• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

The Swiss Federal Debt Brake

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Aktie "The Swiss Federal Debt Brake"

Copied!
22
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Research Collection

Presentation

The Swiss Federal Debt Brake

Author(s):

Eichenauer, Vera; Sturm, Jan-Egbert Publication Date:

2020-12

Permanent Link:

https://doi.org/10.3929/ethz-b-000465776

Rights / License:

In Copyright - Non-Commercial Use Permitted

This page was generated automatically upon download from the ETH Zurich Research Collection. For more information please consult the Terms of use.

ETH Library

(2)

The Swiss Federal Debt Brake

Fiscal Sustainability Symposium

Vera Z. Eichenauer and Jan-Egbert Sturm

December 8, 2020

(3)

| December 8, 2020 |

Charles Koch Foundation 2

General Government Debt in selected countries/regions

Source: IMF

0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140

2000-2004 2005-2009 2010-2014 2015-2019 20-24

United States European Union (EU27) Switzerland Developing Economies

% of GDP

(4)

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50

20002001200220032004200520062007200820092010201120122013201420152016201720182019202020212022 Federal debt (% GDP w/o sports) Cantonal debt (% GDP w/o sports)

% GDP

(5)

|

|

 The expansion of federal debt in 1990s

Spending bias coupled with a pro-cyclical fiscal policy:

economic upturns not used for fiscal consolidation

Raising federal revenues usually requires a constitutional amendment. Spending increases require only a simple majority vote in parliament

Weak fiscal rule since 1959

 1997: start of planning the introduction of the debt brake

Structurally largely balanced budget as necessary condition for its introduction

Budget target for 2001 was formulated in 1997

(temporary constitutional provision in 1998 referendum: 70.7% Yes)

 2003: first application of the debt brake

2001 referendum: 84.7 % Yes

Charles Koch Foundation December 8, 2020 4

Background: Introduction of the Debt Brake

(6)

 Goals

1.

Ensure medium- and long-term debt stabilization by avert (chronic) structural imbalances

2.

Grant short-term countercyclical budget leeway

 Application

The Swiss debt brake applies since 2003 to the ordinary budget.

Since 2010, extended to extraordinary income and expenditures but managed seperately

 Constitutional provision for the debt brake principles

Strict implementation through the Financial Budget Act (FHG)

Design of the Swiss Federal Debt Brake

(7)

|

|

 The budget must be balanced given tax revenues subject to a business cycle correction

 Constitutional upper limits on the main tax rates make it (virtually) impossible to act on the revenue side

 No short-run economic impulses are intended to come from the expenditure side of the federal budget

Tax revenues are supposed to act as automatic stabilizers

Feature 1: Application only to the expenditure side

(8)

 Asymmetric management: Deficits and surpluses are treated differently

Constitutional framework permits symmetrical management, but current law is more restrictive

Parliament gave priority to debt reduction over spending increases or tax relief

 Deficits and surpluses are managed in the (notional) compensation account

Surpluses cannot be used to increase the expenditure ceiling or to reduce taxes

 They thus lead to a reduction in debt

A surplus in the compensation account is continued and the obligation to reduce the surplus does not apply

Balance in the compensation account increases also in case of systematic forecasting errors of revenues, of the cyclical adjustment factor, and thus the maximum expenditure ceiling

Feature 2: Management of surpluses and deficits

(9)

|

|

Rule: expenditure may not exceed receipts over an economic cycle. (Constitution)

 𝐺𝐺𝑡𝑡 ≤ 𝑘𝑘𝑡𝑡𝑇𝑇𝑡𝑡 with 𝑘𝑘𝑡𝑡 = 𝑌𝑌𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡

𝑡𝑡

A modified HP filter is used to calculate 𝑌𝑌𝑡𝑡

 Tax revenues act as automatic stabilizers

If actual expenditure differs from ceiling, this is charged to a (notional) compensation account

