• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

RISK: A Seminar Series

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "RISK: A Seminar Series"

Copied!
614
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

IlASA COLLABORATIVE PROCEEDINGS SERIES

RISK:

A SEMINAR SERIES

(2)

IIASA COLLABORATIVE PROCEEDINGS SERIES

CP-81 -Sf LARGE-SCALE LINEAR PROGRAMMING

Proceedings of an I IASA Workshop, 2--6 June 1980 G.B. Danaig, M.A.H. Dempster, and M.J. Kallio, Editon CP-81 -S2 THE SHINKANSEN PROGRAM: Transportation, Railway,

Environmental, Regional, and National Development Issues A. Straszak, Editor

CP-82-s1 HUMAN S m L E M E N T SYSTEMS: Spatial Patterns and Trends Selected Papers from an I IASA Conference on the Analysis of Human Settlement Systems

T. Kmashima and P. Korcrlli, Editors CP-82-52 RISK: A Seminar Series

H. Kunreuther, Editor

(3)

A SEMINAR SERIES

Howard Kunreuther, Editor

INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE FOR APPLIED SYSTEMS ANALYSIS Laxenburg, Austria

1981

(4)

International Standard Book Number 3-7045-0030-5

Collaborative Papers in this Special series sometimes report work done at the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis and sometimes work done elsewhere. They are given only limited review, and are issued after limited editorial attention. The views or opinions they express do not necessarily represent those of the Institute, its National Member Organizations, or other organizations supporting the work.

Copyright O 1982 International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis A-2361 Laxenburg, Austria

All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopy, recording, or any information storage or retrieval system, without permission in writing from the publisher.

(5)

PREFACE

This volume i s a compendium of risk seminars held at I IASA from October 1980 to Sep- tember 1981. Since risk i s a relatively new area of research, there is considerable variety in the way different individuals approach the subject. This has the advantage of bringing a number of viewpoints into the area from which one can begin to develop a body of evi- dence as well as a foundation for future studies. I t also presents a challenge to researchers to consolidate relevant concepts into a paradigm enabling a body of empirical research to be undertaken that will make an impact on the worlds of science and decision.

The papers in this volume present ingredients that will prove useful for future efforts in the risk field. Part.1 consists of papers that represent attempts t o develop conceptual frameworks from several different perspectives. The papers in Part II deal with the role of risk assessment and analysis as well as the concept of acceptable risk in the context of societal decision-making. Part I II contains papers that address the way laypersons as well as experts actually assess the risk associated with specific hazards. Part IV concerns meth- odological issues associated with estimating probabilities and values for uncertain events.

The concluding section (Part V ) i s devoted to alternative approaches for managing risk, such as decision analysis, communicating information, resolving conflicts, inspection, and the performance of insurance markets.

The Risk Seminars represent an attempt to increase the networking role played by IIASA. A special word of appreciation goes t o Craig Sinclair who jointly initiated these risk seminars and planned them with me until he left IlASA in December 1980. 1 am grateful to Noel Blackwell for helping to organize this volume and t o Eryl Ley for her assistance in producing the manuscript. Finally, this volume would not have been possible without the support of Alec Lee, Chairman of the Management and Technology Area, Andrzej Wierzbicki, Chairman of the System and Decision Sciences Area, Roger Levien, former Director of IIASA, and C.S. Holling, Director of IIASA, who have encouraged the Risk Group in i t s efforts.

HOWARD KUNREUTHER March 1982

(6)
(7)

CONTENTS

PART l CONCEPTUAL ISSUES I N RISK

Decision Making for Low Probability Events: A Conceptual Framework

Howard Kunreuther

The Cultural Approach to Risk: The Case of Poverty Michael Thompson

Organisational Responses t o Hazard Barry A. Turner

Society and Problem-Oriented Research: On the Socio-Political Functions of Risk Assessment

J. Conrad

PART II RISK ANALYSIS ISSUES Reflections on Risk Assessment Alvin M. Weinberg

Risks of Risk Decisions

Chauncey Starr and Chris Whipple

Risk Management and Acceptable Risk Criteria Harry J. Otway and Detlof von Winterfeldt Value Structures Underlying Risk Assessments Patrick Humphre ys

PART Ill MEASURING RlSK

"The Public" Vs. "The Experts": Perceived Vs. Actual Disagreements About Risks

Baruch Fischhoff, Paul Slovic, and Sarah Lichtenstein Psychological Aspects of Risk: The Assessment of Threat and Control

P.J. M. Stallen and A. Tomas

(8)

Quantitative Risk Assessment for Health and Safety Regulation 24 1 Lester B. Lave

Developing Safety Criteria F. Niehaus and E. Swaton

Risk with Energy from Conventional and IVonconventional Sources

Herbert lnhaber

PART I V METHODOLOGICAL ISSUES I N RlSK Marginal Value and Intrinsic Risk Aversion David E. Bell and Howard Raiffa

Information and Modeling in Risk Assessment Robert L. Win kler

Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice Richard Thaler

PART V APPROACHES FOR MANAGING RISK

Decision Analysis for the Evaluation of Risk in Nuclear Waste Management

John W. Lathrop and Stephen R. Watson

Communicating Environmental Health Risk Assessment and

Other Risk Information: Analysis of Strategies 421

Ilan Vertinsky and Patricia Vertinsky

The Role of Risk Perception in Establishing a Rational

Energy Policy for W. Europe 483

Richard Caputo

Energy, Engineering Inspection, and the Safe Use of Nuclear Power

Octavius Hunt Critchley

Competition, Ownership and Control in Markets with Imperfect Information: The Case of the German Liability

and Life Insurance Markets 563

Jorg Finsinger

(9)

PART l

CONCEPTUAL ISSUES I N RISK

(10)
(11)

DECISION M A K I N G FOR LOW PROBABILITY EVENTS:

A CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK*

Howard Kunreuther

International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria

Recent empirical evidence from field surveys and controlled laboratory experiments reveal anomalies with respect to decisions by individuals t o protect themselves against low prob- ability. high loss events. In particular, behavior is frequently at odds with what would be predicted by standard models of choice which involve benefitcon comparisons.

Th~s paper develops a framework for analyzing decisions for low probability events and discusses their policy implications. The framework highlights the following four inter- related components:

(1) Type of information collected by individuals in making their decisions (i.e., accuracy of data on losses, probabilities and protective options);

( 2 ) The decision process of individuals (e.9.. expected utility maximization, threshold models);

(3) Implications of policies on specific groups (e.9.. affected individuals, general taxpayers); and

(4) Welfare implications (e.g., equity and efficiency considerations).

Examples from nudies on natural hazards, health and safety problems will be used to illustrate how this framework synthesizes descriptive models of choice with policy pre- scription. The paper concludes by suggesting directions for future research.

'The remarch mporred In rh~s paper Is supportad by rhe Bundnm~n~snr~urn fur Fonchung und T r h - nologla F R G mnrran no 321175911RGB 8001 Wh~le support for ch~r w r k 1% gratefully u.

knowledged. the vlawr axpressed am rhe author's o w , and e n not r y a r u r ~ l y tharad by tha sponsor.

(12)

I.

