• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

The Keynesian multiplier and the Pigou effect under substitution between private and public consumption

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "The Keynesian multiplier and the Pigou effect under substitution between private and public consumption"

Copied!
10
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Munich Personal RePEc Archive

The Keynesian multiplier and the Pigou effect under substitution between private and public consumption

Corchon, Luis

Carlos III

21 April 2009

Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/18764/

MPRA Paper No. 18764, posted 20 Nov 2009 14:29 UTC

(2)

Working Paper 09-64 Departamento de Economía

Economic Series (39) Universidad Carlos III de Madrid

September 2009 Calle Madrid, 126

28903 Getafe (Spain) Fax (34) 916249875

THE KEYNESIAN MULTIPLIER AND THE PIGOU EFFECT UNDER SUBSTITUTION BETWEEN PRIVATE

AND PUBLIC CONSUMPTION

*

Luis C. Corchón Departament of Economics

Universidad Carlos III

First version April 21th 2009. This version September 9th 2009.

Abstract

In this paper we present a fixprice model in which private and public consumption show some degree of substitution. We offer formulae for the Keynesian multiplier which depend on this degree of substitution. We also show that there is a Pigou effect and that, sometimes, this effect is larger than the Keynesian multiplier.

*

The author acknowledges comments from Alberto Alonso and financial support from

(3)

1. INTRODUCTION

Current economic events have fueled a lively discussion about the best way to …ght unemployment. This paper is an attempt to discuss this issue in a simple static macroeconomic model in which:

1. Agents maximize utility subject to budget constraint and given prices.

2. Goods and money markets clear but, for exogenous reasons that are not discussed in this paper, the labor market does not clear.1

Our model is very stylized: There is only one input, labor, which produces a consumption good under constant returns to scale. The latter assumption simpli…es the supply side of the economy by making supply in…nitely elastic and together with our assumption of perfect competition implies that there are no pro…ts. Since neither the responsiveness of supply to demand nor the distri- bution of income are at the stake in current discussions this is not a harmful as- sumption. Money is the only asset and it is demanded because it is an argument in the utility function. This choice of modelling is dictated by simplicity, see Blanchard and Fischer (1989). The government obtains all revenue on a linear income tax again an assumption brought about by simplicity. Finally, monetary wages are given.2 Thus, important considerations for the understanding of the crisis such as productivity growth, capital/investment, indirect taxation, mo- nopolistic competition, stock market and increasing/decreasing returns to scale are outside the scope of this paper.

Following an idea of Bailey (1971), see also Barro (1981), we consider the possible substitution between private and public consumption. For instance if publicly built schools are as good as privately built schools, an increase in the former should have some e¤ect on the private demand of the latter. Or if the government runs a de…cit, the citizens may feel that this de…cit, sooner or later, will fall on them.3 Thus in our model the utility of the representative consumer is a function of two variables. On the one hand, a linear combination of the privately and the publicly provided consumption good with weights 1 and a 2 [0;1]. On the other hand on money and the budget surplus of the government with weights 1 and b 2 [0;1]. If a = 0, the consumer feels that the publicly provided good, say bridges, is not related to the privately provided good, say, beef. Ifa= 1, the consumer takes the publicly provided consumption good, say public health care, as a perfect substitute for the privately provided consumption good, say private health care. Ifb= 0, the consumer feels that the debt (resp. surplus) incurred by the government will not be paid (resp. received) by her, because it will be paid (resp. received) in a distant future or by a future

1For a possible explanation of why wages do not adjust supply and demand of labor see Bewley (1999).

2Our model falls into the …xprice literature pioneered by Barro and Grossman (1976), Benassy (1975), Drèze (1975), Malinvaud (1977) and Younès (1975). See Silvestre (1982) for a general view on this literature.

3This is the issue behind the "Ricardian equivalence".

1

(4)

generation. Ifb = 1, the consumer takes the government debt (resp. surplus) as an immediate decrease (resp. increase) in her wealth. b can be interpreted as the percentage of the current de…cit paid by the current generation. Similar preferences have been considered by Heijdra, Ligthart and van der Ploeg (1998) in the framework of Monopolistic Competition and by Linnemann and Schabert (2003) in a New Keynesian model. Our main results are:

1. When the increase in public expenditure is …nanced entirely by taxes or b= 1, i.e. the de…cit is discounted as an immediate reduction in wealth, the Keynesian multiplier is 1 a. When publicly and privately provided consumption goods are not related (a= 0) this is the well-known result that the multiplier of the balanced budget is one.