 Rule applied to budget forecasts and outcomes

Second calculation determines what must be credited or debited in the compensation account

 Deficits have to be eliminated in the following years - No rules are provided for surpluses

 The rule offers an escape clause for unexpected situations and uncontrollable developments

Charles Koch Foundation

The Federal Debt Brake Mechanism

(10)

 Extraordinary budget receipts and expenditures are subject to the debt brake since 2010

 Managed in the amortization account

 Shortfalls in the amortization account must normally be compensated within six financial years by means of surpluses in the ordinary budget

 In the event of foreseeable deficits in the amortization account,

the maximum amount of ordinary expenditure may be reduced as a precautionary measure

Extraordinary budget

(11)

| December 8, 2020 |

Charles Koch Foundation 10

Development Swiss central government debt, 1990-2016

Source: Federal Administration

0 5 10 15 20 25 30

0 25 50 75 100 125 150

90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 Gross debt Level compensation account Gross debt-to-GDP ratio (r.scale)

Bln. CHF % GDP

(12)

 Since 2006, the revenue growth was under- and the expenditure growth overestimated

 During the time period 2004-2019:

Forecast errors for revenues explained 52% of the inflows

 whereof 44% were due to ‘Withholding Taxes’

Forecast errors for expenditures 40%

 Are budget underruns a first-class problem?

Systematic forecasting bias undermines the trust in the finance ministry’s forecasting abilities.

This might be detrimental in other contexts.

From a division of power perspective, the budget authority of the parliament is undermined if forecast errors have a systematic bias in favor of fiscal surpluses.

Increasing balance in the compensation account

(13)

| December 8, 2020 |

Charles Koch Foundation 12

Budget underspending, 1994-2019

Source: Federal Administration

-2500 -2000 -1500 -1000 -500 0 500 1000

94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 Budget underspending Budget underspending (w/o interest payments and shares to third parties)

Mln. CHF

(14)

Expenditures: Difference budget and budget estimate

Ø 2004-2019 Ø 2007-2019 Ø 2004-2019 Ø 2007-2019

Ordinary expenditures 1’055 1’095 1.7% 1.7%

(621) (664) (1.0%) (1.0%)

Transfers' to third parties -194 -199 -2.5% -2.6%

(303) (333) (3.9%) (4.2%)

Interest expenditures 292 306 11.4% 12.7%

(337) (324) (13.3%) (13.6%)

Other ordinary expenditures 956 988 1.9% 1.9%

(373) (399) (0.7%) (0.8%)

thereof own expenditures 440 4.2%

(197) (1.8%)

% of the budget estimate

million CHF

(15)

| December 8, 2020 | Charles Koch Foundation

Revenues: Difference budget and budget estimate

Ø 2004-2011 Ø 2012-2019 Ø 2004-2011 Ø 2012-2019

Ordinary revenues 2’504 267 4.4% 0.3%

(1’934) (1’469) (3.3%) (2.2%)

Withholding tax 1’338 973 43.4% 17.0%

(993) (797) (33.2%) (13.2%)

Other revenues 1’166 -706 2.2% -1.2%

(1’234) (1’212) (2.3%) (2.0%)

million CHF % of the budget estimate

(16)

1. Lower costs or lower demand 2. Shifts between fiscal years 3. The precautionary motive

4. The problem of the fiscal commons

Reason why budgets are not fully spend

(17)

|

|

1. Lower costs or lower demand

Such estimation errors should be symmetrical and balanced in the medium to long term

However, the last decade was marked by the financial crisis and franc shocks

 Interest rate, inflation and economic developments were (systematically) misjudged

2. Shifts between fiscal years

Article 36 FHG allows the Federal Council, in the case of delays, to transfer already granted credits to the following year

However, this regulation presents a certain bureaucratic hurdle and may therefore not be fully exploited

The new management model for the federal administration (NFB) allows administrative units to create reserves that can be reused as credit overruns (introduced in 2017)

