing for supplementary credits

− Administrative units tend to (over-) cautiously budget (but also to use funds economically)

− In these situations, the effective expenditure is more likely to correspond to the social optimum than the tentatively carefully negotiated budget ceilings

− Reducing budget underspending then implies designing the “costs” of exceeding and falling short of the budget more symmetrically

− The introduction of global budgets under the NFB goes in this direction

(17)

Four reasons why budgets are not fully spend

1. Lower costs or lower demand 2. Shifts between fiscal years 3. The precautionary motive

4. The problem of the fiscal commons

− The political economy assumes that the administration is budget-maximizing

− Influence and prestige are positively related to the size of the budget

− All administrative units are competing for access to the common source of revenues

− The decisive factor is the institutional design of the budgetary process or the control mechanisms designed to prevent inefficient use of public funds

− For practical reasons, control mechanisms are more pronounced when budgets are spend than during the budgeting process. This should result in budget underspending.

− Global budgets and intertemporal transferability of budgets are likely to increase this problem

− Penalties for budget underspending, such as a budget cut in the following year or a strengthening

of the role of fiscal management in the budget process, could reduce such budget underspending

(but could increase the “December fever”).

(18)

The Corona Crisis

– a Swiss Perspective

(19)

COVID 19 pandemic: registered deaths worldwide - cumulative & daily (7-day average)

Source: Reuters

0 200,000 400,000 600,000 800,000 1,000,000 1,200,000 1,400,000 1,600,000 1,800,000

01.01 01.02 01.03 01.04 01.05 01.06 01.07 01.08 01.09 01.10 01.11 01.12 Persons

0

2,000

4,000

6,000

8,000

10,000

12,000

14,000

16,000

18,000

Persons

(20)

COVID 19 pandemic: registered deaths in Switzerland - cumulative & daily (7-day average)

Sourcce: Reuters

01.01 01.02 01.03 01.04 01.05 01.06 01.07 01.08 01.09 01.10 01.11 01.12 0

1,000 2,000 3,000 4,000 5,000

6,000 Persons

0 15 30 45 60 75 Per million persons 90

Persons Euroraum

(21)

Health-Wealth Trade-Off? Experiences from the first wave

Sources: Reuters, national statistical offices, Datastream. Circle size ~ Population size

-200 0 200 400 600 800 1,000

-35% -30% -25% -20% -15% -10% -5% 0% 5% 10%

co n fi rm ed d ea th s p er m ill io n p eo p le ( 31 /7 )

real GDP growth from previous year, 2020 Q2

Africa

Asia-Pacific

Europe

North and South America

Switzerland Australia Nigeria

South Africa

China

India Indonesia

Japan Austria

Belgium

France

Germany Italy

Netherlands

Portugal

Russia Spain

Sweden United Kingdom

Canada United States

Argentina

Colombia Mexico

Peru

Switzerland Denmark

(22)

Oxford Stringency Index

Source: Oxford

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

CH NL DE

(23)

KOF Stringency Index – cantonal differences

Source: KOF

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80

1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12

ag ai ar be bl bs fr ge gl gr ju lu ne nw

ow sg sh so sz tg ti ur vd vs zg zh ch

(24)

Variation of the reproduction rate in the cantons

Sources: NCS-TF, KOF

0.0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1.0 1.2 1.4 1.6

Mar Apr Jun Jul Aug Sep Okt Nov

RMAD CV

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8

RMSD

Variation measures Reproduction rate

Re (r.scale)

(25)

KOF Stringency-Plus Index

and Cantonal Differences in Reproduction Rates

Sources: NCS-TF, KOF

0 5 10 15 20 25 30

10 11

Below average Above average 0.5

0.8 1.0 1.3 1.5 1.8

2.0 Reproduction rate Re Number of Cantons

(26)

Comparison of Swiss GDP developments - financial versus corona crisis

Sources: Seco, KOF

140 145 150 155 160 165 170 175 180 185 190

2019 2020 2021 2022

Corona crisis

2.Lockdown (left scale)

-1.9

-7.3 6.8

-10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8

% 10 Billion (2017) CHF

140 145 150 155 160 165 170 175 180 185 190

2008 2009 2010 2011

Financial crisis

Level (left scale) Quarterly comparison (right scale)

