• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Relational Contracts and Global Sourcing

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Relational Contracts and Global Sourcing"

Copied!
37
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

University of Tübingen Working Papers in Economics and Finance

No. 83

Relational Contracts and Global Sourcing

by

Bohdan Kukharskyy

Faculty of Economics and Social Sciences www.wiwi.uni-tuebingen.de

(2)

Relational Contracts and Global Sourcing

Bohdan Kukharskyy

Abstract

Relational contracts – informal agreements sustained by the value of future relationships – are integral parts of global production processes. This paper develops a repeated-game model of global sourcing in which final goods producers decide whether to engage with their suppliers in relational contracting and whether to integrate a supplier into a firm’s boundaries or deal with the latter at arm’s length. The model predicts that the likelihood of vertical integration increases in the long-term orientation of cooperation parties. Combining data from the U.S.

Census Bureau’s Related Party Trade database with measures for long-term orientation from Hofstede et al. (2010) and World Values Survey, I find empirical evidence supportive of this paper’s key prediction. To better understand if the relationship is causal, I apply instrumental variables approach using genetic proxies and inherited components of long-term orientation as instruments. Taken together, the evidence suggests that the level of long-term orientation of the home and host country has a positive effect on the relative prevalence of vertical integration.

Keywords: Relational contracts, long-term orientation, international make-or-buy decision JEL-Classifications: D02, D23, F14, F23, L22

I am grateful to Wilhelm Kohler and Michael Pflüger for helpful comments and suggestions and to Yuriy Gorodnichenko and Gerard Roland for providing the data. All errors are my own.

Bohdan Kukharskyy, Faculty of Economics, University of Tübingen, Mohlstrasse 36, 72074 Tübingen, Germany, Tel (Fax) + 49 (0) 7071 23 - 76013 (5223), E-mail: bohdan.kukharskyy@uni-tuebingen.de.

(3)

1 Introduction

When organizing production on a global scale, firms face the issue of contractual insecurity.

In case of a dispute between cooperation parties, courts may be constrained in their ability to verify each party’s deviation from the contract or unable to enforce verdicts upon subjects of different jurisdictions. Since an international arbitration process is also costly and time- consuming, firms often rely on relational contracts – informal long-term agreements sustained by the value of future relationship (Dixit 2004, MacLeod 2007). Yet, anecdotal evidence suggests that the ability of economic agents to engage in relational contracting hinges on their time preference rates, which systematically vary across countries.

One of the most widely documented examples in this context is the case study of two major automobile manufacturers, a Japanese corporation Toyota and an American enter- prise General Motors (GM). The former is well known for making extensive use of relational contracts (see, e.g., Board 2011 and Gibbons and Henderson 2012). As attested in a com- prehensive survey by Helper and Henderson (2014: 59), “as long as [Toyota’s suppliers] make a good-faith effort to perform as they should, the assembler will ensure that they receive a reasonable return on their investment [...], and as long as the supplier continued to meet the automaker’s expectations, the supplier could count on the relationship continuing indef- initely”. In contrast, GM’s cooperation with its suppliers is characterized by short-term – usually one-year – contracts focusing almost entirely on immediate financial results. The U.S. automobile manufacturer had been reportedly struggling to adopt its main competi- tor’s relational governance approach, but with little success (see Helper and Henderson 2014).

Business practitioners and academic researchers generally agree that GM’s inability to imi- tate Toyota’s organizational practices can be traced back to inherent differences in long-term orientation between Japanese and American managers.

Albeit anecdotal in its nature, the case study of Toyota vs. GM suggests a general research question: Do cross-country differences in long-term orientation, defined as the willingness of economic agents to forfeit instant gratification for the sake of long-term monetary benefits, have an impact on the organizational behavior of firms in those countries? This paper aims at shedding some light on this question by studying the effect of time discounting on the global organization of production. More specifically, I investigate how the level of long-term orientation affects a multinational firm’s decision to integrate a foreign supplier into firm boundaries or cooperate with the latter at arm’s length, thereby emphasizing the role of relational contracting. This paper argues, both theoretically and empirically, that the relative prevalence of vertical integration is increasing in the final good producers’ and suppliers’ levels of long-term orientation.

(4)

The model presented in this paper builds on the seminal theory of a multinational firm along the lines of Antràs and Helpman (2004) and embeds it into a repeated-game context suggested by Baker et al. (2002). The rationale behind this approach lies in the notion that business cooperations involving relationship-specific investments are the ones where long- term relationships may prevail. The mere possibility of a repeated interaction opens the door to relational contracting. More specifically, a final good producer and a supplier may commit at the outset to provide first-best investment levels in all subsequent periods of the game and sustain this agreement by the value of future relationship. It is well known from the Folk theorem, however, that the incentive compatibility of such an agreement crucially depends on both parties’ time preference rates. More specifically, a final good producer and supplier are willing to engage in relational contracting only if both parties are sufficiently long-term oriented. If the relational agreement is not self-enforcing, parties negotiate in each period ‘on the spot’ regarding the division of surplus and are stuck with the hold-up problems well-known from Antràs and Helpman (2004). The latter type of cooperation will be referred to throughout as spot contracting.

Regardless of whether cooperation parties are able to enter a relational agreement or ne- gotiate in every period on the spot, final good producers face the make-or-buy decision, i.e.

choose whether to integrate a supplier into firm boundaries or source intermediate inputs at arm’s length. Overall, this paper allows for four organizational modes: spot integra- tion, spot outsourcing, relational integration and relational outsourcing. The make-or-buy decision under spot contracting is analogous to Antràs and Helpman (2004): A final good producer integrates (outsources) manufacturing production if the importance of manufac- turing components in the production process is low (high, respectively). This result is in the spirit of the canonical Property Rights Theory of the firm along the lines of Grossman and Hart (1986) and Hart and Moore (1990): In order to minimize ex ante underinvestment, ownership rights over non-verifiable inputs are assigned to the party whose investment con- tributes relatively more to the value of the relationship.

