• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

The amplifying effect of capitalization rates on housing supply

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "The amplifying effect of capitalization rates on housing supply"

Copied!
15
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

ContentslistsavailableatScienceDirect

Journal of Urban Economics

journalhomepage:www.elsevier.com/locate/jue

The amplifying effect of capitalization rates on housing supply

Simon Büchler

a,b

, Maximilian v. Ehrlich

b

, Olivier Schöni

b,c,

aMIT Center for Real Estate

bCenter for Regional Economic Development (CRED), Department of Economics, University of Bern

cDepartment of Finance, Insurance and Real Estate, Laval University

a r t i c le i n f o

JEL classification:

R 1 R 3 R 5 Keywords:

Housing supply Capitalization rate Land use regulation Geographic constraints

a b s t r a ct

Weprovideempiricalevidencethatincreasesinhousingrentalincomeleadtoalargersupplyresponsethanprice increasesofthesamepercentagevalue.Werationalizethisdifferentialinsupplyresponsivenesswithanampli- ficationmechanismarisingfromadownwardrevisionofcapitalizationratesfollowingarentalincomeincrease.

Wedocumentthattheamplificationofthehousingsupplypriceelasticityislesspronouncedingeographically constrainedandtightlyregulatedneighborhoodsandareashavingmoresophisticatedinvestors.Ourfindings holdvaluablelessonsforpublicpoliciesaffectingthehousingrentalincome,suchasrentcontrolandhousing subsidies.

1. Introduction

Existingresearchemphasizestheimportanceofhousingsupplyprice elasticityfora varietyof economicoutcomes.Theresponsivenessof housingsupplyaffects,amongotherthings,housingcycles,theallo- cationoflaboracrossspace,andthedegreeofcapitalizationofpublic policiessuchasplace-basedsubsidies.1However,todate,weknowrel- ativelylittleabouttheresponsivenessof housingsupplywithrespect tochangesinrents.Thisissurprising,asurbaneconomictheorytypi- callyfocusesonperiodichousingcosts,andmanypublicpoliciessuch asrentcontrolandhousingsubsidiesdirectlyactontherentalincome generatedbyrealestateproperties.Inthispaper,weinvestigateunder whichcircumstancesthehousingsupplyresponsivenesstochangesin rentsdiffersfromthesupplyresponsivenesstopricechangesandwhy theratioofrentandpriceelasticitiesvariesacrossregions.

Westartbydevelopingapartialequilibriumframeworkfeaturing housingsupplyanddemandaswellasrealestateinvestors.Thethe-

WearegratefultoBrentAmbrose,PaulAnglin,NathanielBaum-Snow,AymoBrunetti,GuillaumeChapelle,DavidGeltner,LuHan,ChristianHilber,Albert Saiz,AlexvandeMinne,AnnieKinsellaThompson,BillWheaton,PaulWillen,Jeff Zabelandtwoanonymousrefereesforveryhelpfuladviceandsuggestions.We benefitedfromnumerouscommentsbytheparticipantsoftheBostonFEDUrbanandRealEstateSeminar,theUniversityofSt.GallenResearchSeminar,2019UEA inPhiladelphia,2018UEAinNewYork,2018SSES,MITCREResearchSeminar,SRERCZurich2017,CREDResearchSeminar,aswellasfromthemonitoringgroup atSECOandBWO.WethankMeta-Sys,Comparis,SwissFederalStatisticalOffice,SwisscantonalofficesandComparisforgenerouslysharingtheirdata.Ehrlichand SchöniacknowledgefundingfromtheSwissNationalScienceFoundation(grantnumber162589).

Correspondingauthorat:DepartmentofFinance,InsuranceandRealEstate,LavalUniversity,2325RuedelaTerrasse,G1V0A6,Québec.

E-mailaddresses:buechler@mit.edu(S.Büchler),maximilian.vonehrlich@vwi.unibe.ch(M.v.Ehrlich),olivier.schoni@fsa.ulaval.ca(O.Schöni).

1 Forinstance,Glaeseretal.(2008)investigatetheroleofhousingsupplyelasticitiesforpricedynamics,Diamond(2017)linksthedegreetowhichlocalgovern- mentscanextractrentstohousingsupplyelasticities,KlineandMoretti(2014)emphasizetheimportanceofhousingsupplyelasticityforthedistributionaleffects ofplace-basedpolicies,andHsiehandMoretti(2019)focusontheimplicationsofhousingsupplyconstraintsforthespatialmisallocationoflabor.SeeGlaeserand Gyourko(2018)andHilber(2017)forasynthesis.

oreticalframeworkservestwopurposes.First,itguidesourempirical analysisand, inparticular,motivates theidentificationstrategyused toestimatehousingsupplyelasticities.Second,itallowsustorational- izedifferencesintheestimatedsupplyresponsivenesstorentandprice dynamics.Weshowthatlocalchangesininvestors’expectationsabout rentalincomegrowthandriskpremiaaredecisivetoexplainsupplydif- ferences.Specifically,thehousingsupplyresponsetochangesinprices andrentsisidenticalifcapitalizationratesdonotadjusttochangesin rents.Ifcapitalizationratesdoadjust,housingsupplypriceelasticities areeitheramplifiedordampenedbythisadjustment.

