• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Victory and Defeat in Differential Games

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Victory and Defeat in Differential Games"

Copied!
20
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

W O R K I N G P A P E R

VICTORY

AND DEFEAT

LN

DIFFERENTIAL GAMES

Jean-Pierre Aubin

September 1988 WP-88-079

l n t e r n a t ~ o n a l l n s t ~ t u t e for Appl~ed Systems Analys~s

(2)

VICTORY AND DEFEAT IN DIFFERENTIAL GAMES

Jean-Pierre Aubin

September 1988 WP-88-079

Working Papers are interim reports on work of the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis and have received only limited review. Views or opinions expressed herein do not necessarily represent those of the Institute or of its National Member Organizations.

INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE FOR APPLIED SYSTEMS ANALYSIS A-2361 Laxenburg, Austria

(3)

Victory and Defeat in Differential Games

Jean-Pierre Aubin

C E R E M A D E

,

U N I V E R S I T ~ DE PARIS- DAUPHINE

&

I I A S A , INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE FOR APPLIED SYSTEMS ANALYSIS

(4)

FORE WORD

T h e author constructs the set-valued feedback map wich allow players in a differential game the possiblity of winning, separately or colletively, or the certainty of winning or loosing and characterizes the indicator func- tions of their graphs as solutions to (contingent) partial differential equa- tions. Decisions are defined to be the derivatives of the controls of players, and decision rules for each of these set-valued feedback maps allowing the players to abide by them as time elapses are provided.

Alexander B. Kurzhanski Chairman System and Decision Science Program

(5)

1 Description of the Game

Let our two players Xavier and Yves act on the evolution of the state z(t) E

R n

of the differential game governed by the differential equation

by choosing Xavier's controls

and by choosing Yves's controls

Here, h, describing the dynamics of the game, maps continuously

R n

x

RP x RQ

into

Rn,

and U :

R n

?.t

RP

and V :

R n

?.t

R q

are closed1 set-valued maps describing the state-dependent constraints bearing on t h e players.

We shall assume t h a t the open-loop controls u ( - ) and v(.) are absolutely continuous and obey a growth condition of the type2

We shall refer to them as "smooth open-loop controls", the non negative parameters3 p and a being fixed once and for all. The domain K of the game is the subset of

( 5 ) (z, u, v) E

R n x RP

E

R Q

such that

u E U(z) & v E V(z)

Roughly speaking, Xavier may win as long as its opponent allows him t o choose a t each instant t

2

0 controls u ( t ) in the subset U ( z ( t ) ) , and must loose if for any choice of open-loop controls, there exists a time T

>

0 such t h a t u ( T )

4

U ( z ( T ) ) .

'This means that the graph of the set-valued map is closed. Upper semicontinuous set-valued maps with compact values are closed, and thus, closedness can be regarded as a weak continuity requirement.

2one can replace p((lu(1

+

1) by any continuous function 4(u) with linear growth.

30r any other linear growth condition 4(.) or $(.) which makes sense in the framework of a game under investigation.

(6)

Definition 1.1 Let ( u o , v0, zO) be an initial situation such that initial con- trols uo U ( q ) and vo V ( z O ) of the two players are consistent with the initial state zo.

W e shall say that

- Xavier must win

if

and only

if

for all smooth open-loop controls u ( - ) and v ( - ) starting at uo and vo, there ezists a solution z ( - ) t o (1) starting at zo such that (2) is satisfied.

- Xavier may win if and only if there ezist smooth open-loop controls u ( - ) and v ( - ) starting at uo and vo and a solution z ( - ) to (1) starting at zo such that (2) is satisfied.

- Xavier must loose if and only if for all smooth open-loop control u ( . ) and v ( . ) starting at uo and vo and solution z ( . ) t o (1) starting at zo, there ezists a time T

>

0 such that

- The initial situation is playable if and only if there ezist open- loop controls u ( . ) and v ( . ) starting at uo and vo and a solution z ( . ) t o (1) starting at zo satisfying both relations (2)and (3).

Naturally, if both Xavier and Yves must win, then both relations (2)and (3) are satisfied. This is not necessarily the case when both Xavier and Yves may win, and this is the reason why we are led to introduce the concept of playability.

2 The Main Theorems

Theorem 2.1 Let us assume that h is continuous with linear growth and that the graphs of U and V are closed. Let the growth rates p and a be fized.