2. When the increase in public expenditure is …nanced by a de…cit the mul- tiplier is decreasing in both a and b. When the goods o¤ered by the government and the private sector are not related (a=b= 0) we obtain a formula that is identical to the textbook Keynesian multiplier.

3. When written in terms of elasticities, instead of the usual formulation of a ratio of increments, the Keynesian multiplier is always smaller than one.

This means that an increase in public expenditure of x% increases total output in less thanx%.

4. The Pigou e¤ect, namely the e¤ect on real wealth of a decrease in prices, in terms of elasticities is, also, smaller than one. When the increase in public expenditure is …nanced entirely by taxes ora=b= 1the elasticity associated with the Pigou e¤ect is larger than the elasticity of the Key- nesian multiplier. Ifa=b= 0the Keynesian multiplier is larger than its Pigouvian counterpart for "reasonable" values of the parameters.

2. THE MODEL

There are two goods consumed with prices denoted bypand1. The second good will be called money from now on. There is an input, labor, whose price is denoted by!. Good1 is produced under constant returns to scale and units are chosen such that the marginal cost of this good is !. Assuming that the economy is perfectly competitive,

p=!: (1)

The government raises funds by a tax on income (I) with a constant tax ratet, and buys goods1 and2 in quantities GandS. While Gis positive, S can be positive (surplus) or negative (de…cit). The government budget constraint is

pG+S=tI: (2)

(5)

There is a representative consumer with preferences representable by a Cobb- Douglas utility function

U =A(x+aG) (M+bS)1

wherexis the consumption of good 1,M is the consumption of money,A >0, 2(0;1)anda; b2[0;1]. When a=b= 1 the consumer considers thatGand S are perfect substitutes of private consumption and wealth. Whena=b= 0 the consumer does not take into considerationGandS. This may be because she considers public expenditure as a total waste (like certain public works) and that the debt arising from the de…cit will paid in a distant future, perhaps by a di¤erent generation. Another interpretation ofa= 0is that the government produces a di¤erent good (bridges) whose price, by taking units, can also be taken as!. This good a¤ectsAmaking the consumer better o¤ but it does not a¤ect her consumption choices. Compare with Heijdra, Ligthart and van der Ploeg (1998) equation (1) and Linnemann and Schabert (2003) equation (2).

The representative consumer has endowments of labor and money ofLand M respectively. Her budget constraint is

px+M =I(1 t): (3)

Adding (2) and (3), we get thatpG+S+px+M =I. Since pro…ts are zero and wages are obtained producingGorx, income is de…ned as I=!G+!x+M. Taking into account (1);the last two equalities imply thatS+M =M. Thus, when the public sector runs a surplus (S >0),M < M. A public sector de…cit (S <0) impliesM > M :

From utility maximization at given prices and income, demand functions are x = (I(1 t) +bS)

p (1 )aG, (4)

M = (1 )(I(1 t) +apG) bS (5)

2. 1. Market Clearing Equilibrium

In a market-clearing equilibrium all markets clear. Denoting the variable, say,z in a market-clearing equilibrium aszC (C for clearing) we have that

xC+G = L: (6)

IC = !CL+M. (7)

Notice that the real GDP of our economy isxC+Gwhich, given our choice of units, is justL. From (4), (6) and (7) prices and wages in a market-clearing equilibrium are

pC =!C= (M S(1 b))

(1 )(L G(1 a)): (8)

3

(6)

Thus prices and wages increase with the money supply, the de…cit (unlessb= 1) and the public expenditure (unlessa= 1) and decrease with the labor supply.

From (6) consumption of good1in a market-clearing equilibrium is

xC=L G (9)

Thus, consumption of good1increases with resources and decreases with public expenditure in a one-by-one basis independently of the parametera.

2.2. Non Clearing Equilibrium

In a no clearing labor market equilibrium, non clearing for short, the supply of labor exceeds the demand of labor denoted byLN. All other markets clear.

Let us denote the variables in such an equilibrium by the superscriptN (N for non clearing). Thus,

LN = xN +G. (10)

pN = !N: (11)

Now the income of the consumer is determined by the actual production, namely IN =!N(xN +G) +M : (12) Taking into account (11) and (4) we have that

xN = (IN(1 t) +bS)

!N (1 )aG: (13)

Plugging (12) and (2) in (13) and using (10) we have that xN = (M S(1 b))

!N(1 ) aG (14)

LN = (M S(1 b))

!N(1 ) +G(1 a) (15)

From (15) we see thatL > LN

!N > (M S(1 b))

(1 )(L G(1 a)) =!C (16)

Thus it can be said that, in this model, unemployment arises because wages are too high.4 This is just a wat of saying that our model embodies a Pigou e¤ect where a decrease in prices may increase GDP.