Next,webringthetheoreticalframeworktothedataandestimate theaverageresponsivenessofhousingsupplywithrespecttopriceand rentchangesattheneighborhoodlevel.Todoso,weusedetailedgeoref- erenceddataonadvertisedresidentialpropertiesandbuildingstockfor Switzerlandcoveringtheperiod2005–2015.Wefindthatanincrease in rentsleadstoanaboutthriceaslargesupplyincreasethananin- creaseofpricesofthesamepercentagevalue:Thesupplyresponsefol-

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jue.2021.103370

Received29February2020;Receivedinrevisedform14June2021 Availableonline3July2021

0094-1190/© 2021TheAuthors.PublishedbyElsevierInc.ThisisanopenaccessarticleundertheCCBYlicense(http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/)

(2)

lowingatenpercentincreaseinsquaremeterrents(prices)isapprox- imately14percent(fourpercent).Accordingtoourframework,these resultssuggestthat,onaverage,realestateinvestorsrevisecapitaliza- tionratesdownwardfollowingapositivedemandshock.Thisrevision, inturn,amplifiesthesupplyresponsetopricechanges.Wedocument thatthesupplyamplification,andthecorrespondingadjustmentofex- pectations,areheterogeneousacrossspace.Geographicallyconstrained andtightlyregulatedmarkets– i.e.,majorurbanareasandalpinetourist areas– andneighborhoodshavingmoresophisticatedbuyersasproxied bylandlords,institutionalinvestors,orsecond-homeinvestorsdisplay loweramplificationvalues.

Switzerlandisanexcellentlaboratorytoinvestigatehousingsupply duetosubstantialheterogeneityinthelocalfactorsinfluencingit.The decentralizedformofgovernmentgrantslow-tier politicalunits(mu- nicipalities)large autonomyin landuse planningandfiscalpolicies.

Geographicfeaturesofthelandscape,suchaselevation,slope,andter- rainruggedness,alsovaryconsiderablyacrossspace.Thesecharacter- isticsofthecountrymakethereactionofhousingsupplycontingenton localizedfactors.Importantly,theowner-occupiedandrentalmarkets areapproximateofequalsizeinSwitzerland,whichfacilitatesthees- timationofrentalandpricesupplyelasticitiesthroughoutthecountry, therebyallowingustostudytheroleofcapitalizationratesforhousing supply.2Finally,theexistenceofdetailedinformationonproperty-level housingcharacteristicsallowsustoruleoutthatdifferentattributes– i.e.,aqualitygap– betweenpropertiesdrivethedifferencesinsupply elasticities.

Ourpaperbridgestwostrandsoftheliterature.Thefirststrandfo- cusesontheestimationoflocalhousingsupplypriceelasticities.Despite theimportanceofhousingsupplyelasticity,papersquantifyingitremain scarce.GyourkoandMolloy(2015)provideacomprehensivereviewof theliteratureinvestigatingtheestimationanddeterminantsofhousing supply.Inhisseminalarticle,Saiz(2010)estimateshousingsupplyelas- ticitiesacrossU.S.MetropolitanStatisticalAreas(MSAs)asafunctionof geographicandregulatoryconstraints.UsingaVectorErrorCorrection Model,Wheatonetal.(2014)alsoestimatehousingsupplyelasticities forU.S.MSA’s,obtainingestimatesinlinewiththoseofSaiz (2010). Baum-Snow andHan, 2021adopt a structural approachto quantify cross-andwithin-cityhousingsupplyelasticitiesforU.S.metropolitan areas,showingthathousingsupplyelasticitiesincreasemonotonically withthedistancetocitycenters.WhilerelyingonSaiz(2010)empirical specificationforestimatinginversehousingsupplyelasticities,wefol- lowasimilaridentificationstrategyasinBaum-SnowandHan,2021. Specifically,weidentifyhousingsupplyelasticitiesusinglocaldemand shockstriggeredbythehistoricspatialdistributionofsectoralemploy- mentsharesandtheconnectivityofaneighborhoodwithlocallabor markets.Asacomplementaryshift-shareinstrument,weusethehistor- icaldistributionof languagesharesacross Swissneighborhoodscom- binedwiththegrowthoflanguagegroupsataggregatelevels.

Thesecond strandof theliteraturefocuses onhowinvestors’ ex- pectations impact market dynamics. Time variation in expectations – as captured by price to rent ratios dynamics – have been used byCase andShiller(2003)toidentifybubble-like behavior.Bycon- structing a user cost model incorporating economic fundamentals, Himmelberget al.(2005) show that expectedhouse price apprecia- tionplaysanimportantrolein explaininglocal U.S.pricedynamics.

FocusingontheU.S.housingboomintheearly2000s,Ben-Davidetal., 2019showthatagentsinvest invacanthomesiftheyexpectfurther priceincreases.Kaplanetal.(2020)highlighttheroleofexpectations forhousepriceandrentmovementsaroundtheGreatRecession.

Theimportanceof expectationsformarketdynamics hassparked interest in the way individuals form expectations. Mayer and Sinai (2007) investigate theeffect of backward-looking expectations

2 Similarhomeownershipratesareobservede.g.,inAustria,Germany,and SouthKorea.

inhousepricebooms.Sivitanidesetal.(2010)findthatcapitalization rates behavesimilarlytoprice/earningsratios,witheconomicagents formingpricegrowthexpectationsbasedonpastdynamics.Glaeserand Nathanson,2017constructamodelwherebuyersarenotentirelyratio- nalinpredictingfuturepricedynamics,whichexplainsobservedprice correlationovertime.KuchlerandZafar(2019)showthatindividuals formexpectationsabouthousepricedynamicsfromrecentpersonalex- periences.Thefactthatinvestorsaremyopic,orbackward-looking,isin linewithourfindings,whichsuggestthatinvestorsexpectfurtherrent growthinlocationsthathaveexperienceddemandincreasesinthere- centpast.Usingspatialvariation,weshowthatpartofthelocalhousing supplyresponsetodemandshocksisaffectedbychangesininvestors’

expectations.