There ezist five (possibly empty) closed set-valued feedback maps from Rn t o

RP

x

RQ

having the following properties:

- Ru

c

U is such that whenever ( u o , v o ) E R u ( z o ) , Xavier may win and that whenever ( u o , v O ) @ RU ( z O ) , Xavier must loose

- If h is lipschitzean, Su

c

Ru is the largest closed set-valued map such that whenever ( u o , v o ) E S u ( z o ) , Xavier must win.

(7)

- Sv C Rv

c

V , which have analogous properties.

- R u v C Ru

n

Rv is the largest closed set-valued map such that any initial situation satisfying (uo, u o ) E Ruv(zo) is playable.

Knowing these five set-valued feedback maps, we can split the domain K of initial situations into ten areas which describe the behavior of the differential game from the position of the initial situation.

Graph(&)

-

Xavier must loose K \ G r a p h ( R v )

Yves must loose Yves must loose

I

Yves must loose

'

Graph(Rv)

I I

Yves may win

The 10 areas of the domain of the diferential game Xavier must win

Yves must win Xavier must win

?

1

PLAYABILITY

1

? ? ?~

? Yves may win

In particular, the complement of the graph of R u v in the intersection of the graphs of Ru and Rv is the instability region, where either Xavier or Yves may win, but not both together.

T h e problem is t o characterize these five set-valued maps, the existence of which is now guaranteed, by solving the "contingent extension" of the partial differential equation4

4 U is a solution t o this partial differential equation, one can check t h a t for any initial situation ( 2 0 , uo, vo) E Dom(O), there exists a smooth solution ( z ( . ) , u(.), v ( . ) ) such t h a t

Xavier may win I Xavier must loose 1

t

-

@ ( z ( t ) , u ( t ) , u ( t ) ) is non increasing

Yves must win

? ? ?

T h i s property remains true for the solutions t o the contingent partial differential equation (9).

Yves must win Xavier must loose

(8)

which can be written in the following way:

a@ a@

- . h ( z , u , v ) +

a

z IIU~II<P(IIUII+~) inf - .

a~

u l + I I V ~ I I S U ( I I ~ I I + ~ ) inf - . v

a@

a v I = O We shall also introduce the partial differential equation5

which can be written in the following way:

a@ a@

- - h ( z , u , v ) +

a2

SUP

- -

u l + s u p - . v

a@

I = O

I I U ~ I I S P ( I I U I I + ~ )

a"

I I V ~ I I S U ( I I V I I + ~ )

av

T h e link between the feedback maps and the solutions t o the solutions t o these partial differential equations is provided by the indicators of the graphs: we associate with the set-valued maps S u , R U and R u v the func- tions G u , \ku and \k from

Rn

x

RP

x

Rq

to R+ U {+oo) defined by

and the functions Qv and Qv associated to the set-valued m a p R v and Sv in an analogous way.

These functions being only lower semicontinuous, but not differentiable, cannot be solutions t o either partial differential equations (6) and. (7). But we can define t h e contingent epiderivatives of any function @ :

R n

x 5 0 n e can check that if f is lipschitzean and iP is a solution to this partial differ- ential equation, for any initial situation (20, uo, uo) E Dam(@), any smooth solution ( z ( . ) , u ( . ) , u ( . ) ) satisfies

' 0 if ( u , v ) E S ~ ( Z )

$00 if ( u , v )

4

SU(Z) ' 0 if ( u , v ) E R u ( z )

$00 if ( u , v )

$

R u ( z ) 0 if ( u , v ) E R u v ( z )

, +00 if

(v) 4

R u v ( z ) (8) <

t

-

O ( z ( t ) , u ( t ) , u(t)) is non increasing

I

i) G u ( z , u , v ) := <

ii) \ k u ( z , u , v ) :=

iii) \ k ( z , u , v ) := <

This property remains true for the solutions to the contingent partial differential equation (10).

(9)

RP x

RQ

-+ R U {+m) and replace the partial differential equations (6)and (7) by the contingent partial differential equations

(9) inf D t @ ( z , u , v ) ( h ( z , 21, v), u', v')

1 1 ~ ' I l 5 ~ ( 1 1 ~ 1 1 +

1) IIv'II

5

4IIvII

+

1) and

(10) S U P D T @ ( z , 21, v ) ( h ( z , 21, v), u', v')

I l ~ ' 1 1 5 P ( I I u I I +

1)

IIv'II

5

o(IIvII

+

1) respectively.