-2.8 -1.6

0.6 1.1

-10 -8 -6 -4 -2 0 2 4 6 8

% 10

Billion (2017) CHF

(27)

A sector perspective for Switzerland

Source: KOF

-30 -25 -20 -15 -10 -5 0 5

A - Agriculture and forestry B- Mining C - Manufacturing industry D/E - Energy and water supply F - Construction G - Trade, repair trade H/J Transport and storage, information and communication

I - Hospitality industry K - Credit and insurance industry L/N/M - Real estate, bus.services, freelance, scientific & techn. servicesL

O - Public administration P - Education and teaching Q - Health and social services R/S/T - art, entertainment, private HH, other services

%-Difference compared to 2019

2020 versus 2019 2021 versus 2019

(28)

Swiss GDP per capita since 1949

Sources: BFS, KOF

20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90

49 51 53 55 57 59 61 63 65 67 69 71 73 75 77 79 81 83 85 87 89 91 93 95 97 99 01 03 05 07 09 11 13 15 17 19 21

thousand CHF

(29)

General government balance and fiscal stimulus against a counterfactual scenario

Source: KOF

-25 -20 -15 -10 -5 0 5 10 15 20 25 30

Counterfactual Baseline 2.Lockdown Baseline 2.Lockdown

General government balance Fiscal impulse relative to the counterfactual 3.9%

4.4%

2020

2.4%

3.1%

2021

1.0%

1.6%

2022

Bln. CHF

(30)

Quotes of the Finance Minister (Bundesrat Ueli Maurer)

• “Noch einmal ein 30 Milliarden Hilfspaket könne sich die Schweiz nicht leisten.”

24.10.2020

− “"Switzerland cannot afford another 30 billion aid package.”

• “Wir könnten dann mindestens einmal die Olympischen Spiele auf dem

Schuldenberg haben. Der wird so hoch das es dort sicher schneesicher ist.”

11.12.2020

− “We should then be able to have the Olympic Games on our debt mountain at least once.

It will be so high that snow is guaranteed there.”

(31)

Public debt in Switzerland

Sources: EFV, BFS, KOF

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50

2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 Federal debt (% GDP w/o sports) Cantonal debt (% GDP w/o sports)

Municipal debt (% GDP w/o sports) Social insurance debt (% GDP w/o sports)

% GDP w/o sports

(32)

General Government Debt in selected countries/regions

Source: IMF

0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140

2000-2004 2005-2009 2010-2014 2015-2019 20-24

United States European Union (EU27) Switzerland Developing Economies Netherlands

% of GDP

(33)

Concluding remarks

• Solid public finances at the beginning of the COVID-19 pandemic

• Estimated central government deficit for 2020: 21 billion (general government deficit: 25 billion)

− The law provides for a period of six years for the reduction of this debt

− The parliament can decide to extend the repayment period

• Current expert discussion

− Time period over which this extraordinary debt should be paid back

− Tax increases or acceptance of higher debt levels are hardly discussed despite -0,5% interest rate on short-term Swiss government bonds

− Budget underruns and forecasting errors will not be discussed (negatively) in the near future

• Strong support for the debt brake in the population

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

10 Despite these discrepancies, the future fourth financial framework for 2007-2013 is going to present major heading and investment distribution changes, but is still going to

The eurozone budget could thus be used as a carrot and/or a stick: either as ex ante financial support to help countries in crisis to carry out reforms (which often require

The executive budget process consists of three main phases: development of the President’s budget proposal, submission and justification of the President’s budget proposal,

 Services’ Share of the Budget: The budget request proposes a nominal increase in funding for the Army and decreases for the Navy and Air Force relative to current levels

This initiative improves, promotes and protects the health of New Zealanders by providing funding to maintain DHB services such as hospital care, mental health support, primary

Medarova (2012), “The implications for the EU and national budgets of the use of innovative financial instruments for the financing of EU policies and objectives”,

(ii) the rise in inflation will diminish the available inflation tax base for the government and the attempt on the part of the government to collect a given inflation tax revenue

Anahtar Kelimeler: Avrupa Birliği, Avrupa Birliği Bütçesi, Bütçe Revizyonu Future of The European Union Budget: Budget Review