Wealsorelatetotheliteratureonlocalgeographicandregulatory constraints(e.g.,AuraandDavidoff,2008,HilberandVermeulen,2016, andLutzandSand,2019)andshowthatpricesupplyelasticitiesarede- terminednotonlybyregulationandgeographicconstraintsbutalsoby adjustingcapitalizationrates.3HilberandMense(2021)showthatla- bordemandshocksinconjunctionwithsupplyconstraintsexplainmost oftheincreaseintheprice-to-rentratioinGreaterLondonoverthelast twodecades.

Ourcontributiontotheliteratureisthreefold.First,weempirically establishalinkbetween housingsupplyresponsivenessandinvestors expectations.Thislinkisessential,aspublicpoliciesaffectingrentalin- comemightleadtounanticipatedconsequencesinthesupplyofhousing duetochangesinexpectations.Second,ourempiricalanalysisquantifies thespatialdynamicsoflocalexpectations.Specifically,weprovidenovel evidencethattheadaptationofinvestorsexpectationsoccursatthelocal levelandthatsuchadjustmentisconsistentwithapath-dependentview ofspatialdevelopment.Investorsexpectthatplacesthathavegainedin attractiveness(i.e.,experiencedapositivedemandshock)willcontinue todoso,asreflectedbyadecreaseincapitalizationrates,leadingtoad- ditionalhousingdevelopment.Third,weshowthatthehousingsupply elasticityvariesconsiderablywithinandacrossurbanareasduetothe fine-scaleimpactofgeographicandregulatoryconstraints.Thisvaria- tionleadstoaspatiallyheterogeneouscapitalizationofglobaldemand shocksthatcannotbeobservedwhenestimatingthehousingsupplyelas- ticityattheurbanarealevel,asdonebypreviousresearch.

Theremainderof thepaperisstructuredasfollows.Section2in- troduces the conceptual framework motivating our empirical analysis. Section 3 explains our empirical identification strategy.

Section4presents thedataandprovidesdescriptivestatistics forthe Swisshousingmarket.WediscusstheresultsinSection5andprovide severalrobustnesschecksinSection6.Section7concludes.

2. Conceptualframework

Thefollowingpartialequilibriumframeworkallowsustoformal- izetheidentificationassumptionsunderlyingtheempiricalanalysisand rationalizecorrespondingfindings.Wespecifythesupplyanddemand sideofthehousingmarketandoutlinetheroleplayedbyrealestate investors.4

2.1. Housingdevelopers

AsinGlaeser(2008),ineachneighborhood𝑛,housingdevelopers choosetheamountofhousingspacetodevelop.Tobuildhousing,de- velopersmustpaytheprice 𝑃𝑛𝑙𝑎𝑛𝑑 toacquireland,andthelocalcon- structioncost𝑐𝑛 topurchasebuildingmaterialsandremuneratelabor.

3Relatedly,Solé-Ollé andViladecans-Marsal(2012)analyzetheroleofpo- liticalcompetitionforresidentialdevelopment.LinandWachter,2020docu- mentspillovereffectsoflocalregulatoryconstraintsonneighboringlocalities, Cosmanetal.(2018)analyzehousingappreciationandmarginallandsupplyin adynamicframework.

4OnlineAppendixApresentsamoredetailedderivationofthemodel.

(3)

Withoutlossofgenerality,wecapturebothlocalproductivityofthecon- structionsector,aswellastheunitcostofinputs,in𝑐𝑛.Thedevelopers profitoptimizationproblemisgivenby

max (𝑃𝑛ℎ𝑙𝑐𝑛𝛿𝑖𝑛𝑡𝑛+1𝑙𝑃𝑛𝑙𝑎𝑛𝑑𝑙), (1)

where𝑃𝑛isthelocalpriceofhousingperunitoflivingspace,𝑙denotes theamountoflandandthebuildingheight.Weassumethatthecost component𝑐𝑛𝛿𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑡+1𝑙isconvexwithrespecttobuildingheight(𝛿𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑡>0), describingthefactthattheconstructionoftallerbuildingbecomespro- gressivelycostlierduetogeographicandregulatoryconstraintslimiting residentialdevelopmentontheintensivemargin.5

Developerschoosetheoptimalintensityofdevelopmentforeachho- mogeneousunitoflandintheneighborhood.Thezero-profitcondition ismetandgovernstheequilibriumpriceofland𝑃𝑛𝑙𝑎𝑛𝑑.Totalhousing supplyis givenbytheproductofoptimalbuildingheight𝑛 andthe amountofdevelopableland𝐿𝑛availableintheneighborhood.Weas- sumethatthequantityoflandavailableforresidentialdevelopmentin theneighborhoodrespondsendogenouslytohousingpricesaccording to𝐿𝑛= ̄𝐿𝑛𝑃

1 𝛿𝑒𝑥𝑡𝑛 + 1

𝛿𝑖𝑛𝑡𝑛 𝛿𝑒𝑥𝑡𝑛

𝑛 ,where ̄𝐿𝑛 capturescharacteristicsoflocations shiftinglandsupply,andtheparameter𝛿𝑒𝑥𝑡𝑛 governsthe(inverse)re- sponsivenessofresidentiallandavailability(seeOnlineAppendixA).