INTRODUCTION*

Society has become increasingly concerned with developing appropriate m e a s u r e s lor mitigating t h e consequences of low probability events which have potentially large losses. It should be recognized a t t h e o u t s e t t h a t what is a low probability event for one interested p a r t y may be viewed a s a high probability event for another. Similarly, t h e relative magnitude of t h e losses is also a func- tion of where one sits. For example, t h e chances of suUering a severe p r o p e r t y loss from a natural disaster or a severe injury from a n automobile accident may be viewed a s very small by a single individual but t r e a t e d a s relatively high by a government agency concerned w i t h national losses. P r o p e r t y damage from a Bre may a p p e a r staggering to t h e d e c t e d family but s e e m relatively small a t a m o r e aggregate level because of t h e different bases u s e d to evaluate conse- quences.

ms

p a p e r proposes a conceptual framework for dealing with events which a r e perceived t o have a small c h a n c e of o c c u r r e n c s by a t Least one of t h e i n t e r e s t e d parties. The approach emphasizes t h e i m p o r t a n c e of undertaking descriptive analysis as a critical input for prescriptive recommendations.

After o u t b i n g t h e framework (Section 11). I will illustrate its applicability in Section 111 with several examples which have both personal significance (e.g..

safety of power mowers and motor vehicles) a s well a s societal importance (e.g..

siting of L V C facilities). The importance of understanding decision processes a s 1 would like t o thsnlc Uday Apte for helping t o gather material an the lllutrative examples

&cussed in section I1 of the paper.

(13)

a critical input to policy is underscored by empirical data on individual decision making with respect to insurance protection against natural hazards. Section IV summarizes key results from a large-scale field survey and controlled laboratory experiments which comprised this four-year study and illustrates t h e possible roles t h a t the public and private sectors can play in providing b e t t e r protection against future losses. In t h e concluding section. a more formal model is pro- posed which incorporates the decision processes and the role of inlormation as critical inputs, for developing prescriptive measures.

F e u r e 1 depicts a conceptual framework for structuring t h e analysis. An appropriate starting point is Problem Formulation (Box 1). Before undertaking a detailed analysis one needs t o identify and define the problem. What a r e the goals a n d objectives corresponding to the particular a r e a of concern? Can one gain insight into the nature of the problem through an historical perspective?

This initial d e h i t i o n a l phase is critically important a s it enables one t o under- take a detailed descriptive or behavioral analysis which can then be linked to alternative strategies. Furthermore, i t helps limit the types f policies o r plans t h a t a r e relevant and provides guidelines for evaluating them.

P

Figure 1. Conceptual framework for analysis structure

Let us turn now to the descriptive phase. We need to define and describe explicitly the anterested parties (Box 2 ) impacted by the problem. Three sectors a r e considered in the illustrative examples which follow: consumers (i.e.. those who demand the particular products or a r e directly or indirectly afTected by it);

firms o r enterprises (i.e., the organizations or business or supply the product);

and government (i.e., public sector agencies or bureaus who interact with the private sector-consumers and enterprises). For each problem there a r e a s e t of legal and political constraints whlch determine how information currently flows between the chree sectors and the groups within each sector. It is important to understand t h e dynamics of thls interaction: who interacts with whom, and w h e n this interaction takes place.

The other key element of the descriptive phase is the decision processes (Box 3) of each of the involved interested parties. By decision processes we

(14)

mean t h e collection and processing of information relevant to the problem being analyzed. Recent empirical evidence from field a n d experimental studies have revealed systematic biases with r e s p e c t to the processing of information and simplified rules in combining data in malang decisions (FischhoU, e t al. 1980:

Kunreuther. e t al. 1978; a n d Tversky and Kahneman 1974). These findings shed considerable light on the relative importance of external events. such a s p a s t experience, as well a s internal dynamics, such a s discussions with others. in influencing decisions on low probability events. It is t h u s clear t h a t t h e collec- tion a n d processing of information a r e Likely to be closely tied t o t h e relevant constraints and t h e interactions between t h e interested parties.

Turning now t o the prescriptive phase, t h e r e is a need to j o n n u l a t e a l t m a - f i v e p l a n s or courses of actions (Box 4) for coping with a particular problem. The generation of goals and objectives for any problem will suggest a s e t of plans t o be considered. TWO types of institutional arrangements between t h e interested parties circumscribe t h e types of plans which can be considered. One e r t r e m e is for consumers and firms t o i n t e r a c t through a m a r k e t s y s t e m without a n y government involvement. The o t h e r e x t r e m e is for government t o impose strict regulations which gives t h e private s e c t o r no freedom of choice. Most strategies a r e between t h e s e two extremes: t h e government s e c t o r utilizes incentives such as subsidies and taxes along with some regulations a n d information exchange t o guide consumer a n d firm m a r k e t interactions.

Finally, t h e r e is a need t o g v d u t e plans (Box 5 ) . How well diflerent poli- cies perform will be influenced by t h e decision processes of t h e i n t e r e s t e d par- ties. The rankmg of 'dinerent policies is also contingent upon t h e relative impor- tance given to t h e interested parties. If residents in hazard-prone a r e a s a r e deemed important enough t o merit special t r e a t m e n t after a disaster, then Strategy A may be much more appealing t h a n Strategy

B.

On t h e other hand, if disaster victims a r e deemed responsible lor their o m recovery, then Strategy

B

m a y be s e e n a s preferable to Strategy A. In evaluating different measures one has t h e enforcement costs which utilize government funds. t o include t h e compliance costs which m u s t be p

9

by t h e sellers a s well a s

111. ILLUSTRATIVE !iXA!!fPLES

The framework depicted in Figure 1 can be applied to a s e t of problems which lnvolve protective measures to reduce the probability of a n event or miti- gate its consequences. The section begins with those which involve personal safety and conclude with broader societal issues. The purpose of these illustra- tions is to show how t h e framework can s t r u c t u r e analysis; no detailed evalua- tion of alternatives is undertaken.

S a f e r P o w e r Mowers

Should power mowers be made safer? Each year approximately 75.000 peo- ple ccme in contact with moving power mower blades which can cause severe injuries. Nearly 10.000 o i the blade-contact injuries involve amputations of fingers or toes (Washington Post 1979a). The problem involves a tradeofl between the costs of producing a safer mower and t h e reduction in injuries which presumably would result. In this case, the relevant i n t e r e s t e d parties a r e

(15)

the homeowner or gardener who has or deslres a power mower: the lawn mower industry; and the Consumer Products Safety Commission (CPSC). the regulatory agency with the responsibility for approving safety standards in this area.

The decision processes of consumers plays a critical role in evaluating any policy. If individuals a r e careless because they feel t h a t n0thir.g c a n happen t o them when they utilize a mower, then it may be necessary to make power mowers safdr. In addition, or as an alternative, warnings could be provided on t h e dangers of,the mower (e.g.. not to use it on wet grass). Fow well this mfor'- mation is actually processed by individuals determines how well such a policy works.

With respect to a l t e r n a t i v e plans. q e CPCS has proposed mandatory safety s t a n d a r d s in designing power mowers. Industry claims t h a t this regulation, which would increase t h e cost of a power mower by $35, is too strong.