Let us make a simple calibration exercise. Despite the fact that, as noticed in the introduction, our economy has very stylized features, this exercise might throw some light on our model. In order to obtain possible values for the parameters, divide both sides of (15) by the GDP,LN. We interpret LNM!N as

4The same happens in the venerable IS-LM model.

(7)

the velocity of money and we will denote this magnitude byv. De…ningg LGN and s LSN = t g as, respectively, the fractions of public expenditure and de…cit in GDP, (15) yields

(1 )(1 g(1 a)) = (1

v s(1 b)): (17)

From (13) we interpret as the marginal propensity to consume. Letting

=:8; g 2 [:3; :5]and s 2 [ :03; :05] in (17) we see that depending on the values ofaandb,v ranges between4and13:333, not very di¤erent from what is shown in real data. Notice that (17) implies that ifg andsare constant the velocity of money is constant too.

3. THE KEYNESIAN MULTIPLIER

Recall that the government can not chooseS; Gandtsimultaneously. Equa- tion (15) involves the de…cit and public expenditure, so it is the appropriate equation to work with when the strategies of the government are these two vari- ables. Thus in this case, the tax rate is adjusted to satisfy (2). In this case we see that the Keynesian multiplier is

@LN

@G = 1 a (18)

which in the best case scenario (i.e. when public consumption does not a¤ect the private consumption or a = 0) is one and in the extreme case in which public and private consumption are perfect substitutes it is zero. The former corresponds to the well-known result that the multiplier with a balanced budget is one. Writing the multiplier in terms of elasticities we have that

@LN

@G G

LN = (1 a)g <1:

Suppose now that the strategies of the government are t and G. In this case the de…cit (or surplus) takes the toll of the adjustment. After lengthy calculations we obtain that

LN =

M

!N(1 (1 b)t) +G(a a b + 1)

(1 ) + (1 b)t (19)

Now the Keynesian multiplier is

@LN

@G = a(1 ) + 1 b

(1 ) + (1 b)t: (20)

Notice that, as intuition suggests, the larger a the smaller the value of the multiplier. In the extreme case in which a=b = 0 the multiplier is 1 1(1 t) which, interpreting again as the marginal propensity to consume, is just the

5

(8)

textbook Keynesian multiplier. But when b = 1, i.e. when the e¤ect of debt is fully anticipated, the multiplier is, again,1 a, never larger than one. Our expressions (18) and (20) generalize those obtained by Bailey (1971), Chapter 9, Table 1 for the limiting cases whereaandbare either0 or1.

Again writing the multiplier in terms of elasticity

@LN

@G G

LN = ( a(1 ) + 1 b )pNG

M(1 (1 b)t) +pNG( a(1 ) + 1 b )<1: (21)

4. THE PIGOU EFFECT

The …xprice model is an interesting scenario to study the so called "Pigou e¤ect" in which a decrease in prices/wages increases employment via increases in real wealth.5 Let us consider …rst the case in which the de…cit is constant.

In this case, from (15) the multiplier associated with the Pigou e¤ect is:

@LN

@pN = (M (1 b)S)

(1 )(pN)2 : (22)

Writing the previous expression in terms of elasticities,

@LN

@pN pN

LN = (M (1 b)S)

(M (1 b)S) + (1 )pNG(1 a) = 1 g(1 a): (23) Clearly, the elasticity associated with the Keynesian multiplier is larger than the elasticity associated with the Pigouvian multiplier i¤

2g(1 a)>1: (24)

Even in the most favorable case for the Keynesian multiplier, i.e. a = 0, the inequality (24) requires that the ratio public expenditure/GDP be larger than a half. So if the de…cit is constant, we should expect better results on employment from a pro-competitive policy which facilitates price decreases rather than from public expenditure.

Suppose now that the strategies of the government aretandG. In this case the Pigouvian multiplier is

@LN

@pN = M(1 (1 b)t)

((1 ) + (1 b)t)(!N)2. (25) Writing the Pigou multiplier in terms of elasticities, we have that

@LN

@pN pN

LN = M(1 (1 b)t)

M(1 (1 b)t) +pNG(a a b + 1) <1: (26)

5The current crisis has caused a moderate de‡iation in many countries. Thus, prices decreased in Great Britain .4% in March 2009 and .1% in Spain in the same period.