Totalhousingsupplyinaneighborhoodisthengivenby 𝑄𝑠𝑛=𝑛𝐿𝑛=

( 𝑃𝑛 (𝛿𝑖𝑛𝑡𝑛 +1)𝑐𝑛

) 1

𝛿𝑖𝑛𝑡𝑛 ̄𝐿𝑛𝑃

1 𝛿𝑒𝑥𝑡𝑛 + 1

𝛿𝑖𝑛𝑡𝑛 𝛿𝑒𝑥𝑡𝑛

𝑛 =𝑆𝑛𝑃𝑛𝜖𝑛𝑄,𝑃, (2)

where 𝑆𝑛=𝑆𝑛(̄𝐿𝑛,𝑐𝑛,𝛿𝑖𝑛𝑡𝑛 ) summarizes exogenous housing supply shifters.Thestructuralparameter𝜖𝑄,𝑃𝑛 = 1

𝛿𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑡+ 1

𝛿𝑛𝑒𝑥𝑡+ 1

𝛿𝑛𝑖𝑛𝑡𝛿𝑒𝑥𝑡𝑛 ≥0corre- spondstothelocalhousingsupplyprice-elasticity,whichdependson thelocalresponsivenessofresidentialdevelopmentontheintensive(𝛿𝑖𝑛𝑡) andextensive(𝛿𝑒𝑥𝑡)margin.6

2.2. Realestateinvestors

We build on the framework proposed by DiPasquale and Wheaton(1992)andassumethatinvestorsarewillingtopayasquare meterprice𝑃𝑛forapropertygeneratingaperiodicrentalincome𝑅𝑛in neighborhood𝑛.Investorsthusmediatebetweentheproperty market -inwhichhouseholdsconsumehousingservices-andhousingdevel- opers.7Weassumethattheelasticityofbuildingtenurewithregardto capitalizationratedifferencesbetweenowner-occupiedandrentalprop- ertiesisinfinite.Putdifferently,investorsoptimallychoosewhetherto sellor rentoutaproperty,whichimpliesthatthecapitalizationrate ofrentalandsellingpropertiesisthesame.Ifitwerenotso,arbitrage opportunitieswouldarise,leadinginvestorstoshifttheirdemandfrom onerealestateassettotheother.8

Wedepartfromtheliteraturebyassumingthatinvestorsformex- pectationsendogenouslyaboutlocalrisk-adjustedreturns𝑟𝑛 andrent growth 𝑔𝑛 according to observed contemporaneous rents and prices,

5 Tallandhigh-risebuildingstypicallyrequirespecificbuildingmaterialsand specializedworkers,suchasarchitectsandengineers,thatensurethestabilityof itsstructure.Additionally,geographicandregulatoryconstraintsbecomemore binding,astheyaremorelikelytohinderverticaldevelopment.

6 Itiscommonintheliteraturetorepresenthousingsupplyelasticitywith asinglestructuralparameter𝜖enteringahousingsupplyfunctionoftheform 𝑄𝑠=𝑆𝑃𝜖,seee.g.,HsiehandMoretti(2019),Baum-SnowandHan,2021,and LinandWachter,2020.

7 Inthecaseofowner-occupancy,theinvestorrentsouttherealestateasset toherself.

8 Weassumethatrentalandsellingunitsare,onaverage,identicalwithina givenneighborhood,suchthatinvestors’expectationsarethesameduetothe no-arbitragecondition.InSection3.1,wethuspartialoutpotentialqualitydif- ferencesfromrentandpricedynamics.Theno-arbitrageassumptionisatthe coreofthestandardusercostapproachemployedbyHendershottandSlem- rod(1983),Poterba(1984),andMayerandSinai(2007).

i.e., 𝑟𝑛=𝑟𝑛(𝑅𝑛,𝑃𝑛) and𝑔𝑛=𝑔𝑛(𝑅𝑛,𝑃𝑛). Across periods, investors up- datetheirexpectationsbasedon thecapitalinvestmentthey haveto makeandthecorrespondingrentalincometheycouldpotentiallyearn at that time, thus leadingto heterogeneousexpectation adjustments across neighborhoods.Thisleads totheformula𝑃𝑛= 𝑅𝑛

𝑖𝑛(𝑅𝑛,𝑃𝑛), where 𝑖𝑛=𝑟𝑛(𝑅𝑛,𝑃𝑛)−𝑔𝑛(𝑅𝑛,𝑃𝑛)isthelocalcapitalizationrate.

Using thissimple framework,we can analyzethe propagationof rentalincomechangestothesupplyof housing.Therelativerespon- sivenessofhousingsupplytorentchangesisgivenby

𝜖𝑛𝑄,𝑅= 𝑅𝑛

𝑄𝑠𝑛 𝑑𝑄𝑠𝑛 𝑑𝑅𝑛 = 𝑃𝑛

𝑄𝑠𝑛 𝑑𝑄𝑠𝑛 𝑑𝑃𝑛

𝑅𝑛

𝑃𝑛 𝑑𝑃𝑛

𝑑𝑅𝑛 =𝜖𝑛𝑄,𝑃𝜖𝑃 ,𝑅𝑛 , (3) where𝜖𝑄,𝑃𝑛 isthestandardhousingsupplypriceelasticityinEq.(2),and 𝜖𝑛𝑃 ,𝑅isanamplificationcoefficientthatcorrespondstothepriceelasticity withrespecttorentchanges.Thislatterisdeterminedbytheresponsive- nessofthelocalcapitalizationratetorentchanges,i.e.,𝜖𝑛𝑃 ,𝑅=1−𝜖𝑖,𝑅𝑛 (seeOnlineAppendixA).Eq.(3)tellsusthathousingsupplyresponses torent andprice changesdifferwhentheelasticityofpricestorent changesisnotunitary.Ifthevaluationoflocalrealestateassetsisvery sensitivetolocalrentchanges,i.e.,𝜖𝑛𝑃 ,𝑅>1,thehousingsupplywill respondmorestronglytorentchangesthantopricechanges.Investors adjustmentofgrowthexpectationsandlocalriskcapturedbythecap- italizationratedeterminetheelasticityoflocalpricestolocalrents.If these factorswereindependentof rentdynamics, weshould observe identicalsupplyresponsestorentandpricechanges,whichisacentral hypothesiswetestempirically.9