In

o v a l u d i n g t h e s e plans questions of product Liability arise: Is the m , < ~ u f a c t u r e r responsible should t h e r e be an injury from a mower? A r e c e n t case awarded

$6000 t o a man who lost p a r t of his foot in a lawn mower. The company claimed t h a t t h e accident, which occurred because the person's foot slipped on wet grass, could have been avoided had h e r e a d the user manual which warned : "Do not use this mower on Wet Crass." In this case ignorance was considered a n excuse and t h e claim was upheld (Business Week, February 12. 1979).

Motor Vehicle S a f e t y

What a r e t h e appropriate safety m e a s u r e s for reducing d e a t h s and injuries from motor vehicles? This question has some significance when one studies t h e statistics for the U n ~ t e d States: "In 1977, motor vehicles caused 47.700 deaths, 1,900,000 disabling injuries. and approximately $12 billion in property damage"

(Bick a n d Hohenemser 1979). At present less t h a n 20% of t h e drivers o r passengers in private vehicles protect themselves by wearlng s e a t belts even though they a r e installed in all cars. Here, t h e p r c b l e m involves t h e t m d e o f s between personal freedom a n d possible adverse consequences to individuals and society when people do not voluntarily protect themselves. The relevant i n t e r e s t e d p a r t i e s a r e t h e drivers and passengers, the automobile industry, and t h e National Highway Traffic Safety Administration. the regulatory agency empowered t o deal with motor v e h c l e safety.

Echoing t h e same t h e m e a s above, the decision processes of consumers a r e critically important tor designing prescriptive measures. Empirical evidence from laboratory studies suggests t h a t one reason people do not voluntarily t a k e protective action such as wearing safety belts, is because they feel t h a t t h e pro- bability of a n accident is so small t h a t t h e y don't have to worry about it (Slovic.

e t al. 1978). A survey conducted by National Analysts (1971) for t h e Department of Transportation revealed that those most likely t o wear belts a r e ones who have b e e n asked by o t h e r s to wear them. This raises t h e question of the impor- tance of personal influence in the decision makmg process.

At a policy level t h e r e a r e several options which can be considered. Market mechanisms such as lower insurance premiums for c a r s equipped with passive r e s t r a n t s (e.g.. automatic belts or air bags) could encourage people to volun- tarily adopt these measures. Some countries do not pay insurance claims for tnjuries if it is shown t h a t the individual has not protected himself with a safety belt, thereby providing economic incentives for individuals t o use them. A stronger measure, utilized in some countries is to impose a fine for those not

(16)

wearing t h e belt. An e x r r e m e m e a s u r e would b e to require t h a t all a u t o s be equipped with a passive r e s t r a i n t . Each of t h e s e m e a s u r e s has t o be evaluated on a n u m b e r of h m e n s i o n s , t h e most i m p o r t a n t being t h e costs of imposing t h e p a r t i c u l a r approach a n d t h e potential benefits. As in all t h e e s a m p i e s in this section s o m e p a r t i e s will b e helped while o t h e r s will suffer de?ending on which alternative is chosen.

Cigarette Smoking

Should one impose r e s t r i c t i o n s o n c i g a r e t t e s t o d e t e r ~ndividuals from smolnng a n d if so how should this be done? This question is s t i m u l a t e d by empirical d a t a which suggests t h a t annually 350,000 lives a r e lost a n d a p p r o r i - mately $18 billion In hospital bills a r e i n c u r r e d f r o m diseases c a u s e d by smoking (Washington Post 1979b). The relevant inlerested parties a r e s m o k e r s , non- s m o k e r s , t h e tobacco industry a n d t h e Office of Smolung and Health, a regula- t o r y agency c o n c e r n e d with t h e eflects of c i g a r e t t e smoking.

The decision processes of s m o k e r s a r e critical t o t h e d e s ~ g n of alternative policies. If individuals a r e aware t h a t smokmg is h a r m f u l to t h e m b u t ignore t h e s e potential effects, e i t h e r because t h e y feel "nothing will h a p p e n t o m e , "

t h e n additional information campaigns a r e unlikely t o c h a n g e behavior. There is also t h e question a s t o how sensitive t h e s m o k e r is t o price changes in c i g a r e t t e s should additional t a x e s be imposed.

The s p e c t r u m of a l t m a t i ~ e p l a n s r a n g e from m a r k e t solutions (do nothing a n d let people sutTer t h e consequences) t o s t r i c t regulation (banning cigarettes). Recent proposals have involved a s e t of incentive s y s t e m s , s u c h a s increasing t a x e s and using t h e revenue t o help s m o k e r s quit (Harris 1980). o r p r o h b i t i n g smoking in c e r t a i n public places (e.g.. hospitals, t h e a t e r s , and retail s t o r e s ) (Washington Post 1979b). In evaluating t h e s e plans one recognizes t h a t diAerent importance weights on t h e relevant i n t e r e s t e d p a r t i e s may l e a d t o different rankings. F3r example. a policy of "da nothing" favors t h e s m o k e r s a n d t h e tobacco industry wt..LLe banning c i g a r e t t e ? has t h e reverse effect. Taxation policies a n d fines for smoking in c e r t a i n places falls somewhere between t h e above two e x t r e m e s .

Siting o f L N C Facllztzes

Liquefied natural gas ( L N G ) 1s a potential s o u r c e of energy which requires a fairly ccrnpllcated techr.oicgica1 process t h a t has t h e potential. albeit with very low probability, of creating severe Losses. To import LNG t h e gas has to be con- verted t o Liquid form a t a b o u t 1,'600 t h e volume. It 1s shipped in specially con- s t r u c t e d t a n k e r s a c d received a t a t e r m i n a l where it undergoes regasification and is t h e n d s t r i b u t e d . The e n t i r e s y s t e m (i.e., t h e l~quefication facility, t h e LNG t a n k e r and the rece:vlng t e r m i n a l a n d regasification Facil~ty) c a n c o s t m o r e t h a n $1 billion t o c o n s t r u c t ( O f i c e of Technology Assessment 1977). The slting problem of i n t e r e s t 1s whether one should locate facilities for r e g a s ~ f y i n g and s h i p p ~ n g LNG a n d ~f so where would be the b e s t piace. The m l e r e s t e d parties a r e t h e r e s i d e n t s of a r e a s c9tistdered a s potential sites, those benefiting from this additional s o u r c e of energy, t h e g a s companies or consortium who a r e willing to invest m a proposed pro,ect and governmenr, apencles a t t h e Federal. s t a t e . and

(17)

local level who have responsibility tor trading of! the costs (including potential losses from an accident) and benefits ot any decision.

Turning now to the decision process associated with siting, there a r e ques- tions as to how each of the groups utilize information on the probability of any accident to an LNG terminal and the resulting consequences. One of the contro- versies emerging in the siting debate is whether one can or should specify an acceptable level of risk. Some risk assessments of a particular site focus on the chances of a catastrophic accident and conclude that it is acceptable if the pro- bability is below some critical level Others have utilized worst case scenarios and paid attention to the consequences without paying much attention to the chances of its o ~ c u r r e n c e . ~ There is also a need to understand how the diaerent interested parties weigh the s d e t y issue in relation to other concerns of a siting policy such a s the economic impacts, e a e c t s on the environment and how LNG s e m s national energy policy.