Let Ru and Rv be the indicators of the graphs of the set-valued maps

U

and V defined by

Theorem 2.2 We posit the assumptions of Theorem 2.1. Then

- Qu is the smallest lower semicontinuous solution t o the contingent partial diflerential equation (9) larger than or equal t o Ru

- \kv is the smallest lower semicontinuous solution to the contingent partial diflerential equation (9) larger than or equal t o RV

- \k is the smallest lower semicontinuous solution t o the contingent partial diflerential equation (9) larger than or equal t o m a x ( R u , R v )

- If h is lipschitzean,

aU

is the smallest lower semicontinuous solution t o the contingent partial diflerential equation (10) larger than or equal t o Ru

- If h is lipschitzean, igv is the smallest lower semicontinuous solution t o the contingent partial diflerential equation (10) larger than or equal t o RV

If any of the above solutions is the constant + m , the corresponding feedback map is empty.

(10)

Proof of Theorem 2 . 1 - Let us denote by B the unit ball and introduce the set-valued map F defined by

The evolution of the differential game described by the equations (1) and (4) is governed by the differential inclusion

- Since the graph of U is closed, we know that there exists a largest closed viability domain contained in Graph(U) x R Q , which is the set of initial situations ( 2 0 , uo, vo) such that there exists a solution ( z ( . ) , u ( - ) , v(.)) to this differential inclusion remaining in this closed set. This is the graph of R u . Indeed, if (uo,vo) E Ru(zo), there exists a solution to the differential inclusion remaining in the graph of U , i.e., Xavier may win. If not, all solutions starting a t (20, uo, vo) must leave this domain in finite time.

The set-valued feedback map is defined in an analogous way.

- For the same reasons, the graph of the set-valued feedback map R u v is the largest closed viability domain of the set K of initial situations.

- When h is lipschitzean, so is F. Then the solution-map S (20, uo, vO) is also lipschitzean thanks to Filippov's Theorem6, so that the subset of ini- tial situations such that all the functions of S ( z o , uo, vo) remain in a closed subset is also closed. This is the largest closed invariant domain by F of this closed subset. Then the largest closed invariant domain contained in Graph(U) x R Q is the graph of the set-valued feedback map Su.

Proof of Theorem 2.2 - We recall that thanks to Haddad's viability Theorem, a subset L

c

Rn x R P x RQ is a viability domain of F if and only if

V ( z , u , v ) E L , T t ( z , u , v ) n H ( z , u , v )

# 0

Let \kL denote the indicator of L. We know that the epigraph of the contingent epiderivative Dt\kL(z, u , v ) of \kL is the contingent cone to the epigraph of \kL a t ( ( 2 , u , v ) , 0). Since the latter subset is equal to L x R + , its contingent cone is equal to TL(z, u, v) x R + , and coincides with the epigraph of the indicator of T ~ ( z , u , v ) . Hence the indicator of the contingent cone

(11)

TL(z, u, v) is the contingent epiderivative DT\kL(z, u , v) of the indicator QL of L at ( z , u , v ) .

Therefore, the above tangential condition can be reformulated in the following way:

V (z, u, v) E L, 3 w E H ( z , u, v) such that DT\EL(z, u, v) (w) = \kTL(z,U,V) ( w ) = 0 Since the epiderivative is lower semicontinuous and the images of F are compact, this is equivalent t o say that

v ( z , u , v ) E L , W E H ( Z , U , V ) inf D t \ k L ( ~ , u , v ) ( w ) = 0

By the very definition of the set-valued map F , we have proved t h a t L is a closed viability domain if and only if its indicator function \kL is a solution t o the contingent partial differential equation (9).

- Hence t o say that the graph of R u is the largest closed viability domain contained in the graph of U amounts t o saying t h a t its indicator

\ku is the smallest lower semicontinuous solution t o the contingent par- tial differential equation (9) larger than or equal t o the indicator Ru of Graph(U)

x Rq.

The same reasoning shows that indicator \kv of R v is the smallest lower semicontinuous solution to the contingent partial differential equation (9) larger than or equal t o Rv and that the indicator Q of the graph of R u v is the smallest lower semicontinuous solution t o the contin- gent partial differential equation (9) larger than or equal t o the indicator of K, which is equal t o max(Ru, R v ) .