Aparametrizationoflocalcapitalizationratesisinstructivetopro- videanintuitionaboutthewaywedifferfromtheliteratureandtoun- derstandtheidentificationassumptionsexposedinthenextsection.Let usassumethat𝑖𝑛=𝑖0𝑅𝛾𝑛𝑛𝑅𝑃𝑛𝛾𝑃𝑛,where𝑖0isthe“standard” capitalization rate,whichtheliteratureusuallyassumestobeexogenouslydetermined bycapitalmarkets.10Theparameters𝛾𝑛𝑅and𝛾𝑛𝑃representthelocalelas- ticityofcapitalizationrateswithrespecttorentandpriceshocks.Itis easytoshowthattheamplificationcoefficientispinneddownbythese twoparametersviatheequation𝜖𝑛𝑃 ,𝑅=1−𝛾𝑛𝑅

1+𝛾𝑛𝑃.Thisparametrizationpar- simoniouslyendogenizescapitalizationrateswhileallowingforspatial differencesintheinvestors’discountratewhenevaluatingrealestate assets.Ifweset𝛾𝑛𝑅=𝛾𝑛𝑃 =0,weobtainthestandardGordongrowth model.Empirically,wetestwhetherthisspatialgeneralizationof the Gordongrowthmodelismeaningful.11

2.3. Residents

The economyis endowed witha continuous measure of 𝑁 indi- vidualsdistributedacrossneighborhoods.Buildingonrecentworkby Monteetal.(2018),eachindividualworkinginindustry𝑘decidesin whichneighborhood𝑛toliveandinwhicharea𝑖towork.Theidiosyn- craticindirectutility𝑈𝑛𝑖𝑘 ofindividual𝜔isgivenby

𝑈𝑛𝑖𝑘(𝜔)=𝑏𝑘𝑛𝑖(𝜔)𝑊̃𝑛𝑖𝑘

𝑅𝛼𝑛 , (4)

9NotethatEq.(3)isvalidforanysupplyfunctionwhosepriceelasticityis describedbyasingleparameter.ThestructureimposedbyEq.(2)onlyservesthe purposeofillustratingtheidentificationassumptionsunderlyingtheempirical estimation.

10Ourresultsgeneralizetoaparametrizationthatallowsforlocalexogenous capitalizationrates𝑖0𝑛.InSection6,wechecktherobustnessofourresultswhen 𝑖0𝑛includeslocalmeasuresofliquidityrisksanduncertaintyintherevenuegen- eratedbytheproperty.

11Theexistingliteratureoncapitalizationratesempiricallydocumentsastrong heterogeneityincapitalizationratesacrossspace,withurbanandhigh-amenity areastypicallydisplayinglowercapitalizationrates.However,theexistingur- banliteraturelargelyneglectssuchdifferences.Ourparametrizationaccommo- datessuchfeatures.

(4)

wherewe setthepriceof thetradablenuméraireequaltounityand assumethatindividualsspendashare𝛼onhousing.Thevariable𝑊̃𝑛𝑖𝑘 denotestheindustry-specificwageofworkerslivingin𝑛andcommuting to𝑖.

Theutilitycomponent𝑏𝑘𝑛𝑖capturesidiosyncraticpreferencesthatdo notdependonmarketfundamentalsbut,rather,ontheexogenoustastes ofworkersforagivenplaceofresidence/placeofworkcombination.We assumesuchpreferencestobei.i.d.realizationsofaFréchet-distributed randomvariablewithscaleparameter𝐵𝑛𝑖𝑘 andshapeparameter𝜀𝑘>1. Thegreaterthevalueof𝜀𝑘,thelessheterogeneousarelocationalpref- erencesofworkersinagivenindustry,thusimplyinggreatermobility acrossspace.

Wemodel𝑊̃𝑛𝑖𝑘aswagepereffectiveunitsoflabor𝑊𝑛𝑖𝑘dividedby commutingcosts𝑚𝑛𝑖,implyingthatworkersreducelaborsupplywhen commutingfromdistantlocations.Ourfocusbeingonhousingmarkets, wedonotexplicitlymodelthedemandsideoflabormarkets,andcon- siderwages𝑊𝑛𝑖𝑘asanexogenousvariable.12

Givenhouseholdshomotheticpreferences,totalhousingdemand𝑄𝑑𝑛 inneighborhood𝑛isgivenby

𝑄𝑑𝑛 =𝛼𝑊̄𝑛

𝑅𝑛𝑁𝑛=𝛼 1 𝑅𝛼𝑛(1+𝜖𝑘)

𝑁 Φ

𝑖,𝑘𝐵𝑘𝑛𝑖 (𝑊𝑛𝑖𝑘

𝑚𝑛𝑖 )𝜖𝑘+1

, (5)

where𝑊̄𝑛= 𝑁1

𝑛

𝑖,𝑘𝑊𝑛𝑖𝑘

𝑚𝑛𝑖𝑁𝑛𝑖𝑘 istheweightedaverageincomeearnedin neighborhood𝑛,𝑁𝑛=∑

𝑖,𝑘𝑁𝑛𝑖𝑘 isthetotalnumberofhouseholdsliving in𝑛,andΦisacompositetermreflectingtheattractivenessofallother possiblepairsofresidence𝑟andemployment𝑠.13Eq.(5)providestwo insightsthatproveusefulwhenconstructinghousingdemandshifters.