The formulation of alternative strategies will be greatly impacted by t h e decision process of the diaerent parties. One way of clarifying M e r e n c e s between the groups is t o specify who is responsible for damages should an accident occur. If the location of an LNG facility is viewed primarily a s a private venture, then some form of insurance should be oaered to gas companies t o pro- t e c t them against catastrophic losses. If this type of coverage is not available on the private market. then government may have to provide this protection. A complementary set of plans may involve compensating residents of a proposed siting a r e a for decreases in their real estate value and perhaps provide them with lower energy rates in r e t u r n for their increased risk in the future. An alter- native is to pass regulations such as the one by the Department of Energy which requires t h a t new sites be in remote a r e a s or in locations with relatively small population densities.

N. INSURANCE AGAINST NATL.RAL

HAZARDS~

Let us now turn to a more detailed s t r d y of homeowner decisions on whether to protect themselves against the consequences of natural hazards.

The results raise a s e t of policy-related issues. They also shed light on the deci- sion processes individuals are ldcely to use when dealing with situations such as' those discussed in the previous section.

Problem Formulation

The problem of interest is the appropriate role of the public and private sectors in providing insurance protection against the consequences of natural hazards and relief in the aftermath of a disaster. An tustoricai perspective with respect to this problem is relevant here. Annual losses from natural disasters in the United States is frequently over $1 billion dollars. Relatively few homeown- ers have voluntarily purchased insurance against the consequences of floods and earthquakes. even though coverage is easily avadable and in the case of floods highly subsidized by the federal government. In the past, the U.S government has responded to the financial plight of the uninsured victims by providing liberal relief in the form of low interest loans and grants to a ~ d the recovery efforts.

(18)

Evidence o n increased federal d i s a s t e r relief is provlded by comparative d a t a on t h e Small Business Administrat,ion (SEA) d i s a s t e r loan program. The growth of t h e program is easily s e e n i n Figure 2; t h e i n c r e a s e is particularly significant in t h e c a s e of home loans where both t h e t o t a l n u m b e r a n d t o t a l dol- l a r values in t h e 1968-76 period were m o r e t h a n 25 t i m e s what t h e y were in t h e Arst 1 2 y e a r s of t h e program. I t is striking t h a t t h e $1.2 billion approved by t h e SEA for victims of Tropical S t o r m Agnes r e p r e s e n t e d almost four t i m e s t h e e n t i r e a m o u n t allocated by t h e SEA For all d i s a s t e r s between fiscal y e a r s 1954 a n d 1965. Over $540 million of t h e a m o u n t approved by t h e SBA for victims of t h i s d i s a s t e r w e r e in t h e form of forgiveness g r a n t s w h c h did not have t o be r e p a i d

Figure 2. Small business administration d i s a s t e r loans.

Interested Parties

Insurance against floods is provided by the Federal I n s u r a n c e Adrninistra- tion with tughly subsidized r a t e s on existing property: new p r o p e r t y is c h a r g e d a p r e m i u m based on e s t i m a t e d risk. For i n s u r a n c e t o be oflered t o residents a n d businesses in a hazard-prone region, t h e c o m m u n i t y m u s t a g r e e t o a d o p t land use regulations and building codes t o r e d u c e f u t u r e losses f r o m t h e hazard.

E a r t h q u a k e coverage is offered t o t h e public by private companies. Even though coverage is not expensive ($2 p e r SlOOO coverage on wood-frame homes in Cali- fornia with a 5% deductible), less t h a n 3% of t h e homeowners in t h i s earthquake- p r o n e s t a t e have bought this Insurance.

The i n t e r e s t e d p a r t i e s for this problem are t h u s t h e F e d e r a l Insurance Administration ( a government agency), t h e p r ~ v a t e i n s u r a n c e industry (i.e., companies and a g e n t s ) , t h e Small Business Admin~stration. t h e residents in hazard-prone areas. a n d t h e general t a x p a y e r who covers t h e subsidized portion of flood coverage and t h e subsidized portion of d i s a s t e r relief.

(19)

Decision Processes

What are the factors w h c h influence individuals to purchase insurance pro- tection against relatively low probability events such a s floods and earthquakes?

To answer this question fleld survey questionnaires and controlled laboratory experiments were undertaken. The field survey involved face-to-face interviews with 2.055 homeowners residing in 43 areas throughout the United States sub- ject t o coastal and riverine flooding, and 1,008 homeowners living in 18 earthquake-prone areas of California. Half the respondents had purchased flood or earthquake insurance, the other half had not. The controlled laboratory experiments undertaken by Paul Slovic. Baruch Rschhoff, and Sarah Lichten- stein, a t Decision Research, shed light on the causal relationships between vari- ables entering into the 'insurance decision. A few of t h e key Bndings from this study which relate t o individual decision processes a r e now summarized

Although most uninsured homeowners interviewed were aware that flood and earthquake coverage existed, the majority were unaware t h a t they were eli- gible to purchase a policy. Those who were aware had no reliable knowledge of the costs of a policy. The subsidized flood rate is between $2.50 and $3.50 per

$1000 coverage depending on the proportion of coverage devoted to structure and contents. The earthquake premium on wood-frame homes in California averages $2 per $1000. Hence any homeowner estimating the respective rates between $2 and $4 for flood coverage and $1 and $3 for earthquake insurance was classided a s reasonably accurate. Figure 3 shows that most of the insured homeowners were accurate in their estimate or underestimated t h e premium.

Few uninsured individuals had accurate information and a large proportion ovenstimated the premium. This finding suggests t h a t the uninsured individu- als had not made any conscious efTort to obtain information on rates from their insurance agent even if they knew coverage was available.

u r n X L U-m < a cn n-a .a u u r .

h..r b.

Figure 3. Subjective e s t ~ r n a t e s of insurance premium (per $1.000 coverage)

(20)

With r e s p e c t to t h e hazard itself, both insured and unirisured individuals had imperfect information on t h e probability and consequences of a severe flood or earthquake causing damage to their property and contents. When h o m e o m - e r s were asked to estimate the chance of a severe flood o r earthquake damaging their property in t h e next year. 15 p e r c e n t of t h e respondents in flood a r e a s and 0 p e r c e n t of those in earthquake are-, were unable t o provide any s o r t of esti- mate. Some people thought t h e probability of a disaster hitting t h e m was quite high-1 chance in 10-yet they said they had purchased no disaster insurance.

Others believed t h e chances of a disaster aflecting t h e m was almost nil-1 in 100.000-yet they had purchased disaster insurance. It s e e m s c l e a r t h a t a number of individuals participating in t h e Beld survey do not understand t h e concept of probability. The findings are consistent with t h e heuristics and biases implied by controlled laboratory experiments over t h e p a s t decade (Fischhofl, e t aL 1979; Tversky and Kahneman 1974).