- We know that the a closed subset L

c R n x RP

x

RQ

is "invariant"

by a lipschitzean set-valued map F if and only if

This condition can be reformulated in terms of contingent epiderivative of the indicator function \EL of L by saying that

V ( z , u , v ) E L , sup D t \ k ~ ( z , u , v ) ( w ) = 0

w€H(z,u,v)

Hence t o say t h a t the graph of Su is the largest closed invariance domain contained in the graph of U amounts t o saying t h a t its indicator Q U is the smallest lower semicontinuous solution t o the contingent partial differential equation (10) larger than or equal to the indicator Ru of Graph(U)

x RQ.

13

(12)

3 Closed-Loop Decision Rules

When t h e initial situation (20, U O , vO) belongs t o one of the following subsets:

then the players has nothing t o worry about because both of them must either win or loose whatever the choice of their control.

In the other areas, at least one of the players may win, but for achieving victory, he has t o find open-loop or closed-loop controls which remain in the appropriate set-valued feedback map.

Let us denote by R one of the feedback maps R u , R v , R u v and assume t h a t the initial situation belongs t o the graph of the set-valued feedback map R (when it is not empty). The theorem states only that there exists a t least a solution (z(.), u(.), v(.)) to the differential game such t h a t

To implement these strategy, players have to make decisions, i.e., to choose velocities of controls in an adequate way:

We observe that playable solutions

Proposition 3.1 The solutions to the game satisfying

are the solutions to the system of diflerential inclusions

(13) ) (.'(t),vl(t)) E G R ( z ( ~ ) , u ( ~ ) , v ( ~ ) ) where we have denoted by GR the R-decision map defined by

For simplicity, we shall set G := GR whenever there is no ambiguity.

Proof - Indeed, since the absolutely continuous function (z(.), u ( - ) , v(.)) takes its values into Graph(R), then its derivative ( z l ( - ) , ul(.), v l ( - ) ) belongs almost everywhere t o the contingent cone

(13)

We then replace zl(t) by h ( z ( t ) , u (t), v(t)).

The converse holds true because equation (13) makes sense only if ( ~ ( t ) , u ( t ) , v(t)) belongs to the graph of R.

The question arises whether we can construct selection procedures of the decision components of this system of differential inclusions. It is convenient for this purpose to introduce the following definition.

Definition 3.2 () We shall say that a selection (5'2) of the contingent derivative of the smooth regulation map R in the direction h defined by

is a closed-loop decision rule.

The system of diflerential equations

i) zl(t) = h ( z ( t ) , ~ ( t ) , ~ ( t ) ) (16) ii) ul(t) = c ( z ( t ) , u ( t ) , v ( t ) )

iii) vl(t) = d ( z ( t ) , u ( t ) , v(t)) is called the associated closed-loop decision game.

Therefore, closed-loop decision rules being given for each player, the closed-loop decision system is just a system of ordinary differential equa- t ions.

It has solutions whenever the maps c and d are continuous (and if such is the case, they will be continuously differentiable).

But they also may exist when c or d or both are no longer continuous.

This is the case when the decision map is lower semicontinuous thanks to Michael's Theorem:

Theorem 3.3 Let us assume that the decision map G := G R is lower semicontinuous with non empty closed convex values on the graph of R .

Then there exist continuous decision rules c and d, so that the decision system 16 has a solution whenever the initial situation (uo, vo) E R(zo)

But we can obtain explicit decision rules which are not necessarily con- tinuous, but for which the decision system 16 has a still solution.

It is useful for t h a t purpose to introduce the following definition:

(14)

Definition 3.4 (Selection Procedure) A selection procedure of the reg- ulation map G :

Rn - RP

x

R4

is a set-valued map SG :

R n - RP

x

R4

( 1 7 ) V Z E K , S ( G ( z ) ) := S G ( z ) n G ( z )

# 0 ii)

the graph of SG is closed

and the set-valued map S ( G ) : z 2.tS ( G ( z ) ) is called the selection of G . It is said convex-valued or simply, convex

if

its values are convex and strict if moreover

( 1 8 ) V z E D o m ( G ) , So ( z ) n G ( z ) = { d ( z ) ) , ~ ( z ) ) is a singleton.