The choice of the ownership form under relational contracting, however, serves a different purpose. Since parties implicitly agree to provide the first-best amount of relationship- specific inputs, final good producers no longer aim at incentivizing ex ante investment.

Instead, the make-or-buy decision is made so as to minimize suppliers’ incentives to renege on the relational agreement. The model shows that a supplier’s deviation incentives under relational integration are lower than under relational outsourcing. Intuitively, if a final good producer possesses property rights over a supplier’s assets, the supplier has a low bargaining position in case of a deviation from the relational agreement. Therefore, final good producers

(5)

under relational contracting strictly prefer integration over outsourcing.

Depending on both parties’ time preference rates, a final good producer decides whether to enter a relational agreement or cooperate with a supplier on the spot. Given that final good producers engaged in relational contracting always source manufacturing inputs within firm boundaries, whereas those ‘stuck’ with spot contracting integrate a supplier only if the importance of manufacturing components in the production process is relatively low (and cooperate with the latter at arm’s length otherwise), the model suggests the following key testable prediction: The prevalence of vertical integration is (weakly) increasing in the supplier’s and final good producer’s levels of long-term orientation.

I test this hypothesis by pooling together several datasets. To measure the relative preva- lence of vertical integration, I follow the bulk of the recent empirical literature on multina- tional firm boundaries in using U.S. Census Bureau’s Related Party Trade data.1 More specifically, I use the share of U.S. intra-firm imports in total U.S. imports as the dependent variable. The independent variable is a country’s index of long-term orientation, drawn from Hofstede et al. (2010). This score represents one of the five key cultural dimensions identified by Geert Hofstede to measure fundamental cultural differences and is generally recognized as a valid proxy for a country’s time preference rate (see Galor and Özak 2014). As argued by Hofstede et al. (2010), individuals in countries with a high level of long-term orientation value persistence, perseverance, and are willing to delay short-term material gratification in favor of long-term benefits. In contrast, individuals in short-term oriented countries care more about immediate gratification than long-term fulfillment. In line with the paper’s key prediction, I find a positive relationship between the share of U.S. intra-firm imports and a foreign country’s long-term orientation score. Importantly, this association remains signifi- cant after controlling for a standard set of explanatory factors that have been suggested in empirical studies of the Property Rights Theory of a multinational firm.

Since the above-mentioned relationship can potentially be driven by unobserved het- erogeneity across countries, and a country’s long-term orientation might be endogenous to economic outcomes, the identification of a causal effect of long-term orientation on the make- or-buy decision calls for an instrumental variables approach. To provide valid instruments for a country’s time preference rate, I exploit genetic data from Gorodnichenko and Roland (2011). More specifically, I construct two alternative measures of genetic distance between the population in a given country and the population in one of the most long-term oriented countries, Japan. Both measures are highly correlated with a country’s current level of long-

1 Given that comprehensive firm-level datasets on the international integration decisions are not readily available, this industry-level dataset has become a workhorse tool in empirical studies of international make-or-buy decisions, cf. Antràs (2013, 2015).

(6)

term orientation. This association can be rationalized in the light of recent literature, which argues that parents pass on not only their genes but also cultural traits to the offspring, see, e.g., Bisin and Verdier (2010) for an overview.2 At the same time, since international make-or-buy decision is exogenous to a country’s genetic characteristics, the instruments fulfill the exclusion restriction. Using these instruments, I find a positive effect of foreign suppliers’ long-term orientation on the share of intra-firm imports from a given country.

In order to assess the effect of a final good producer’s time preference rate on the relative prevalence of vertical integration, I construct a measure of long-term orientation that varies across U.S. sectors. For this purpose, I use information on ancestry from the 2000 U.S. Census to calculate the prevalence of managers and CEOs from a certain cultural background in a given industry. Weighing these ethnic shares with the long-term orientation scores of their ancestors’ countries, I construct industry-specific indices of long-term orientation and merge them with the above-mentioned Related Party Trade data. In accordance with the model’s prediction, I find a positive relationship between final good producers’ long-term orientation levels and the share of intra-firm imports in a given industry. This association remains significant after including a standard set of control variables and correcting for unobserved cross-country variation using country and year fixed effects.

As a robustness check, I rerun the regressions using a country’s level of trust as an alternative proxy for relational contracting. Since relational contracts are generally perceived as trust-based agreements (MacLeod 2007), a higher level of trust is arguably conducive to the emergence of implicit agreements between final good producers and their suppliers. The measure of trust is constructed using the well-known generalized trust question from the World Values Survey (see Guiso et al. 2010). In line with this paper’s key theoretical prediction, I find that higher level of trust in the home and host country is associated with greater share of intra-firm imports. To better understand if this relationship is causal, I follow Algan and Cahuc (2010) in instrumenting the current level of trust by its inherent component.

The instrumental variables estimates broadly confirm the OLS results, suggesting that a higher level of trust leads to more intra-firm trade.

Related literature. This paper is not the first to embed the static framework along the lines of Antràs and Helpman (2004) into a repeated game. Kukharskyy and Pflüger (2015) do so to study the effect of relational contracting on the economic well-being of nations.

Unlike the current paper, however, the authors do not derive a clear empirical prediction regarding the effect of home and host country’s long-term orientation on the international make-or-buy decision nor bring this prediction to the data.

2 To be clear, this paper doesnot presuppose a causal relationship between genes and cultural attributes such as long-term orientation, but rather exploits the correlation between the two.

(7)

From the empirical perspective, this paper is related to the burgeoning literature that aims to better understand the effect of culture on international trade and foreign direct in- vestment. Gorodnichenko et al. (2015) find a negative effect of cultural distance, measured as the difference in individualism scores, on intra-firm trade. Using historically motivated instrumental variables, Siegel et al. (2011, 2013) find a negative effect of egalitarianism dis- tance, defined as the difference in the belief that all people are of equal worth and should be treated equally in society, on foreign direct investment flows, cross-national flows of bond and equity issuances, syndicated loans, and mergers and acquisitions. Guiso et al. (2009) construct a measure of bilateral trust between European countries and instrument it with religious, genetic, and somatic similarities to show that lower bilateral trust leads to less trade and less direct and portfolio investment between two countries. Using data from the Eurovision Song Context, Felbermayr and Toubal (2010) construct a measure of cultural proximity and show a strong positive effect of this measure on trade volumes. Yet, none of these empirical studies consider the effect of long-term orientation on intra-firm trade.