It is tempting to a t t r i b u t e t h L casual a t t i t u d e a b o u t t h e r i s k s of natural hazards a n d protective activities t o homeowners' beliefs t h a t t h e federal govern- ment w i l l bail t h e m out in a crisis. But Figure 4 indicates t h a t t h e majority of uninsured residents anticipate no aid a t all from t h e government even when they expected t o s u d e r Large losses from a disaster. Most of t h e s e people were aware t h a t t h e SEA provides aid t o t h e victims. b u t they h a d little knowledge of t h e Loan t e r m s o r whether they could receive forgiveness grants. On t h e basis of these results, one c a n conclude t h a t m o s t homeowners in hazard-prone a r e a s have not even considered how they would recover should they s u d e r flood o r earthquake damage. Inatead they t r e a t such events as being s o unlikely t h a t they ignore t h e consequences altogether.

Figure 4. Impact of federal aid on uninsured homeowners.

What variables influence a person's declsion to p u r c h a ~ e insurance? A key lactor is a belief that the hazard is a serious problem. This concern is found pri- marily arnong people who have had past experience with the hazard. "You ask me why I didn't have Lnsurance before the June 1972 flood" said one homeowner in Norristown, Pennsylvania. "We had the flood in September of '71 and I had two

(21)

leet or water in my basement. And

I

felt this I c a n tolerate a n d this is probably a s high a s it will ever get." To his chagrin, this m a n suffered severe property damage in 1972. Only then did he decide t h a t he needed insurance. Another uninsured flood victim, said t h a t his rationale was t h a t "the $60 in premiums they could use for something else. But now they don't c a r e if the dgure was

$600. They're going to take insurance because they've been through it twice and they've learned a lesson from it."

As shown in Figure 5, another important factor in influencing t h e purchase of a policy appears to be knowing someone who h a s purchased coverage o r dis- cussing insurance with a friend, neighbor o r relative. The following example graphically illustrates this point. In a p r e t e s t of the questionnaire in San Fran- cisco. a homeowner responded to one of t h e questions by saying t h a t h e did not have earthquake insurance. A friend of his who was listening t o t h e interview commented t h a t he had himself purchased s u c h insurance a few y e a r s before.

The respondent was dumbfounded and asked his friend about t h e availability of e a r t h q u a k e coverage and how much it cost. "I'm going to have t o look into e a r t h q u a k e insurance mysell." h e added.

Figure 5. Interpersonal communication between insured a n d uninsured.

The controlled laboratory experiments on insura c e undertaken a t Decision Research provides further insight into these results.'Subjects were exposed to a variety of risks t h a t had different losses a n d probabilities associated with them. By keeping the premium constant for all risks a n d varylng t h e losses and probabilities in such a way t h a t the expected loss (loss multiptied by probab~tity) was t h e s a m e , it was possible to t e s t the importance of probability and loss on insurance purchase decisions.

One would expect t h a t individuals should prefer to insure themselves against events having a low probability of occurrence but a high loss r a t h e r than against those having a high probability and low loss. The reverse was found to be true for a variety of experimental formats. These results suggest t h a t if the chances or an event a r e sufTiclently low, people do not even reflect on its conse- quences. In o t h e r words, people a r e primarily interested in buying insurance if

(22)

they feel the p r o b a b ~ l i t y of a disaster 1s high enough for t h e m to stand a good chance of gektinq a r e t u r n . They thus n e w insurance as an ~ n v e s t m e n t r a t h e r than aa protection.

F o r m u l a t i n g i l l t e r n c r t i v e P o l i c i e s

There a r e a s e t of allernative policies for dealing with t h e natural hazards problem outlined above. The c u r r e n t institutional a r r a n g e m e n t s for floods and earthquakes i l l u s t r a b s the role of incentives and regulations to supplement m a r k e t mechanisms.

'

In the case of t h e flood hazard, t h e federal government o d e r s subsidized premiums as a n incentive for residents to purchase coverage. They also a r e imposing speciflc land use regulations on communities who participate in t h e flood p r o g r a m More recently banks have required homeowners t o p u r c h a s e flood insurance a s a condition for obtaining a mortgage. Those who apply for federal relief after a disaster a r e also required to purchase coverage a s a condi- tion for obtaining a low interest loan. For these groups. Bood insurance is man- d a t o r y r a t h e r t h a n voluntary.

Protection against earthquake damage has been more of a private r a t h e r than public &air. No one is required t o purchase insurance a s a condition for a mortgage or a disaster loan. Even though coverage is available. :here has been no g r e a t effort m a d e by insurance companies o r their agents t o actively m a r k e t policies. The insurance industry claims t h a t it d o e s ' n o t have enough rein- surance capacity t o cover t h e damage from a catastrophic quake in a populated a r e a of California if most residents and businesses were p r o t e c t e d with insurance. Today t h e principal government role with r e s p e c t to t h e hazard is through local bulding codes a n d ordnances on t h e design of s t r u c t u r e s a n d t h e provisions of federal aid t o cover the uninsured portion of a n earthquake loss.

Other programs for coping with t h e problem a r e stimulated by t h e following questions:

(1) What types of information would enable peop!e to make b e t t e r deci- sions for coping with the risk? How can either the insurance industry.

government a t all levels (i.e., federal, s t a t e , and local) and/or public interest groups aid in t h s effort?

One course of action is to make flood a n d e a r t h q u a k e coverage m o r e attractive by presenting information through normal channels. The insurance agent may serve an important and useful function in this regard. To t h e extent t h a t he has the t r u s t of his clients, he can stimu- late their awareness of t h e hazard by teUing t h e m the chances of a disaster occurring and the potential losses t h a t could result. One way for t h e &gent t o increase the client's concern with the hazard may be t o present information on the probability of a disaster on a different time interval than the traditional one year period. For example, in describing t h e chances of a 100 year flood, t h e agent could note t h a t for someone living in a house for 25 years, the chances of suffering damage a t least once will be .22. He c a n also provide details a s to what coverage is available a n d how much it costs. Since most individuals seem to t r e a t Insurance a s an investment, t h e agent should e d u c a t e his cl' n t s that the biggest recurn on their policy is to have no r e t u r n a t all.

tf

(23)

(2) What is the balance between t h e use of m a r k e t mechanisms for equat- ing supply and demand, developing appropriate incentives (e.g.. taxes a n d subsidies) a s well a s regulatory m e a s u r e s (e.g., required insurance coverage) in the design of a hazards s t r a t e g y ?

Financial institutions may play a key role h e r e by requiring some type of natural hazard insurance a s a condition for a mortgage on residen- tial property. Several types of policies deserve consideration. One option would be a broader form of homeowners insurance which com- bines flood and earthquake. A less e x t r e m e proposal would b e t o add only earthquake coverage to a s t a n d a r d h o m e o m e r s p o k y a n d main- tain t h e c u r r e z t flood insurance program. A third option would be to maintain t h e c u r r e n t insurance coverage and provide d i s a s t e r relief to special groups or for special situations. Distributional c o s t considera- tions may suggest t h a t special t r e a t m e n t be given to low-income or elderly residents.