Hence, we obtain also the following existence theorem for closed-loop decision rules obtained through sharp convex selection procedures.

Theorem 3.5 Let SG be a convex selection of the set-valued map G . Then, for any initial state ( 2 0 , uo, v o ) E graph(R), there exists a starting at ( z o , uo, v o ) t o the associated system of diflerential inclusions

i ) z' ( t ) = h ( z ( t ) , u ( t ) , v ( t ) )

( 1 9 )

{

ii) t ,' t E S ( D ~ ( z ( t ) , 4 t ) , v ( t ) ) h ( z ( t ) ,

4%

~ ( t ) ) )

:= G ( z ( t ) , u ( t ) , v ( t ) ) n s ~ ( z ( t ) , u ( t ) , v ( t ) ) I n particular, if we assume further that the selection procedure SG is sharp, t h e n the single-valued map

is closed-loop decision rule, for which decision system 16 has a solution for any initial state ( 2 0 , uo, v o ) E graph(R).

Proof - We shall replace the system of differential inclusions ( 1 3 ) by the system of differential inclusions

(15)

Since the convex selection procedure SG has a closed graph and convex values, the right-hand side is upper semicontinuous set-valued map with nonempty compact convex images and with linear growth. It remains to check t h a t GraphR is still a viability domain for this new system of dif- ferential inclusions. Indeed, by construction, we know that there exists an element w in the intersection of G(z, u, v) and SG(z, u, v). This means t h a t the pair (h(z, u, v), W ) belongs t o h ( z , u , v) x SG(z, u, v) and t h a t it also belongs to

Graph(G) := TGraphR (2, U )

Therefore, we can apply Haddad's Viability Theorem. For any initial situa- tion (20, UO, vO), there exists a solution (z(.), u ( - ) , v ( - ) ) to t h e new system of differential inclusions (20) which is viable in Graph(R). Consequently, for almost all t

>

0, the pair (zl(t), u l ( t ) , vl(t)) belongs to the contingent cone to the graph of R a t (z(t), u ( t ) , v(t)), which is the graph of the contingent derivative D R ( z ( t ) , u ( t ) , v(t)). In other words,

for almost all t

>

0, ( u l ( t ) , vl(t)) E G ( z ( t ) , u ( t ) , v ( t ) )

We thus deduce t h a t for almost all t

>

0, (ul(t), vl(t)) belongs to the selec- tion S ( G ) (z(t), u ( t ) , v(t)) of the set-valued map G ( z ( t ) , u ( t ) , v ( t ) ) . Hence, we have found a solution to the system of differential inclusions (19).

We can now multiply the possible corollaries, since we have given several instances of selection procedures of set-valued maps.

Example- COOPERATIVE BEHAVIOR Let a : Graph(G) ++ G be continuous.

Corollary 3.6 Let us assume that the set-valued map G is lower semi- continuous with nonempty closed convez images on Graph(R). Let a be continuous on Graph(G) and convez with respect to the pair ( u , v ) . Then, for all initial situation (uo, vo) E R(zo), there ezist a solution starting at

( z o , uo, vo) and to the diflerential game (1)-(4) which are regulated by:

for almost all

2

0, (ul(t), vl(t)) E G ( z ( t ) , u ( t ) , v(t)) and a ( z ( t ) , ~ ( t ) , v(t), u l ( t ) , vl(t))

= inful,ul~c(z(t),u(t),v(t)) a ( z ( t ) , ~ ( t ) , v (t), ul, vl)

(16)

In particular, the game can be played b y the heavy decision of minimal norm:

Proof - We introduce the set-valued map SG defined by:

S G ( Z ) := { ( c , d ) E Y ( a ( z , u , v , c, d )

5

inf a ( z , u , v , u ' , v ' ) )

( u f , v l ) € G ( z , u , v )

It is a convex selection procedure of G . Indeed, since G is lower semicon- tinuous, the function

( z , u , v , c , d ) ++ a ( z , u , v , c , d )

+

sup ( - a ( z , u , v , u l , v ' ) ) (u',v')€G(z,u,v)

is lower semicontinuous thanks t o the Maximum Theorem. Then the graph of SG is closed because

Graph(SG) =

{ ( z , u , v )

1

~ ( z , u , V , C , d )

+

S U P ( u ~ , v ~ ) ~ ~ ( z , u , v ) ( - a ( z , u , V , ~ 'v ' ) ) 9

5

0 ) The images are obviously convex. Consequently, the graph of G being also closed, so is the selection S ( G ) equal to:

S ( G ) ( z , u , v ) = { ( c , d ) E G ( z , u , v )

I

a ( z , u , v , c , d )

5

inf a ( z , u , v , u ' , v l ) ) )

( u ' , v ' ) E G ( z , u , v )

We then apply Theorem 3.5. We observe t h a t when we take

the selection procedure is strict and yields the decisions of minimal norm.