The remainder of the paper is structured as follows: Section 2 lays out the basic set up. Section 3 describes the make-or-buy decision under spot and relational contracting and derives the key testable prediction. Section 4 presents econometric evidence supporting this paper’s key proposition. Section 5 concludes.

2 The set-up

The model economy consists of a home country, N, and F ≥ 1 foreign countries, denoted by the subscript `. Foreign countries ` differ regarding their production cost, geographical distance to N, and the time preference rate of their managers. Each country is populated by a unit measure of consumers, who are symmetric in terms of their utility functions. Each consumer is endowed with a unit of inelastically supplied labor. A subset of individuals also possess entrepreneurial abilities, which allow them to become firm managers.

Demand. Along the lines of Antràs and Helpman (2004), the utility function is assumed to be:

U =x0

J

X

j=1

lnXj , Xj = Z

xj(v)αdv 1/α

, µ >0 , 0< α <1, (1) where x0 is consumption of a homogenous good, Xj is an index of aggregate consumption of differentiated goods in sectorj, andxj(v)denotes consumption of a differentiated variety v in this sector. Parameter µ measures the intensity of preferences for differentiated goods and α is a parameter related to the elasticity of substitution between any two varieties,

(8)

σ = 1/(1− α). The budget constraint reads PJ

j=1PjXj +x0 = Y, where Y denotes a household’s income, Pj ≡ R

pj(v)1−σdv1/(1−σ)

is the price index of differentiated goods, and pj(v) represents the price of a single variety v in sector j. Utility maximization yields demand functions for the differentiated goods bundle, a single differentiated variety, and the homogenous good, respectively:3

Xj =µPj−1 , xj(v) = µpj(v)1−α1 P

α 1−α

j , x0 =Y −µ. (2)

Production. The homogenous good is produced in both countries under constant returns to scale and perfect competition. Production of one unit of output requiresaN units of labor in home country anda` > aN labor units in a foreign country`(i.e. workers inN are assumed to be more productive than in any foreign country). This numéraire good is assumed to be costlessly traded, implying the same (unitary) price in all countries. Consequently, the model exhibits a constant wage differential between the home country and foreign destinations:

wN > w` ∀ `. For simplicity, I normalize the wage rate in N to unity, wN = 1.

Production technology of differentiated varieties draws on Antràs and Helpman (2004).

Provision of each variety v requires two relationship-specific inputs: headquarter services hj(v)and manufacturing componentsmj(v), supplied by headquarter firmsH and manufac- turing suppliers M, respectively. Each intermediate input is produced with one unit of labor per unit of output. These inputs are combined to final goods according to the following Cobb-Douglas production function:4

xj(v) =

hj(v) ηj

ηj mj(v) 1−ηj

(1−ηj)

, (3)

where parameterηj ∈(0,1)captures the relative importance of headquarter services (hence- forth, headquarter intensity) in the production process of sector j.

Establishment of a firm (H or M) requires one entrepreneur as a fixed cost. Each en- trepreneur is an owner-manager of the unit and reaps this unit’s operating profit. As in Antràs and Helpman (2004), provision of headquarter services occurs strictly in N. Manu- facturing suppliers, however, are located in foreign countries.5 I assume that final assembly of

3 I assume sufficiently small preferences for differentiated goods (i.e.,µ < Y) to ensure positive consump- tion of the homogenous good in equilibrium.

4 For simplicity, I refrain from modeling firm heterogeneity regarding productivity. However, this feature can be easily introduced into the current framework along the lines of Antràs and Helpman (2004) without qualitatively affecting its main results.

5 This model can be easily extended by assuming thatM are located both inN andF and allowingH to choose between domestic and foreign sourcing, cf. Antràs and Helpman (2004). However, given that domestic sourcing is not observable in the dataset used in the empirical part of the paper, it is ruled out at the outset.

(9)

manufacturing components and headquarter services into final goods takes place inN. Inter- national trade in manufacturing components is costly, asτ`>1units ofmneed to be shipped from a foreign country ` for one unit to arrive in N. Similarly, shipment of final goods from N to` is associated with identical iceberg transport cost, τ` >1. Given the mill (fob.) price of final goods, pN j(v), the price paid by consumers in foreign country` is p`j(v) = τ`pN j(v).

Due to a symmetry of final good producers, the price indices prevailing in N and ` can be expressed asPN j = (nN j)1−αα pN j(v)andP`j`PN j, respectively, wherenN j represents the number of final good producers in sectorj. Combining these results with equation (2), yields total output of varietyv,xj(v) =µpN j(v)1−α1 P

α 1−α

N j +P

`τ`µ(τ`pN j(v))1−α1`PN j)1−αα . Us- ing this expression together with (3) and the fact thatPN j =µXN j−1 yields total revenue from the final goods production:

Rj(v) =

hj(v) ηj

αηj mj(v) 1−ηj

α(1−ηj)

µF1−αXN j−α. (4) The revenue positively depends on the preference parameter,µ, the number of foreign coun- tries F a good is supplied to and the aggregate demand level, XN j, which is exogenous from the viewpoint of a single producer, but determined endogenously in the industry equilibrium.

To save on notation, I drop the variety index v and the sector indexj from now on.

Contractual environment and organizational form. As in Antràs and Helpman (2004), the setting is one of incomplete contracts. Courts cannot verify the quality of intermediate inputs, and cooperating parties cannot sign ex ante enforceable contracts specifying the purchase of relationship-specific manufacturing components for a certain price. Against the backdrop of contractual incompleteness, a headquarter decides whether to integrate (I) the manufacturing supplier into firm boundaries or to outsource (O) manufacturing production to an independent supplier. The ex ante stipulated organizational form, k ∈ {I, O} is verifiable and enforceable by the courts.