Specifically,weshouldexpecthigherhousingdemandinneighborhoods thatarei)betterconnectedtoproductiveareas,andii)attractivealong oneofthedimensionscapturedbyidiosyncratictastes𝐵𝑘𝑛𝑖.InSection3, wederivetwoinstrumentsthatcaptureshiftsinhousingdemandtrig- geredbythesetwodimensionswhileremainingexogenouswithrespect tohousingsupplychanges.

2.4. Demandshocks,expectations,andhousingsupply

Inthissection,weoutlinecomparativestaticresultsonhowanex- ogenousdemandshockinformsusaboutchangesinhousingsupplyand adjustmentsofexpectations.Ininterestofparsimony,letusdenoteby 𝜃anylocalshockexclusivelyaffectingthedemandsideofthehousing marketasdescribedbyEq.(5),andassume thattheperiodiccostof housingservices– equilibriumrents– increasefollowingthisdemand shock,i.e.𝜕𝑅𝜕𝜃𝑛

𝑛 >0.

UsingEq.(2),thehousingsupplyresponsetoademandshock is givenby

𝜕𝑄𝑠𝑛

𝜕𝜃𝑛 = 𝑆𝑛𝜖𝑄,𝑃 𝑖𝑛 𝑃𝑛𝜖𝑄,𝑃−1

(𝜕𝑅𝑛

𝜕𝜃𝑛𝑃𝑛𝜕𝑖𝑛

𝜕𝜃𝑛

)

. (6)

Theterm𝑃𝑛𝜕𝜃𝜕𝑖𝑛

𝑛isresponsiblefortheamplificationofhousingsupply viachangesincapitalizationratesfollowingapositivedemandshock.14 Wearguethattheresponseoflocalcapitalizationrates toapositive demandshockisunequivocallynegative,i.e.𝜕𝑖𝑛

𝜕𝜃𝑛 <0,thusincreasingthe supplyofhousingwithrespecttothestandardGordonGrowthmodelin whichcapitalizationratesareexogenouslyfixedandonlythefirstterm inparenthesesremains.

12 Indeed,theidentificationstrategyexposedinSection3reliesonexogenous changesinlocallabordemand.Forthisreason,werefraintomodellaborde- mandendogenously.

13 SeeOnlineAppendixAforadetailedderivationofEq.(5).

14 Tokeepthenotationassimpleandgeneralaspossible,herewerefrainfrom explicitlyformalizingtheendogenousrelationshipbetweencapitalizationrates 𝑖𝑛andrents𝑅𝑛– whichareaffectedbythedemandshock– andsimplywrite

𝜕𝑖𝑛

𝜕𝜃𝑛.

This negativerelationshiparisesbecause,followingapositive de- mandshock,i)theperceptionoflocalrisklikelydecreases(𝜕𝑟𝑛

𝜕𝜃𝑛 <0), and/orii)rentgrowthexpectationsincrease(𝜕𝑔𝑛

𝜕𝜃𝑛>0).15Forexample, anunexpecteddemandshock𝜃capturingimprovementsoflocalameni- ties,orarelocationofasufficientlylargecompany,leadstochangesin localhousingdemandandthusalterinvestors’expectations.

Expectations arelikely to be formedaccording topastdynamics (see e.g.DiPasqualeandWheaton,1995). Our resultsare consistent with myopic expectation as documented for real estate markets by KuchlerandZafar(2019).Begleyetal.(2019)documentthathetero- geneousexpectationsaboutlocalpopulationgrowthleadtodifferences inlocalprice-rentratiosintheUS.Aslongasthelocaldemandincrease hassome unexpectedelement, myopicinvestors willadjusttheir ex- pectationsaboutthegrowthratesofrentsupwardsandthusdecrease capitalizationrates.

Theequilibriumfeatureofrentgrowthratesmakesitextremelydif- ficulttopredictthem,evenwheninvestorshavestrongpredictivecapa- bilitiesregardingfuturedemandchanges.First,housingsupplyreacts endogenouslyatthelocalleveltothedemandshock.Second,evenif ademandshockisinitiallylocalizedtoagivenneighborhood,itwill spreadthroughoutthecountryduetothespatialequilibriumcondition.

Thismakesitverydifficulttocorrectlypredictthe“final” effectofade- mandchangebasedonpastdynamics,anditrationalizestheadjustment ofexpectationsaftertherealizationofademandchange.16

Wenotethattheextenttowhichcapitalizationratesadjustfollow- ingapositivedemandshockarguablydependsontheinvestors’idiosyn- craticcharacteristicaffectingtheirabilitytobuildexpectations.Wein- vestigatethismatterinmoredetailinSection5.3.

3. Empiricalframework

Basedontheaboveframework,wederiveempiricalspecifications toestimatehousingsupplyelasticities𝜖𝑄,𝑃𝑛 and𝜖𝑄,𝑅𝑛 ,anddiscussthe corresponding identificationassumptions.Westartbyimposingaver- agesupplyelasticities𝜖𝑄,𝑃 and𝜖𝑄,𝑅commontoallneighborhoods.In thenextstep,weprovideaparametrizationallowingustoestimatehet- erogeneoushousingsupplyresponsivenessattheneighborhoodlevel.

3.1. Partiallingoutqualitydifferences

TheconceptualframeworkexposedinSection2implicitlyassumes thatthequalityofhousinggoodsishomogeneouswithinthesameneigh- borhoodandacrossrentalandsellingproperties.Therelativelysmall neighborhoodsinourprincipalempiricalanalysisjustifythisassump- tiontoacertainextent,aspropertiessharingsimilarhousingcharacter- isticstendtoclustertogether.