Reason why budgets are not fully spend

(18)

3. The precautionary motive

Budgetary hurdles, or even social and cultural practices, can make it more costly for administrative units to undercut budgets

Over-budgeting is used to cover unforeseen events or to avoid filing for supplementary credits

 Administrative units tend to (over-) cautiously budget (but also to use funds economically)

In these situations, the effective expenditure is more likely to correspond to the social optimum than the tentatively carefully negotiated budget ceilings

 Reducing budget underspending then implies designing the “costs” of exceeding and falling short of the budget more symmetrically

The introduction of global budgets under the NFB goes in this direction

Reason why budgets are not fully spend

(19)

|

|

4. The problem of the fiscal commons

The political economy assumes that the administration is budget-maximizing

 Influence and prestige are positively related to the size of the budget

 All administrative units are competing for access to the common source of revenues

There is an asymmetric distribution of spending and revenue responsibilities: inherent overuse of the budget

The decisive factor is the institutional design of the budgetary process or the control mechanisms designed to prevent inefficient use of public funds

 For practical reasons, control mechanisms are more pronounced when budgets are spend than during the budgeting process. This should result in budget underspending.

 Global budgets and intertemporal transferability of budgets are likely to increase this problem further

 Penalties for budget underspending, such as a budget cut in the following year or a strengthening of the role of fiscal management in the budget process, could reduce such budget underspending

(but could increase the “December fever”).

Reason why budgets are not fully spend

(20)

 Should unbudgeted surpluses be used to increase the expenditure ceiling?

The group of experts (in 2017) was opposed to such an approach

 It expected a significant reduction of future budget underruns

 Unclear whether a change in the debt brake will undermine the budget accuracy even more

 The confidence in and the effectiveness of the debt brake could be undermined

The expert group recommended waiting for the impact of administrative reforms (NFB, 2017)

 Introduction of global budgets will reduce the incentive to hand in budgets with safety margins

If adjustments were made (because underspending remains significant),

a correction on the revenue side would make more sense than on the expenditure side

Expert Report on Debt Brake

(21)

|

|

 Solid public finances at the beginning of the COVID-19 pandemic.

 Estimated deficit for 2020+2021: 20 billion

The law provides for a period of six years for the reduction of this debt

The parliament can decide to extend the repayment period

 Current expert discussion

Time period over which this extraordinary debt should be paid back

Tax increases or acceptance of higher debt levels are hardly discussed despite -0,5% interest rate on short-term Swiss government bonds

Budget underruns and forecasting errors will not be discussed (negatively) in the near future

 Strong support for the debt brake in the population

Concluding remarks

(22)

The Swiss Federal Debt Brake

Fiscal Sustainability Symposium

Vera Z. Eichenauer and Jan-Egbert Sturm

December 8, 2020

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

The eurozone budget could thus be used as a carrot and/or a stick: either as ex ante financial support to help countries in crisis to carry out reforms (which often require

The executive budget process consists of three main phases: development of the President’s budget proposal, submission and justification of the President’s budget proposal,

The federal government responded to financial turmoil with an extraordinary set of measures in 2008 and 2009, including two major economic stimulus measures and a variety of programs

 Services’ Share of the Budget: The budget request proposes a nominal increase in funding for the Army and decreases for the Navy and Air Force relative to current levels

10 Despite these discrepancies, the future fourth financial framework for 2007-2013 is going to present major heading and investment distribution changes, but is still going to

Anahtar Kelimeler: Avrupa Birliği, Avrupa Birliği Bütçesi, Bütçe Revizyonu Future of The European Union Budget: Budget Review

The state established for the tax liabilities represented by duties, taxes, rates and other state back finances including matching increase in tax and penalties for overdue

Medarova (2012), “The implications for the EU and national budgets of the use of innovative financial instruments for the financing of EU policies and objectives”,