In contrast to the one-shot game in Antràs and Helpman (2004), firms in the current model interact repeatedly. This alternative assumption aims at capturing the notion that business cooperations involving relationship-specific investments are the ones where long- term relationships predominate. It is well-known from the literature on repeated games (Baker et al. 2002) that the threat of discontinuing a long-term relationship may ensure some cooperation despite contractual incompleteness. However, the ability of cooperating parties to sustain a long-term cooperation depends on their time preference rates. Let δN ≡ 1/(1 +dN) denote the discount factor of a headquarter manager and δ` ≡1/(1 +d`) the discount factor of a supplier manager in country `, whereby dN and d` represent the

(10)

respective rates of time preference (discount rates). The time preference rates in each country are distributed according to a distribution function Γ(d). To accord with the empirical evidence presented below, I assume that the mean of these distribution functions differs across countries. In words, individuals in some countries are (on average) more long-term oriented than in others.

The game begins with the headquarters choosing locations ` for production of manu- facturing inputs. In each foreign destination, the headquarters are matched with suppliers and cooperation parties discover the time preference rates of their respective counterparts.

Depending on the revealed long-term orientation of the supply manager, H chooses one of the two governance modes: spot (s) vs. relational (r) contracting. Under a spot contract, parties bargain in each period with regard to the compensation of relationship-specific invest- ments. This ex-post negotiation process takes place via Nash bargaining, whereby Hobtains a fraction βk ∈(0,1) of the revenue. Following Antràs and Helpman (2004), I assume that headquarters obtain a greater share of surplus under vertical integration compared to out- sourcing, βI > βO. The intuition behind this assumption stems from the canonical Property Rights Theory of the firm along the lines of Grossman and Hart (1986): Integration gives H residual control rights over M’s inputs, which in turn enhances the former’s bargaining position and increases H’s ex post fraction of the revenue.

Under relational contracting, final good producers and their suppliers enter at the outset an informal agreement to provide the first-best level of inputs in all subsequent periods of the game. Furthermore, H commits to compensate M with an ex-post bonus Bk if the latter honors this agreement.6 However, since the quality of relationship-specific investment is not verifiable, such an agreement cannot be enforced by the courts. Hence, a supplier may renege on the relational contract by ex ante underinvesting in manufacturing components.

Similarly, a headquarter may provide a suboptimal level of headquarter activities and refuse to transfer the promised bonus to the supplier. In case any party reneges on the implicit contract, the implicit agreement is broken and the surplus in this period is shared according to the above-mentioned Nash-bargaining (with H obtaining a fraction βk of the revenue).

It is assumed that neither of the current partners can enter into a new relational agreement with a third party. In other words, in case of a deviation from a relational agreement in one period, both parties are ‘punished’ by non-cooperation and zero profits in all future periods.7 Timing. Under a governance mode g ∈ {s, r} and ownership form k ∈ {I, O}, the timing of events in a single period (product cycle) of the game can be summarized as follows.

6 As will be shown below, equilibrium bonus depends on the choice of the organizational formk∈ {I, O}.

7 This ‘grim trigger’ strategy can be justified by assuming a Commercial Registry, which contains infor- mation on all business relationships and is common knowledge for all market participants.

(11)

If H selects spot contracting (s), the consequent timing reads:

s1: H and M simultaneously and independently invest in hk and mk, respectively.

s2: Headquarters and suppliers negotiate about the division of surplus, wherebyHobtains the fraction βk of the revenue.

s3: Final goods are produced and sold. The revenue is distributed between parties accord- ing to the sharing rule negotiated in s2.

If H selects relational contracting (r), the consequent timing reads:

r1: Both parties commit to provide the first-best level of non-contractible inputs hk and mk. H commits to pay a bonusBk toM, if the latter sticks to this agreement.

r2: H and M simultaneously invest in hk and mk as agreed in r1.

r3: The final goods are produced and sold. The revenue is distributed between parties according to the compensation rule agreed upon in r1.

The product cycle stated above is repeated in all future periods of the game, t = 1, ...,∞.

The following section solves this game by backward induction.

Before describing the equilibrium of the game, it is worth pausing to briefly discuss this paper’s assumption regarding the surplus sharing between two parties. Notice that the timing specified above does not include ex ante lump-sum transfers, commonly assumed in the literature to ensure that the entire surplus from cooperation accrues to headquarters, see Antràs and Helpman (2004, 2008). As asserted by Antràs and Staiger (2012: 3148), “the feasibility of these transfers is particularly hard to defend in the international context [...], where such transfers and the obligations associated with them might be difficult to enforce.”

However, I show in Appendix A.3 that this paper’s main results are robust to allowing for the ex-ante transfers.

3 Optimal organizational structure

3.1 Spot governance

To characterize the subgame perfect equilibrium of the game described above, consider first date s2 under spot contracting. At this stage, H chooses h to maximize βkR(h, m)−h, whereas M picks m to maximize (1−βk)R(h, m)−w`τ`m. Using (4), this maximization problem yields equilibrium investment levels

hsk`kηαRsk` , msk` = (1−βk)

1−η w`τ`

αRk`s , (5)

(12)

and the associated revenue under spot contracting Rsk` = βkη(1−βk)(1−η)1−αα

(w`τ`)α(1−η)1−α A, (6)

where A ≡ µ1−α1 α1−αα F X

α 1−α

N has been defined for notational simplicity. Using (5) and (6) in maximization problems above, we obtain H’s andM’s profits under spot contracting

πsHk`k βkη(1−βk)(1−η)1−αα

(w`τ`)α(1−η)1−α A(1−αη), πM k`s = (1−βk) βkη(1−βk)(1−η)1−αα

(w`τ`)α(1−η)1−α A(1−α(1−η)).