Yet,withinaneighborhood,differencesinthequalityandtypeof housinggoodsmayremain.Topreventpotentialqualitybias,inwhat follows,weremoveallpriceandrentvariationacrosslocationsthatorig- inatefromdifferencesinobservablehousingcharacteristics.Tothisend, weconstructlocal(log)priceandrentindicesfromhedonicregressions.

Specifically,ineachperiodweseparatelyestimate

ln𝜏𝑗𝑛𝑡=𝛾𝑛𝑡𝜏 +𝛽𝑡𝜏𝐀𝑗𝑛𝑡+𝜖𝜏𝑗𝑛𝑡, 𝜏=𝑅,𝑃 (7) where𝜏𝑗𝑛denoteseitherthepriceorrentofproperty𝑗inneighborhood 𝑛attime𝑡.Thevector𝐀𝑗𝑛𝑡includesacomprehensivesetofattributes suchashousingsurface,theaveragenumberofrooms,age,agesquared, andanindicatorforsingle-familyvs.multi-familyhouses.𝜖𝜏𝑗𝑛𝑡denotes theerrorterm.

15Giventhatrentexpectations entercapitalizationratesnegatively,anin- creaseinexpectedrentalgrowthdecreaseslocalcapitalizationrates.

16Fortheinstrumentsusedbelow,wefindthatpastdynamicsexplainonlyvery littleofthevariationsuchthatdemandchangescannotbeperfectlyanticipated basedonpastdynamics.

(5)

Weusetheestimatedneighborhood-timefixed-effects𝛾𝑛𝑡𝜏 asquality- adjustedlog-prices(log-rents)ln𝑃𝑛𝑡(ln𝑅𝑛𝑡).17Notethatthecoefficients 𝛽𝑡𝜏aretime-variant,suchthatthevaluationofhousingcharacteristics canflexiblychangefromperiodtoperiod.

3.2. Model-informedidentificationofaveragesupplyelasticities

Log-linearizing supplyEq. (2), expressing prices asa functionof quantities,andfirstdifferencing,in equilibrium18 weobtainthefol- lowingempiricalspecification

Δ ln𝑃𝑛=𝛼𝑃+ 1

𝜖𝑄,𝑃Δ ln𝑄𝑛+Δ ln𝑆𝑛𝑃, (8) where𝜖𝑄,𝑃1 istheaverageinversehousingsupplyelasticitycommonto allneighborhoodsandΔdenotesatimedifferencebetween2005and 2015.Theterm𝛼𝑃 denotestheaveragevalueofchangesinobserved supplyshifterscommontoallneighborhoodsand,inaslightabuseof notation,Δ ln𝑆𝑛𝑃representsthecorrespondingmean-centeredvariable.

Time-invariantcomponentsarepartialledoutfromΔ ln𝑆𝑛𝑃 byfirstdif- ferencing,suchthatonlydynamicsupplyshiftersenterEq.(8).

EstimatingEq.(8)byOLSlikelyleadstobiasedestimatesofthepa- rameterofinterestduetotheendogeneityofΔ ln𝑄𝑛 viathedemand side.This isapparentfromEq.(5)whenwriting changesinhousing demandas

Δ ln𝑄𝑛=Δ ln𝑊̄𝑛+Δ ln𝑁𝑛−Δ ln𝑅𝑛. (9) Therefore,estimatesof 1

𝜖𝑄,𝑃 inEq.(8)arepotentiallybiasedduetoi) acorrelationofthecomponentsof housingdemand changessuchas changesinaveragewagesandnumberofresidentswithchangesofun- observedsupplyshiftersinΔ ln𝑆𝑛𝑃 (omittedvariablebias),andii)the impactofhousingpricesviachangesinrentsonhousingdemand(re- versecausality).

AccordingtoEq.(2)(seeOnlineAppendixA),Δ ln𝑆𝑛𝑃 includes,in additiontoexogenoussupplyshifters,changesinlocalconstructioncost.

Changesinthepriceofconstructionmaterialsandthecosttomakeland availableforresidentialdevelopmentareunlikelytodifferacrossspace, mostlyduetothesmallcountrysize.Onthecontrary,shiftsinhousing demandmightaffectconstructioncostsviawages.

Topartiallyaddressdifferencesinconstructioncostsacrossneigh- borhoods,wecontrol,inafirststep,forseveralsupplyshiftersinEq.(8). Let𝐗𝑛 denotethevectorcontainingsuchcontrols.19Inparticular,𝐗𝑛 includesconstructioncostindicesi.e.,changes inlabor andmaterial costsdefinedforthemainnationalconstructionmarkets,theintensity ofhistoricaldevelopmentasmeasuredbydevelopmentdensityin1980 andterrainruggedness.AccordingtoHilberandRobert-Nicoud(2013), thehistoriclevelofhousingdevelopmentproxiesforthefactthathigh- amenityareasdevelopfirstandtendtoadoptmorestringentland-use regulationsovertime.Controllingforterrainruggednesstakesintoac- countthatplotsoflandfeaturinggeographiccharacteristicsfavorable todevelopmentsuchasflatandnon-rockysurfacesarelikelydeveloped beforethoseshowingadversegeographiccharacteristics.Therefore,we expectunfavorablegeographicfeaturestoincreaserentsandpricesover time,asdevelopersfacehigherconstructioncostsforprovidingaddi- tionalhousingunitsontheextensivemarginofexistingdevelopment.