E v a l u a t i n g S t r a t e g i e s

Any s t r a t e g y o r program impacts on t h e i n t e r e s t e d parties in m e r e n t ways. The evaluation phase forces policy m a k e r s to come to grips with t h e ques- tion a s to t h e appropriate role of t h e public and private s e c t o r s in hazard management. To illustrate, consider two contrasting scenarios. In scenario 1.

a c t s of Cod. s u c h a s floods and earthquakes, a r e viewed a s a public responsibil- ity; t h e n liberal disaster relief should b e provided to all victims and/or highly subsidized insurance offered t o residents in hazard-prone areas. In scenario 2, individuals a r e expected to assume t h e responsibility for protecting themselves against t h e hazard; t h e n private insurance should be offered and those who decide not t o purchase coverage voluntarily w i l l be forced t o suUer t h e conse- quences. Scenario 1 is equivalent t o assigning a high weight to potential victims and a low weight t o t h e general taxpayer. Scenario 2 gives i n c r e a s e d impor- t a n c e t o t h e general taxpayer. In this case, policies which r e q u i r e individuals faced with a risk to bear t h e cost of potential losses a r e viewed a s being a t t r a c - tive. How this evaluation process currently t a k e s place and should t a k e place in t h e f u t u r e i s an important topic for discussion.

V. TOWARDS A DESCRIPTIVE

MODEL

OF CHOICE

The examples p r e s e n t e d above suggest the need for an understanding of t h e decision processes of t h e interested parties before one c a n r e c o m m e n d different policies. A first s t e p in this direction is depicted in Figure 6 where t h e t h r e e i n t e r e s t e d parties-consumers, flrms, and government-are linked t o a s e t of events (e.g., catastrophes, accidents) each of which has a probability and Loss associated with it. To make the problem m o r e c o n c r e t e and realistic assume t h a t t h e r e a r e n different consumer groups s o m e of which have dirTerent possi- ble losses and p r o b a b h t i e s associated with a particular event. For example.

t h e r e m a y be diflerent exposures to a c e r t a i n hazard so t h a t t h e chances of incurring a specified loss will differ between individuals. Assume t h a t t h e r e a r e m identical firms e a c h providing t h e s a m e type of protection (e.g.. insurance) against the consequences of t h e s e events.

(24)

Figure 6. Descriptive component.

P e r f m a n c e of a Market S y s t e m

Given this s i m p l f i e d world it should t h e n be possible t o analyze how well a m a r k e t s y s t e m o p e r a t e s u n d e r a variety of different a s s u m p t i o n s r e g a r d m g t h e a c c u r a c y of information by c o n s u m e r s a n d firms on t h e d i s t r i b u t ~ o n of events.

For example. suppose c o n s u m e r s a n d firms have p e r f e c t information on t h e pro- bability a n d loss distribution of events. What t y p e of i n s u r a n c e policies w i l l b e oflered t o c o n s u m e r groups? How does t h e situation c h a n g e when t h e r e is i m p e r f e c t information b y e i t h e r or both of t h e s e p a r t i e s ?

A similar analysis c a n b e u n d e r t a k e n if one p o s t u l a t e s d f l e r e n t types of decision rules u s e d by c o n s u m e r s o r firms. For example. suppose t h a t e a c h con- s u m e r evaluates t h e benefits a n d c o s t s of purchasing i n s u r a n c e a n d chooses a n a m o u n t (possibly no coverage) which maximizes e x p e c t e d utility. How m u c h i n s u r a n c e will e a c h c o n s u m e r group p u r c h a s e a n d what t y p e s of coverage will firm3 offer? Suppose. on t h e o t h e r hand, t h a t c o n s u m e r s utilize a threshold model of cholce: if t h e probability of t h e event is perceived t o b e below s o m e critical level t h e n t h e p e r s o n ignores i t s consequences a n d d o e s not consider a n y t y p e of protection: otherwise they p u r c h a s e t h e a m o u n t of coverag? which maximizes e x p e c t e d utility. What i m p a c t will s u c h a behavioral model have on t h e types of i n s u r a n c e poilcies oflered by firms and t h e d e g r e e of protection a d o p t e d by c o n s u m e r s ? In a similar vein one c a n investigate t h e Impact of a model where factors s u c h a s p a s t experience and discussionz with friends a n d neighbors trigger s e a r c h for new information a n d i n t e r e s t In protective m e a s - u r e s such a s insurance.

The i m p a c t of d d e r e n c assumpJtions regarding the a c c u r a c y of information and alternative decision rules c a n be investigated e i t h e r a t one p o ~ n t of time o r in a dynamic context. When one Looks a t t h e situation over t i m e t h e n t h e r e is a n e e d t o specify t h e different rules t h a t c o n s u m e r s a n d firms a r e likely t o u t ~ l i z e for updating information on t h e probability a n d consequences of specific events.

As shown by Arrow (1963) a n d Akerlof (1970) t h e r e a r e problems of adverse

(25)

selection when firms have misinformation or imperfect informatlon on the risks each of the n consumer groups a r e facing. For example, if firms cannot distin- guish between high and low rlsk groups they may s e t a premium based on t h e average probability of a loss. If consumers have a c c u r a t e information on t h e hazard. high risk groups will Bnd this policy to be much more attractive t h a n low risk groups. and will purchase a proportionately larger s h a r e of t h e total cover- age. Over time, claims experience leads d r m s to s e t higher and higher premi- ums. thus making insurance Less and Less attractive t o those in t h e lower risk classes. Eventually the only group who 5nds insurance to be attractive a r e those in t h e highest risk class.

The above example illustrating m a r k e t failure is i m p o r t a n t for prescriptive purposes because it indicates t h a t t h e private s e c t o r may not provide satisfac- tory protective solutions to potentially disastrous events, e i t h e r because of misinformation and/or because of t h e decision processes of t h e i n t e r e s t e d par- ties. The lack of protection m a y then b e very costly t o both t h e disaster victims (who may not be able t o g e t protection o r a r e unaware of t h e consequences of t h e hazard) a s well a s t h e general taxpayer (who may have t o foot t h e bill a f t e r a disaster occurs). The example also suggests the importance of determining what information consumers and Arms have available, how a c c u r a t e t h e s e d a t a a r e a n d how they a r e actually utilized in t h e decision-making process.

Role of Government

If c o n s u m e r s and/or Frms have misinformation, one of t h e important roles t h a t t h e third p a r t y , government, can play is t o provide b e t t e r d a t a on t h e hazard itself (e.g.. losses, probabilities of its occurrence) as well a s ways of pro- tecting oneself (e.g.. available insurance. type of coverage and its cost). It c a n also provide m o n e t a r y incentives t o encourage c e r t a i n actions (i.e., subsidies) a s well a s disincentives (i.e.. fines, taxes) t o inhibit o r discourage certain types of behavior. Finally, i t c a n regulate or require c e r t a i n t y p e s of actions.

The s u c c e s s of each of these approaches depends on t h e decision processes of the i n t e r e s t e d parties and t h e objectives of different policies. Thus, if consu- m e r s a r e maximizing e x p e c t e d u t i l ~ t y th e n a subsidized insurance premium would lead t o an increase in d e m a n d for coverage. This type of incentive s y s t e m would have no eBect for any consumer who behaved according to a threshold model and perceived t h e probability of a event t o be below h ~ s critical level. In t h e l a t t e r c a s e t h e only way to induce i n t e r e s t In insurance is to provide infor- mation on t h e hazard so t h a t t h e probabdity 1s perceived to be above t h e c r i t i c d level(s) or t o require the person to have insurance coverage.