(7)

Consider next the choice of organizational form ins1. A headquarter decides to cooperate with a supplier under spot integration rather than spot outsourcing whenever

ΘsH(η)≡ πHI`s πsHO` = βI

βO

βIη(1−βI)(1−η)1−ααOη(1−βO)(1−η))

α 1−α

(8)

is larger than one. I prove in Appendix A.1 that the relative attractiveness of spot integration, as measured by ΘsH(η), is increasing in the headquarter intensity η. The intuition behind this result stems from the Property rights theory of the firm: If a supplier’s contribution the production process becomes less important, the need for incentivizingM’s ex ante investment via outsourcing decreases. Furthermore, Appendix A.1 proves that integration dominates outsourcing for high enough headquarter intensities, i.e.ΘsH(η = 1)>1. For low headquarter intensities, however, outsourcing dominates integration if and only if 1−βI < α. Intuitively, if a supplier’s revenue share under integration is sufficiently low, headquarters in sectors with greater importance of manufacturing inputs relinquish control over these inputs in order to restore M’s investment incentives (recall that 1−βO > 1−βI). In order to allow for the coexistence of both organizational form, this paper imposes

Assumption 1. 1−βI < α.

Under this assumption, we have

Lemma 1. There exists a unique headquarter intensity ηˆ ∈ (0,1), such that headquarter profit is higher under spot outsourcing forη <ηˆand higher under spot integration forη >η.ˆ Proof. See Appendix A.1.

Although this result is well-known from Antràs and Helpman (2004), it can be consid- ered as complementary given that it does not rely on the assumption of ex-ante transfers.

In other words, while the organizational form in the original contribution is chosen so as to maximize joint profit from cooperation, headquarters in the current model choose the ownership structure which maximizes their own fraction of profits under spot contracting.

(13)

3.2 Relational governance

3.2.1 Equilibrium path

When H and M enter a relational contract, they implicitly agree to provide the level of investment that maximizes joint firm profit π(h, m) =R(h, m)−h−w`τ`m. Using (4), this maximization problem yields equilibrium investment levels and the associated revenue:

hrk` =ηαRrk` , mrk` =

1−η w`τ`

αRrk` , Rk`r = (w`τ`)α(1−η)1−α A. (9)

Comparing these results with (5), it immediately follows that investment levels under rela- tional contracting are higher than under spot governance, i.e. hrk` > hsk` and mrk` > msk`. Intuitively, a relational contract eliminates the hold-up problem associated with ex post bargaining and provides higher ex ante investment incentives compared to spot contracting.

This immediately implies a higher revenue under relational governance mode, Rrk` > Rsk`. Given that hrk` and mrk` maximize joint firm profit, they will be referred to as first-best in- vestment levels in what follows. If a supplier provides the first-best level of manufacturing components, mrk`, the headquarter compensates him with a bonus Bk` and both parties’

profits are given by πrHk` = Rrk`−hrk`−Bk` and πM k`r =Bk`−w`τ`mrk`, respectively. Using (9) therein, profits on the equilibrium path under relational contracting read

πrHk` = (w`τ`)α(1−η)1−α A(1−αη)−Bk`, πrM k`=Bk`−α(1−η)(w`τ`)α(1−η)1−α A.

(10)

If the relational contract is self-enforcing, there exits a bonusBk`which ensures both parties’

non-negative profits in equilibrium. As will be shown in the next section, this equilibrium bonus crucially depends on a supplier’s profits on the deviation path.

3.2.2 Off-the-equilibrium path

Since a relational contract is implicit and not verifiable by the courts, each party may renege on it. Consider first a supplier’s deviation (D) incentives. M can renege on the relational agreement by delivering a sub-optimal level of manufacturing inputs, m < mrk`. In this case, the relational contract is broken and the distribution of this period’s revenue betweenH and M occurs according to ex post bargaining with exogenous sharesβkand(1−βk), respectively.

M’s maximization problem on the deviation path readsmaxm(1−βk)R(hrk`, m)−m, whereby hrk`isH’s first-best level of headquarter services from (9). This maximization problem implies

(14)

the following investment level and revenue:

mDk` = (1−βk)

1−η w`τ`

αRDk` , RDk` = (1−βk)

α(1−η)

1−α(1−η) (w`τ`)α(1−η)1−α A. (11) A simple comparison of (11) and (9) implies a lower supplier investment on the deviation path as compared to the first best level, i.e. mDk` < mrk`.8 Utilizing (11) inM’s maximization problem, a supplier’s equilibrium profit on the deviation path reads:

πM k`D = (1−βk)1−α(1−η)1 (w`τ`)α(1−η)1−α A(1−α(1−η)). (12) Given the trigger strategy specified above, a supplier can reap these deviation profits only once and is ‘punished’ by non-cooperation in future periods of the game. A supplier honors the relational contract whenever the present value of his profits under relational contracting, πM k`r +

X

t=1

1 1+d`

t

πM k`r = πM k`r + πrM k`d

` , is larger than his one-shot deviation profit, πDM k`. M’s incentive compatibility constraint (ICCM) thus reads:

πrM k`M k`r

d` ≥πM k`D , (13)

whereby πM k`r and πM k`D are given by (10) and (12), respectively. As long as this ICCM is fulfilled, there exists a bonus Bk` which induces the supplier’s first-best investment in perpetuity. The headquarter has an incentive to stipulate the smallest possible bonus, which still fulfills the ICCM. Manipulating (13), this bonus can be expressed as

Bk` = (w`τ`)α(1−η)1−α A

α(1−η) + d`

1 +d`(1−βk)1−α(1−η)1 (1−α(1−η))

. (14) Utilizing (14) in (10), yields per-period profits of H and M on the equilibrium path under relational contracting:

πrHk` = (w`τ`)

α(1−η)

1−α A

(1−α)− d`

1 +d`(1−βk)1−α(1−η)1 (1−α(1−η))

, πM k`r = (w`τ`)

α(1−η)

1−α A

d`

1 +d`(1−βk)1−α(1−η)1 (1−α(1−η))

.