Example- NONCOOPERATIVE BEHAVIOR

We can also choose controls in the regulation sets G ( z , u , v ) in a non cooperative way, as saddle points of a function a ( z , u , v ,

.,

.).

Corollary 3.7 Let us assume that the set-valued map G is lower semi- continuous with nonempty closed conuez images on Graph(R) and that a : Rn x

RP

x

RQ

+ R satisfies

i ) a is continuous

ii) V ( Z , u , u , d ) , c I-+ a ( z , u , v , C , d ) is conuez iii) V ( Z , u , v , c ) , d I-+ a ( z , u , v , C , d ) is concave

(17)

Then, for all initial situation ( u o , vo) E R ( z O ) , there ezist a solution starting

at ( 2 0 , U O , vO) and to the differential game ( 1 ) - ( 4 ) which are regulated b y :

I 1

( ~ ' ( t ) , v l ( t ) ) E G ( z ( t ) , ~ ( t ) , v ( t ) )

ii)

V ( u ' , v l ) E G ( z ( t ) , u ( t ) , v ( t ) ) , for almost all t

2

0, a ( z ( t ) , ~ ( t ) , ~ ( t ) , ~ ' ( t ) , v ' )

i

a(.(t), ~ ( t ) , v ( t ) , ~ ' ( t ) , v l ( t ) )

i

a(.(t), ~ ( t ) , ' l ~ ' , v l ( t ) )

Proof - We prove that the set-valued map SG associating to any

( 2 , u , v ) E Graph(R) the subset

S G ( z , u , v ) := { ( c , d ) such that

V ( u l , v') E G ( z , u , v )

,

a ( z , u , v , C , v ' )

i

a ( z , u , v , u ' , d ) )

is a convex selection procedure of G . The associated selection map S ( G ( - ) ) associates with any ( z , u , v ) the subset

S ( G ( z , u , v ) ) := { ( c , d ) E G ( z , u , v ) such that

V ( u l , v ' ) E G ( z , U , v ) , a ( z , u , v , C , v ' )

5

a ( z , u , v , u', d ) )

of saddle-points of a ( z , u , v ,

.,

-) in G ( z , U , v ) . Von Neumann' Minimax The- orem states that the subsets S ( G ( z , u , v ) ) of saddle-points are not empty since G ( z , u , v ) are convex and compact. The graph of SG is closed thanks to the assumptions and the Maximum Theorem because it is equal to the lower section of a lower semicontinuous function:

Graph(&) = { ( z , u , v , C , d )

I

SUP ( ~ ( 2 , u , ~ , C , v l ) - a ( z , ~ , v , u ' , d ) )

5

0)

( u f , v l ) ~ G ( z , u , v )

We then apply Theorem 3.5. 13

Remark - Whenever the subset Ruv ( z ( t ) )

\

Rv ( z ( t ) ) is not empty, Xavier may be tempted to choose a control u ( t ) such that

because in this case, Xavier may win and Yves is sure to loose eventually.

Naturally, Yves will use the opposite behavior.

(18)

Hence we can attach to the game two functions

and look for closed-loop controls (Q(z), B ( 2 ) ) which are Nash equilibria of this game:

Unfortunately, the selection procedure which could yield such behavior are not convex. The answer to this question remains unknown for the time.

References

[I] AUBIN J.-P. (1988) Qualitative Differential Games: a Viability Approach. Annales de 1"Institut Henri-PoincarO, Analyse Non LinOaire.

[2] AUBIN J.-P. (1988) Contingent Isaac's Equations of a Differ- ential Game. Proceedings of the Third International Meeting on Differential Games, INRIA Sophia- Antipolis.