From a dynamic viewpomt t h e r e is a need t o u n d e r s t a n d differences in ez- ante e s t i m a t e s and ex-post valuations and their effect on policy. Prior t o a disaster an indvidual is Likely to behave m t h one s e t of estlrnates of the proba- bility and losses. After an event occurs he may revlse his estimate considerably.

partly on t h e basis of the new tnformation (i.e.. updating h s prior e s t i m a t e s of probabilities and losses) but also because of the n a t u r e of this declsion process (e.g.. he now views the probability to be above a critical threshold level and hence is concerned w ~ t h possible losses). I f government policy responds t o these ex post p e r c e p t ~ o n changes in a way that was unantlclpated prior to the disaster, this process has to be understood before one designs policies. A clear example of this behavlor IS tn t h e natural hazards field: government provided liberal disaster after the o c c u r r e n c e of a disaster because few people protected

(26)

themselves prior to the event. If crises normally trigger unanticipated reac- tions due to po1it:cal and social pressures (c.f.. the Three Mile Island response), then this process must be taken into account in designing appropriate stra- tegies for dealing with low probability-high consequence events.

Finally, there are a set of philosophical and ethical issues that have to be addressed directly when evaluating the role of governmont as part of any alter- native plan. Given our increased understanding of the imperfect information and sirnpli5ed rules that people use in making decisions, there is the open ques- tion as to "when should we protect individuals from themselves?" If poiicy mak- e r s have learned from experience t h a t there is ex post regret by uninsured con- sumers after an event, what type of incentives or regulations, if any, should be taken ex ante? There is no.easy answer t o this query but it should be explicitly addressed a s an issue regarding the appropriate role of government in dealing with the consequences of low probability events.

I t

also illustrates the interac- tion between the descriptive and prescriptive components depicted in the con- ceptual framework ( F i u r e 1) which has motivated this paper.

(27)

For an excellent discussion of how one can specify goals and objectives for societal problem:, see Keeney and R d a 1978, Chapters 1 & 2.

For an analysis of alternative remedies proposed by t h e Federal Trade Com- mission in the context of these and other costs, see Federal Trade Commis- sion 1979.

The s p e c s c standards a r e t h a t the foot cannot reach the blade of the mower and that the blade must stop within 3 seconds of release of t h e power switch so the hand cannot reach the turning blade.

These diflerences a r e clearly seen in the LUG siting debate in California.

For more detail on this case, see Ahearn 1980. in press; Deutsch in press;

Kunreuther 1980; and Linnerooth 1980.

The material in the next section summarizes t h e findings from a four-year study supported by funds from the National Science Foundation. Readers interested in more detail a r e referred to Kunreuther. et al. 1978.

Mom details on the insurance experiments can be found in Slovic. e t al.

1977. The material also appears in Kunreuther, e t al. 1978, Chap. 7.

A more detailed discussion of policy options appears in Ginsberg and Kun- reuther (in press).

Kunreuther and Schoemaker (in press) provlde a more detailed discussion of the role of the agcnt and the insurance .ridustry in promoting the sale of flood coverage.

(28)

REFERENCES

Ahern, William. 1980. "California Meets the

LNG

Terminal." C o a s t a l Zone M a n a g e m e n t J o u r n a l , 7: 185.221.

Ahern, W. (in press). "The Role of Technical Analyses in Cahfornia Energy Facil- ity Siting Decisions." Proceedings of t h e Liquefied Energy Cases Facil- ity Siting Task Force Meeting. IIASA Laxenburg. Austria. S e p t e m b e r 1980.

Akerlof. G. 1970. "The Market for 'Lemons': Quality Uncertainty and t h e Market Mechanisms." QunrterLy J o u r n a l o f E c a m i c s , 84:480-500.

Arrow,

K.

1963. "Uncertainty a n d t h e Welfare Economics of Medical Care."

A m e a n E c a n m i c R e v i e w , 53:941-973.

a i c k . T.. and C. Hohenemser. 1979. "Target: Highway Risks. I. Taking Individual Aim." E n v i r o n m e n t , 21:7-15, 29-38.

Deutsch, RW. (in press). "Siting a n

L.N.C.

Fccllity in California: The Regulatory Framework and the Factors Involved in t h e Decision Making Process."

Proceedings of t h e Liquefied Energy Gases Facility Siting Task Force Meeting, IIASA, Laxenburg, Austria. S e p t e m b e r 1980.

Federal Trade Commission. 1979. C o n s u m e r I n f o r m a t i a n R e m e d i e s . Washing- ton. D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.

Fischhoff, 0.. P. Slovic. S. k c h t e n s t e i n . 3. Read. and

B.

Combs. 1978. "Hoa Safe is Safe Enough? A Psychometric Study of X t t ~ t u d e s Towards Technolog- ical Risks and Benefits." P o l / c y Sciences 9: 127-152.

Ginsberg. R.. and

H.

Kunreuther. (in press). "Behavioral Determinants of

(29)

Market Failure: The Case of Disaster Insurance," in S. Fiddle, ed..

U n c e r t a i n t y : Social a n d Behavioral Dimensions. New York: Praeger.

Harris. J. 1980. "Taxing Tar and Nicotine." A m e r i c a n Economic R e v i e w . 70:300- 31 1.

Keeney, R.. and H. RauTa. 1978. Decisions w i t h Multiple Objectives. New York:

John Wiley.

Kunreuther,

H.. R

Ginsberg.

L

Miller. P. Sagi. P. Slovic. B. Borkan. and

N.

Katz.

1978. D i s a s t e r I n s u r a n c e R o t e c t i o T u P u b l i c P o l i c y Lessons. New York:

wiiey.

Kunreuther,

H..

and P. Schoemaker. (in press). "Decision Analysis for Complex Systems." Knowledge

Kunreuther. H. 1980. "Societal Decision Making for Low Probability Events:

Descriptive and Prescriptive Aspects." IIASA Working Paper, WP-80-184.

Laxenburg. Austria.

L i ~ e r o o t h , J. 1980. "A Short History of t h e California LNG Terminal." IIASA Working Paper, WPJ30-155. Laxenburg. Austria.

National Analysts Inc. 1971. M o t i v a t i n g F a c t o r s in t h e U s e of R e s t r a i n t S y s t e m s . Final Report. c o n t r a c t

FH

11-7810. Philadelphia: p r e p a r e d for the U.S Department of Transportation.

Office of Technology Assessment. 1977. T r a n s p o r t a t i o n of Liquefied N a t u r a l Gas.

Washington. D.C.: Office of Technology Assessment.

Slovic, P.. B. Fischhod, a n d S. Lichtenstein. 1978. "Accident Probabilities and S e a t Belt Usage: A Psychological Perspective." Accident A n a l y s i s a n d P r e v e n t i o n , 10. 28 1-295.

Slovic. P.. B. Fischhoff. S. Lichtenstein. B. Corrigan, and

B.

Combs. 1977.