(15)

Notice that a supplier’s profit is non-negative for all parameter values (i.e. M’s participation

8 A tedious but straightforward analysis shows that supplier’s investment on the deviation path is higher than under spot contracting, i.e. mDk`> msk`. The result stems from the complementarity of inputsm andhand the fact thatH’s investment under relational agreement is higher than under spot contracting.

(15)

constraint may be ignored). A headquarter’s profit, however, is positive if and only if (1−α)> d`

1 +d`

(1−βk)1−α(1−η)1 (1−α(1−η)) (16)

As shown in Appendix A.2, this condition crucially depends on three factors.9 First, it is more likely to hold the lower headquarter intensity, η. Intuitively, when H’s contribution to the relationship is low, M can hardly exert ex post hold-up and the supplier’s incentives to renege on the relational agreement decrease. Second, this condition is more likely to be fulfilled the lower thed`, i.e. the more long-term oriented a supplier. Intuitively, as the long- term orientation of a supplier increases,ICCM can be satisfied with a smaller bonus andH’s profits from relational contracting increase. Finally, condition (16) is more likely to hold the higher a headquarter’s share of surplus from ex post bargaining, βk. Intuitively, a higher βk reduces M’s bargaining position on the deviation path and decreases the latter’s one-shot deviation incentives, see (12). Since βI > βO, the ICCM under relational integration can be satisfied with a smaller equilibrium bonus compared to relational outsourcing, BI` < BO`. This immediately implies

Lemma 2. Headquarters strictly prefer relational integration over relational outsourcing. A headquarter is more likely to offer a relational contract to a supplier the higher the latter’s level of long-term orientation and the higher a supplier’s contribution to the relationship.

Proof. See Appendix A.2.

The key implication of Lemma 2 is that headquarters offer relational contracts only to integrated suppliers. Relational integration by itself, however, is not yet a sufficient condition for an incentive compatibility of the implicit agreement, since headquarters may as well deviate from it. A headquarter reneges on the relational agreement by underinvesting in h and refusing to provide the ex post bonus BI`. H’s maximization problem on the deviation path reads maxβIR(h, mrI`)−h, whereby mrI` is the first-best level of headquarter services from (9). This maximization problem implies the following investment and revenue on H’s deviation path:

hDI`IηαRDI` , RDI`

αη 1−αη

I (w`τ`)α(1−η)1−α A. (17)

A simple comparison of (17) and (9) implies a lower headquarter investment on the deviation path as compared to the first best level, i.e. hDI` < hrI`.10 Utilizing (17) in H’s maximization

9 The effect ofαon this inequality is ambiguous.

10 As in the case of a supplier’s deviation (see footnote 8), complementarity of inputs implies higher headquarter’s investment on the deviation path compared to spot contracting, i.e. hDI`> hsI`.

(16)

problem, a headquarter’s profit on the deviation path reads:

πDHI`

1 1−αη

I (w`τ`)α(1−η)1−α A(1−αη). (18)

A headquarter complies to the relational integration contract if and only if the following incentive compatibility constraint is fulfilled:

πrHI`+ πrHI`

dN ≥πHI`D , (19)

whereby πHI`r andπHI`D are given by (15) and (18), respectively. It can be easily shown that a supplier is willing to participate in relational contracting only if this ICCH is fulfilled.

Otherwise, parties play a non-cooperative game discussed in section 3.1.

The headquarter intensity η affects the ICCH from (19) via two channels. On the one hand, a decrease in η is associated with lower M’s deviation incentives and, thereby, higher H’s profits on the equilibrium path (cf. Lemma 2). Other things being equal, this effect increases the left-hand side of ICCH. On the other hand, it is straightforward to show that a lowerηis associated with a higherπHI`D , which ceteris paribus increases the right-hand side of ICCH. The intuition behind the latter effect is similar to the one provided in Lemma 2.

When M’s contribution to the relationship is relatively high (i.e., η is low), a headquarter can easily hold-up a supplier ex post and, therefore, H’s deviation incentives increase. It can be shown that the overall effect ofη onICCH depends on parameter values and cannot be assigned without ambiguity. Yet, it immediately follows from (19) that lower dN makes relational integration self-enforcing for a greater range of parameter values. We thus have Lemma 3. A supplier is more likely to accept a relational integration contract offered by a headquarter the higher the latter’s long-term orientation.

Proof. Results immediately from (19).

3.3 Equilibrium governance mode

Having calculated the equilibrium profits under relational and spot contracting, we can turn to the headquarter’s choice of the optimal governance mode and its implication for the in- ternational make-or-buy decision. As shown in the previous section, final good producers engaged in relational contracting strictly prefer integration over outsourcing. Under spot contracting, headquarters self-select into integration vs. outsourcing depending on the head- quarter intensity of their production processes: Final good producers with high η integrate their suppliers into firm boundaries, whereas those with low η cooperate with the latter at

(17)

arm’s-length (cf. Lemma 1). In any given foreign location `, headquarters prefer relational integration over spot contracting whenever the former yields a higher present value of the profit flow, (1+dd N)

N πHI`r ≥maxn

(1+dN)

dN πHO`s ,(1+dd N)

N πHI`s o

, and it is self-enforcing. Formally, a final good producer decides in favor of relational contracting if and only if

πHI`r ≥max{πHO`s , πHI`s }, s.t. ICCM and ICCH.

As shown in Lemma 2, a headquarter’s profit under relational integration, πrHI` is increasing in the supplier’s level of long-term orientation. Furthermore, ICCM and ICCH are more likely to hold the more long-term oriented a supplier and a final good producer, respectively (cf. Lemma 3). Yet, a higher level of both parties’ long-term orientation levels not only increases the relative attractiveness of relational governance, but also has an effect on the relative prevalence of vertical integration. Given that integration is a strictly dominant form under relational contracting, while a fraction of final good producers engaged in spot contracting opt out for outsourcing (if η is sufficiently low), we have the following

Proposition. The likelihood of an integration of a foreign supplier into firm boundaries is (weakly) increasing in a supplier’s and a headquarter’s level of long-term orientation.