(9)

From (21) and (26) we obtain that the elasticity associated with the Keynesian multiplier is larger than the elasticity associated with the Pigouvian multiplier i¤( a(1 ) + 1 b )pNG > M(1 (1 b)t), or

( a(1 ) + 1 b )gv > (1 (1 b)t) (27) In this case the comparison is ambiguous. Ifa=b= 1the Pigouvian multiplier is larger than its Keynesian counterpart. Ifa=b= 0the Keynesian multiplier is larger than its Pigouvian counterpart if and only if gv > (1 t). This inequality holds for the kind of values of g; v and considered in the simple calibration exercise performed at the end of Section 4.

5. CONCLUSIONS

In this paper we have presented a simple …xprice model in which public and private consumption might be substitutes. We have shown that the value of the multiplier depends on this degree of substitution. In particular when de…cits are fully incorporated into wealth we get a "Ricardian Equivalence" result, see Benassy (2007) for a similar result in a di¤erent framework. We also have shown that the Pigou e¤ect exists in our …xprice model and that, sometimes, it is stronger than the Keynesian multiplier. This is, of course, not an argument against public expenditure as a means of increasing employment. But it raises the point that, sometimes, a policy of de‡ation may have even better results in terms of increasing employment. The latter policy was considered dangerous by Keynes ([1936], Chapter 19) because of its e¤ects on price expectations. We plan to study this question more carefully in a subsequent paper.

REFERENCES

Bailey, Martin J. (1971). National Income and the Price Level: A Study in Macroeconomic Theory. 2d ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Barro, Robert J. (1981). "Output E¤ects of Government Purchases". The Journal of Political Economy, 89, 6, 1086-1121.

Barro, Robert J. and Herschel I. Grossman (1976).Money, Employment and In‡ation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

Benassy, Jean-Pascal (1975). “Neo-Keynesian disequilibrium theory in a monetary economy”.Review of Economic Studies42, 503–23.

Benassy, Jean-Pascal (2007). "Ricardian equivalence and the intertemporal Keynesian multiplier". Economics Letters, 94, 1, 118-123.

Bewley, Truman F. (1999). Why Wages Don’t Fall during a Recession. Cam- bridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

Blachard, Olivier J. and Stanley Fischer (1989). Lectures on Macroeco- nomics. MIT Press

Drèze, Jacques (1975). “Existence of an exchange equilibrium under price rigidities”.International Economic Review 16, 301–20.

7

(10)

Heijdra, B., J. E. Ligthart and F. van der Ploeg (1998). "Fiscal Policy, Distortionary Taxation, and Direct Crowding Out under Monopolistic Compe- tition". Oxford Economic Papers 50, 79-88.

Keynes, J. M. (1936). The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.

Linnemann, L. and A. Schabert (2003). "Can …scal spending stimulate pri- vate consumption?". Economic Letters 82, 173-179.

Malinvaud, Edmond (1977). The Theory of Unemployment Reconsidered.

Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

Silvestre, Joaquim (1982). Fixprice analysis in exchange economies. Journal of Economic Theory,26, 28-58

Younès, Yves (1975). “On the role of money in the process of exchange and the existence of a non-Walrasian equilibrium”.Review of Economic Studies 42, 489–501.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

Les précurseurs de la notion de fonction d’utilité (Stanley Jevons, Carl Menger, Léon Walras et Francis Edgeworth) concevaient l’utilité comme une grandeur mesurable

The analysis suggests that in Downsian models the strong relationship be- tween the degree of income inequality among voters and the degree of govern- mental intervention in

I demonstrate that binding liquidity constraints on households can alter the efficacy of the policy changes in the four regimes—defined by the conditioning states—with

We also …nd that relaxing the public plan’s zero pro…t constraint and allowing it to run at a limited de…cit will increase the public plan’s market share, forcing the private

This paper seeks to analyses public and private investment behavior in Zimbabwe for the period spanning from 1970 to 2007, taking into account the effects of the

The results of the Cointegration vectors derived from the johansen method indicates that government investment expenditures have complimentary effects on the

The econometric tests undertaken support the view that private sector output, net capital inflows to the private sector, total sources of funds and past capital stock

To the potential participants in health insurance schemes there would also be private benefits from improved scheme performance, better value for money and the relief