"Preference for Insuring Against Probable Small Losses: Implications for t h e Theory a n d Practice of Insurance." J o u r n a l of R i s k a n d I n s u r a n c e , 4 4 . 237-258.

Tversky, A , and D. Kahnernan. 1974. "Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases." Scrence 185:1124-1131.

Washington Post. 1979a. "Safety Rules Eyed for Power Mowers." January 20.

Washington Post. 1979b. "Prince George County's Smolung Ban Becomes Law,"

March 2.

(30)
(31)

T H E C U L T U R A L APPROACH T O RISK:

T H E CASE O F POVERTY

Michael Thompson

International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria

Are the poor all alike or are they different? Both, obviously. The similarities are handled by political economy - a long-established and familiar approach; the differences are handled by political culture - a newly-emerging and unfamiliar approach. Political culture looks, not at how people are differentiated by constraints

-

by what they can't do

-

but at how people are differentiated by capabilities

-

by the different things they do with what they can do.

If poverty has to do with the absence of the chance t o choose, then non-poverty has t o do with the presence of the chance t o choose. This leads t o the consideration of the possi- bility of personal strategies for resource management and for need management. There are four logically possible management strategies and one coping strategy, and the cultural hypothesis is that an individual will be led t o adopt one of these strategies and to reject the others by virtue of his social context and i t s associated cosmology.

Fieldwork in Britain and informal guided interviews in the United States support this hypothesis and reveal that less than half of those officially classified as "poor" conform to the official image of poverty.

Political culture has implications that go beyond the arena of poverty policy. In suggest- ing that the economist's category "land" is not a "given" but is created and destroyed by social processes, it offers a way of identifying the cultural bias of an institution and a way of compensating for that bias. For instance, if we assume that IIASA's bias is towards caste-ism (that is, towards a personal strategy in which needs are given and only resources are manageable) then we should not be surprised t o discover that those who argue from a more sectist social context (a context in which the adopted strategy i s to manage needs downwards) find credible a level of energy demand two-and-a-half times lower than I IASA's minimum. This cultural approach provides us with a method for handling such disjunctions in credibility, and with a way of understanding the sorts of "perceptiongaps"

that exist between the different parties in current debates about risk, without requiring us to play the "cosmic exile" and pronounce on who is right and who is wrong.

(32)

INTRODUCTION

nThe very rich are different from you and me," said Scott Fitzgerald. "Yes," replied Eemingway, "they've got more money.n Economists, by and large, side with Hemingway; anthro- pologists with Scott Fitzgerald. Both, in taking sides, have missed the whole point of this literary exchange which is that these two positions are not to be seen as contradictory. Scott Fitzgerald is not denying that the very rich have more money than he and Hemingway; he is insisting that, over and above that distinction of degree, there is some other distinction of kind.

He is saying that, at right angles to this clearly visible

economic axis, there is a

cultural

axis which has been overlooked What is more, whilst the economic axis is a continuum with

individuals spread out all the way along it and sliding this way and that as their fortunes wax and wane, the cultural axis in- volves discontinuities - individuals, far from being spread out along it, are clumped around certain points and, far from sliding smoothly back and forth, they can only shift their positions (if at all) by either headlong careers or sudden dis- continuous jumps from one clump to another.

Having criticised Hemingway for missing (albeit deliberately)

the whole point of the argument, let me now redress the balance

a little and take Scott Fitzgerald to task for not carrying his

reasoning through to its logical conclusion. Having gone to all

the trouble of setting up his two axes - one a continuum, the

other a disco~tinuum - he then qoes and spoils it all by assuming

that they represent dependent variables - that as you move up one

you move up the other. But why should only the very rich be

different from you and me? Who,corne to that, is to say that

you and I are the same? And why shouldn't some of the very rich

be different, not just from you and me, but from othcrs among

(33)

the very rich as well? In other words, what Scott Fitzgerald has overlooked is that his two axes may represent two fully independent variables. Let me now try to rectify that orrission.

The anthropologist does not disagree with the economist; he concedes that the very rich have got more money than the

not-so-very rich and that, in consequence, they are able to do all sorts of things that others with less money are not able to do. What the anthropologist is saying is that, when the

economist has said that, that is not all that can be said. We can go on and, slicing through social life along a very different orientation, look, not at how people are differentiated by

constraints

-

by what the17 can't do

-

but at how they are differentiated by capabilities

-

by the different things they do with what they can do.

Now, of course, it is quite possible that Scott Fitzgerald, though he did not pause to consider whether his two variables might be independent of one another, was nevertheless right but the fact that the economic axis deals with problems and with continuities, whilst the cultural axis deals with capabilities and with discontinuities, suggests that this is unlikely. The mathematician will raise objections to such non-kosher dependen- cies and the statistician will throw up his arms in horror if asked to marry aggregations and disaggregations in this way. To these fundamental distinctions between the two axes we must add a contingent one: the economic axis is a well-trodden path that has been mapped and signposted by generations of travellers; the cultural axis is known only through the fragmentary reports of a few explorers and our attempt to traverse it will inevitably be a much more tentative and speculative business.

But at least we can make some preparations against the un- certainties that lie ahead. What might we expect to find out there? We should expect to find several, but not innumerable, distinctly different ways in which people who are all subject to the same constraints set about making the most of whatever possibilities these constraints leave open to them. Whilst it is only to be expected that these different ways of managing

are likely to flourish in all their glorious variety in situations where the constraints are least severe, we should nevertheless be prepared to encounter them even when the constraints are at their most stringent. In other words, we should not be

surprised to find just as many differences in kind among the very poor as among the.very rich. And, if our expectations are confounded,

....

if we don't find any of these differences, even among the very rich? Then, come home Ernest; all is for- given 1

A MODEL OF THE SOCIAL LANDSCAPE

Begin with the idea that individuals can be differentiated by the ways in which they are caught up in the process of social life, and further assume that these different ways of being caught up can be adequately described by just two axes

-

one

( g r o u p ) describing the way an individual is caught up in the

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

The question then arises can you protect civilians in certain cases unless you change their regime, but let’s understand that the Libyan story created a normative opportunity for

Bush signed the Project BioShield Act on July 2, 2004, he declared that it would “help America purchase, develop and deploy cutting-edge defenses against catastrophic attack.” 1

Appendix A.3], briefly recall the notions of a strict monoidal category and their functors [EGNO15, Section 2.8] or [Kock04, Section 3.2], of a symmetric monoidal category, and

At each spatial scale used to define bioregions, the time bin with the lowest geographic spread of sampling (calculated by the minimum spanning tree length between bioregions) is

GPS week: No roll-over, continuous number: March 1998 Error in compressed DOS file naming convention: July 1998 Table A13 contained blank satellite identifiers: Sept 1998

This recap sheet aims to self-assess your progress and to recap some of the definitions and concepts introduced in the previous lectures. You do not need to hand in solutions,

 The economic consequences of an exposed object (an impact model linking water depth, duration of inundation, flow velocity with economic losses). Environmental Risk: Unit

• new approach to fast Ewald summation under mixed boundary conditions: [Nestler, Pippig, Potts 2013 (Preprint)]. • 2d-periodic: Ewald + fast summation