Proof. Follows immediately from Lemmas 1 through 3 and the discussion above.

The effect of time-preference rate on the relative prevalence of integration is weak (rather than strict) since some final good producers that were previously engaged in spot integration may now choose relational contracting without changing the (integrated) ownership struc- ture. Yet, some headquarters that were sourcing intermediate inputs from an independent supplier under a spot contract may switch to relational contracting due to a higher level of long-term orientation and, hereby, integrate a supplier into firm boundaries.

4 Empirical Implementation

4.1 Data

To test the key theoretical prediction of this paper, I combine several datasets. Following the bulk of the recent empirical literature on multinational firm boundaries, I use industry-level information on U.S. intra-firm trade from the U.S. Census Bureau’s Related Party Trade Database to capture the propensity of firms to source goods within firm boundaries.11 More specifically, the left-hand side variable is defined as the share of related party imports in

11 The suitability of this information to measure the international make-or-buy decisions is extensively discussed in Antràs (2015), from where this data is also drawn.

(18)

total (i.e., related and non-related) U.S. imports.12 A higher share of imports sourced from a related party (henceforth, intra-firm import share, IF IS) reflects a greater willingness of U.S. firms to obtain an ownership or control stake in foreign suppliers and, thus, captures the relative attractiveness of integration vs. outsourcing. Following Antràs (2015), I consider the period 2000-2011 and restrict the analysis to 390 manufacturing industries, defined at six-digit North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) level.13

The key explanatory variable is the index of a country’s long-term orientation (LTO) from Hofstede et al. (2010).14 This measure is one of the five key dimensions developed by Dutch sociologist Geert Hofstede to characterize fundamental cross-cultural differences.15 Hofstede et al. (2010: 239) define long-term orientation as the cultural value that “stands for the fostering of virtues oriented toward future rewards, in particular, perseverance and thrift” and show that this measure is positively correlated with the importance ascribed to receiving profits in the future rather than obtaining short-term benefits. In this respect, it is well-suited as a proxy for a time preference rate. The LTO measure varies between 0 (short-term orientation) and 100 (long-term orientation). For easier comparability of results, it has been rescaled to the unit interval, see Table 5 in Appendix B.

To better understand if the relationship between long-term orientation and make-or-buy decision is causal, I apply the instrumental variables approach. Using data from Gorod- nichenko and Roland (2011), I construct two instruments for the LTO: Euclidian (EDist) and Mahalanobis (Mdist) distance between the frequency of blood types in a given coun- try and the frequency of blood types in Japan, cf. Table 5 in Appendix B.16 The choice of Japan as a benchmark country is motived by the fact that this country has a second-highest LTO-score.17 Moreover, Japanese firms are widely known for their tendency to engage in relational contracting (cf. , e.g., the case of Toyota discussed in the introduction). As shown in figures 1 and 2, countries that are more genetically distant from Japan tend to have a

12 Census Bureau defines ‘related parties’ as firms “with various types of relationships including any person directly or indirectly, owning, controlling or holding power to vote, 6 percent of the outstanding voting stock or shares of any organization”.

13 See Data Appendix in Antràs (2015) for further discussion of the data.

14 This score is publicly available at: http://www.geerthofstede.eu

15 The other four cultural dimensions are individualism vs. collectivism, masculinity vs. femininity, uncertainty avoidance, and power distance.

16 The Euclidian genetic distance of country`from Japan (JPN) is defined asEDist(`, J P N) = [(fA,J P N fA,`)2+ (fB,J P NfB,`)2], whereft,` denotes the frequency of blood typet∈ {A, B}in country`. The Mahalanobis distance takes into account the covariance between blood type frequencies. In general, a Mahalanobis distance distance between a vector x and y picked from distributionsX is defined as M Dist(x, y) = [(xy)0P−1

X (xy)]1/2, where P

X is the covariance matrix for X. In the current context,P

X=var(fA,`, fB,`).

17 The country with the highestLTO-index is South Korea. However, the goodness of fit in the regression of LTO on Euclidian (R2 = 0.122) and Mahalanobis (R2 = 0.166) blood distance to South Korea is about half of the one in the case of Japan (cf. figures 1 and 2). Hence, to avoid biases associated with weak instruments, I use Japan as the benchmark country.

(19)

lower level of long-term orientation. To be clear, these figures do not postulate a causal relationship between genes and cultural attributes such as long-term orientation. Instead, if parents transmit not only genes, but also their cultural values to their offspring, popula- tions that are genetically close will happen to be also culturally close.18 At the same time, genetic instruments are likely to satisfy the exclusion restriction. Given that blood types are ‘neutral’ genetic markers (i.e. have no impact on individuals’ physical and cognitive abilities), they do not have a direct effect on a country’s economic outcomes. Furthermore, it is very unlikely that firms make their international make-or-buy decisions based on the genetic distance to the hosts countries.

Figure 1: LTO and Euclidian genetic distance. Figure 2: LTO and Mahalanobis genetic distance.

Finally, to test the impact of a final good producer’s time preference rate on the relative prevalence of integration, I construct a measure of long-term orientation that varies across U.S. sectors. More specifically, I use information on the ancestry of U.S. citizens from the 2000 U.S. Census to estimate the ethnic composition of U.S. industries. In this census, 80.1 percent of the population reported their ethnic origin, 58 percent of which specified a single ancestry, and 22 percent provided two ancestries. For the construction of the measure, I use the first ancestry indicated by an individual.19 Since the theoretical model presented above emphasizes the effect of cultural distance on the managerial make-or-buy decisions, my baseline measures for cultural composition of a sector include only those individuals who indicated their occupation as ‘Manager’ or ‘C.E.O’.20 Having calculated the ethnic shares of managers in a given industry, I weigh them with the long-term orientation scores of their

18 This correlation is well aligned with the recent literature, which argues that culture is transmitted mostly inside the family, see, e.g., Bisin and Verdier (2010) for an overview.