[3] AUBIN J.-P. & CELLINA A. (1984) DIFFERENTIAL I N - CLUSIONS. Springer-Verlag (Grundlehren der Math. Wis- senschaften, Vo1.264, 1-342)

[4] AUBIN J.-P. & EKELAND I. (1984) APPLIED NONLINEAR ANALYSIS. Wiley-Interscience

[5] BERKOWITZ L. (1988) This volume

[6] BERNHARD P. (1979) Contribution 2 l'ktude des jeux diffkrentiels

A

somme neulle et information parfaite. T h h e Uni- versitk de Paris VI

(19)

[7] BERNHARD P. (1980) Exact controllability of perturbed continuous-time linear systems. Trans. Automatic Control, 25, 89-96

[8] BERNHARD P. (1987) In Singh M. G. Ed. SYSTEMS & C O N -

TROL ENCYCLOPEDIA, Pergamon Press

[9] FLEMMING W. & RISHEL R.W. (1975) DETERMINISTIC A N D

SOCHASTIC 0 PTIMAL CONTROL Springer-Verlag

[ l o ] F R A N K 0 WSKA H. (1987) L 'e'quation d'Hamilton- Jacobi con- tingente. Comptes Rendus de 1'Acadkmie des sciences, PARIS, [ l l ] FRANKOWSKA H. Optimal trajectories associated t o a solu- tion of contingent Hamilton-Jacobi Equation Appl. Math. Opt.

[12] FRANKOWSKA H. (to appear)

Hamilton-Jacobi Equations:viscosity solutions and generalized gradients. J . Math.Ana1. Appli.

[13] GUSEINOV H. G.

,

SUBBOTIN A. I. & USHAKOV V. N.

(1985) Derivatives for multivalued mappings with applications t o game theoretical problems of control. Problems of Control and Information Theory, Vo1.14, 155-167

[14] ISSACS R. (1965) DIFFERENTIAL GAMES. Wiley, New York [15] KRASOVSKI N. N. & SUBBOTIN A. I. (1974) POSITIONAL

DIFFERENTIAL GAMES. Nauka, Moscow

[16] LEITMANN G. (1980) Guaranteed avoidance strategies. Jour- nal of Optimization Theory and Applications, Vo1.32, 569-576 [17] LIONS P. -L. (1982) GENERALIZED SOLUTIONS OF

HAMILTON- JACOBI EQUATIONS. Pitman

[la]

LIONS P. -L. & SOUGANIDIS P.E. (1985) Diferential games, optimal control and directional derivatives of viscosity solutions of B e l l m a n and Isaacs' equations. SIAM J . Control. Optimiza- tion, 23

(20)

[I91 SUBBOTIN A. 1. (1985) Conditions for optimality of a guar- anteed outcome i n game problems of control. Proceedings of the Steklov Institute of Mathematics, 167, 291-304

(201 SUBBOTIN A. I. & SLTBBOTINA N. N. (1983) Diflerentiabil- ity properties of the value function of a diflerential game with integral terminal costs. Problems of Control and Information Theory, 12, 153-166

[21] SUBBOTIN A. I. & TARASYEV A. M. (1986) Stability proper- ties of the value function of a diflerential game and viscosity so- lutions of Hamilton-Jacobi equations. Problems of Control and Information Theory, 15, 451-463

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

Looking for both single-valued and set-valued solutions t o systems of first-order partial differential inclusions is then the topic of this paper.. We present it

The problem of minimizing nonconvex nondifferentiable func- tions poses a considerable challenge to specialists in mathe- matical programming.. Most of the difficulties arise from

A main ingredient in the proof of Theorem 1.2 is the solution of a noncommutative mo- ment problem via rank preserving extensions of multivariate Hankel matrices.. It is described

An H -polyhedron is an intersection of finitely many closed half-spaces in

Sampling from the primal patches of the normal cycle numerically is an interesting problem for convex hulls of sets: In this case, it is not clear how to sample boundary points of

Keywords: directed sets, set-valued derivatives, differences of convex sets and their visu- alization, affine, semi-affine, quasi-affine maps, embedding of convex compact sets into

The basic dierences of our approach to other existing embeddings are that there are no equivalence classes (as in [13], [15]) and secondly, that dierences of directed convex sets in R

The results are applied to the numerical approximation of reachable sets of linear control problems by quadrature formulae and interpolation techniques for set-valued mappings..