19 The results are robust to construction of an index that incorporates a person’s first and second ancestry.

20 Robustness checks show that the results continue to hold if one considers the workforce as a whole.

(20)

ancestor’s country of origin to obtain industry-specific measures of long-term orientation:

ltoj =X

`

S`jLT O`, (20)

whereS`j is the share of ethnic group`in industryj andLT O` is the long-term orientation of this ethnic group. Once again, the intuition behind this approach builds on recent empirical evidence that cultural traits are (partly) inherited from the ancestors (cf. Algan and Cahuc 2010, 2014). I consider two versions of this measure. The first one, lto1j, includes only those managers who report their ancestry. For the second measure, lto2j, I assign the average U.S. score to all managers in the U.S. census who do not report their ancestry. Table 6 in Appendix B presents the ten industries with the lowest and highest level of long-term orientation. To be clear, this approach merely exploits the distribution of long-term oriented managers across industries and does not posit inherent differences in long-term orientation between them. In view of this paper’s theoretical proposition, one would expect a higher fraction of intra-firm imports in industries with higher ltoj scores.

4.2 Econometric Specification

This paper’s baseline specification reads:

IF ISj`t =a×LT O`+b1×log (R&DInt)j`+b2×log (CapInt)j`+b3×log (SkillInt)j`

+b4×F reightj`+b5×T arifj`+b6×Dispersionj`+b7×Elasticityj`+b×X`+ε, where IF IS is the U.S. intra-firm import share from the U.S. Bureau of Customs and Border Protection and j, `, and t index sectors, countries, and years, respectively. The key explanatory variable is the level of a foreign country’s long-term orientation, LT O`.

Control variables 1 through 7 are standard in the empirical literature studying the in- ternational make-or-buy decision and are drawn from Antràs (2015). Since the suitability of these variables has been discussed at length in Antràs (2015), the introduction of control variables in the current paper is deliberately brief. In order to test for the key prediction of the Property Right Theory (cf. Lemma 1), headquarter intensity (η) is proxied by the R&D-, capital-, and skill-intensity. More specifically,Log(R&DInt)denotes the log of Research and Development expenditures as a share of total sales,Log(CapInt) is the log of the real capital stock per worker, and Log(SkillInt) is defined as the log of the number of non-production workers divided by total employment. Using a Property Rights model featuring firm-level heterogeneity and a tradeoff between domestic and foreign sourcing, Antràs (2015) finds a

(21)

positive effect of trade cost and productivity dispersion and an ambiguous effect of demand elasticity on the share of intra-firm trade. To account for these predictions, I follow Antràs (2015) in including controls for FreightCost (the ratio of CIF imports to FOB imports) and U.S.Tariffs, a measure for theDispersion of firm productivities (constructed as the standard deviation of log exports across U.S. port locations and destination countries), and a proxy for the Elasticity of demand.

One might argue that a country’s level of long-term orientation merely reflects the sta- bility of its institutions. In order to rule out the effect of legal institutions on the prevalence of integration, I include a wide range of institutional controls. In this paper, I report only the effect of government stability (GovStability) and provide the robustness checks including alternative institutional measures upon request. This proxy stems from the International Country Risk Guide (ICRG) and measures both the government’s ability to carry out its de- clared program(s), and its ability to stay in office, averaged over 1980 through 2000. Finally, cultural attributes of a society might also be a function of its size or economic develop- ment. To rule out this alternative explanation, I include the log of a country’s GDP in 2000, Log(GDP), from Penn World Table as an additional regressor.

4.3 Empirical Analysis

As a first pass at the data, I regress the share of U.S. intra-firm imports (IF IS) against the level of a country’s long-term orientation, LTO. As shown in specification (1) of table 1, the correlation between these two measures is positive and highly significant. A long-term oriented country such as Japan has over 50% of imports that are intra-firm, whereas for a rather short-term oriented country like Portugal this fraction is less than 25%. While this correlation is informative, one obviously needs to control for other variables to see if this relation is not driven by omitted factors. Columns (2)-(5) in table 1 report the results of the baseline OLS regressions. As one adds more controls, the coefficient on LTO decreases but remains significant throughout the specifications. Estimates for the control variables in columns (2) and (4) are broadly in line with previous empirical studies of global sourcing, cf. Chapter 8 in Antràs (2015). In particular, Log(R&DInt) and Log(CapitalInt) both have the predicted sign and are significant, while Log(SkillInt) has the right sign but is not significant in all specifications. This evidence suggests that a country’s LTO may have an independent impact on firms’ make-or-buy decisions alongside the well-established channel of the Property Rights Theory of the firm.

Clearly, the results from the simple OLS regression presented above are not sufficient to claim a causal impact ofLTO on intra-firm imports. For instance, given that the presence of

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

15 There is no research that tracks gender differences in environments like the contracting games considered here in which there are gains from exchange and cheap-talk

The umbrella agreement will also define those credit information services which the software agents are entitled to negotiate and to contract for.. In addition, the umbrella

In a labor market with search frictions where homogeneous profit-maximizing firms can approach heteroge- neous reciprocal workers directly due to perfect information (e.g.

It should be noted that already the non-associative join operator, and thus the derived associative one, can be defined in terms of, a new type and class

Because the principal’s actions and the success of trade are publicly observed, hτ = Iτ , Aτ , i, ṽτ − p̃τ , where Iτ is the set of insiders of the agent in period τ , the

In this paper, we develop continuous-time methods for solving dynamic contracting problems and apply them to an optimal taxation model in which the agent’s privately

To this end, we regress firm-pair specific ownership shares on the rule of law index, while controlling for a large set of observable characteristics (of the subsidiary’s country,

The most insightful representation of the ordered logit results involves evaluating the marginal effects of the covariates on the probability of the four different outcomes. Thus,