Similarly,wecontrolfortheelevationoftheland.Wefurthercontrolfor thedistancetothenearestcentralbusinessdistrictstocapturepotential

17 Notethatallourresultsarerobusttoallowingforregion-specificvaluations ofhousingattributes,i.e.,theinclusionof𝛽𝑟𝑡 whereregions𝑟aredefinedas cantonsorcommutingzonescontainingasufficientnumberoflocations𝑛.

18 Inequilibrium𝑄𝑑𝑛=𝑄𝑠𝑛=𝑄𝑛holds,suchthatweomitsupplyanddemand superscriptsinwhatfollows.

19 Notethatsuchcontrolsmightalsopartialoutqualitydifferencesnotfully capturedbyhedonicindices.

timetrenddifferentialsinthelaborsupply(anddemand)acrossspace.

Thesevariablesmightalsocapturechangesintransportationcosts.20 Despite controlling for several supply shifters, omitted variables and reverse causality may still bias the estimation of Eq. (8). To solve this issue, we proposean instrumental variableapproach that aimstoexclusivelyshifthousingdemandwhileleavinghousingsup- plyunchanged.Specifically,werequireaninstrument,denotedΔ ln𝑍𝑛, whichisrelevantforhousingdemandchangeswhileremainingexoge- noustosupplychangesconditionalonthesetof controlsin 𝐗𝑛,i.e., 𝐸(Δ ln𝑍𝑛Δ ln𝑆𝑛𝑃|𝐗𝑛)=0.

AsapparentfromEq.(9),wecannotuseobservedchangesin the componentsofthehousingdemand,asinequilibriumtheyareaffected bytensionforcesbetweenhousingdemandandsupply.Followingthere- centworkbyBaum-SnowandHan,2021,weisolateexogenouschanges inlabordemandgiventhespatiallinkages(commutingcost)ofaneigh- borhoodwithemploymentcenters.Wedefine

Δ ln𝑍𝑛=∑

𝑖,𝑘

𝟏(𝑚𝑛𝑖𝑡0<1hour)

𝑚𝑛𝑖𝑡0 𝑓𝑛𝑡𝑘0Δ ln𝐹𝐶𝑘(𝑛), (10) wheretheindicatorfunction𝟏(𝑚𝑛𝑖𝑡0<1hour)equalsoneforneighbor- hoods𝑖thatarelocatedatmostat60minutestraveltimefromneigh- borhood𝑛,andzerootherwise.21Thequantity𝑓𝑛𝑡𝑘0representstheshare ofemploymentbelongingtosector𝑘inneighborhood𝑛attime𝑡0.The termΔ ln𝐹𝐶(𝑘𝑛)isthecorrespondingaggregategrowthrateofemploy- mentinindustry𝑘over[𝑡,𝑡0]inregion𝐶inwhichneighborhood𝑛is located.22

The intuition behind Eq. (10) is straightforward.We computea weightedemploymentgrowthofthepredeterminedsectoralcomposi- tionintheproximityofagivenneighborhoodbyimposingacommon industrygrowthequaltotheonethatoccurredintheregion𝐶inwhich theneighborhoodislocated.Takingintoaccounttheproximityinterms ofcommutingtimetootherneighborhoodsisofparticularrelevancein thecaseofsmallspatialunits,e.g.,neighborhoods,asmostindividuals likelydonotworkinthesameneighborhoodwheretheylive.Weuse aone-hourradiusforthemaximumcommutingdistanceinthebench- markanalysis,asthisleadstothestrongestpredictivepowerofthein- strument.

Two features in thewaywe computeΔ ln𝑍𝑛 support exogeneity claimswithrespecttounobservedsupplydynamics.First,inlinewith Bartik(1991),weexcludeneighborhood𝑛itselffromthecomputation ofΔ ln𝐹𝐶𝑘(𝑛).Second,weexcludeallsectorsrelatedtoconstructionand realestatefrom𝑓𝑛𝑡𝑘0andΔ ln𝐹𝐶𝑘(𝑛).Therefore,theinstrumentcaptures weightedchangesinlabordemandthatarenotrelatedtotheconstruc- tionsector.

TheinstrumentdefinedbyEq.(10)isashift-shareinstrumentinline withBartik(1991).23Recently,Adãoetal.,2019,Borusyaketal.,2021, andGoldsmith-Pinkhametal., 2020investigatedtheeconometricas- sumptionsnecessaryforthevalidityofshift-shareinstruments.These instrumentsarevalidifeitherinitialsharesareindependentandran- domlyassignedacrossobservationsorgrowthshocksoccurrandomly acrossregions.Inoursetting,wearguethatinitialsectoralsharesare exogenouswithrespecttochangesinunobservedsupplyshiftersandlo- calrentandpricedynamics.Thesectoraldistributionofemploymentis highlypersistentandlargelydeterminedbynaturalamenitiesandmar- ketaccess,suchthatthehistoricsectoraldistributionisunlikelytobe

20Ofcourse,thesecontrolvariablesalsoaffecthousingdemand.Inthiscase, includingtheminthesupplyfunctionisevenmoreimportantastheyreduce endogeneityissuesarisingfromchangesinhousingdemandaccordingtoEq.(9).

21Wesettraveltimewithinthesamemunicipalityto1minute.

22Inourbaselineresults,weuseCantonsasaggregateregion𝐶,whichrepre- sent26upper-tieradministrativeunits.Ourresultsarerobustusinglowertier regions,suchasdistricts(Bezirke).

23GrahamandMakridis,2021introducearelatedidentificationstrategycom- biningvariationintheinitialdistributionofhousingcharacteristicstogether withanationaldemandshiftforthesecharacteristics.

(6)

correlatedwithrecentchangesoflocalhousingsupplyshiftersΔ ln𝑆𝑃. FollowingGoldsmith-Pinkhametal.,2020,inSection6,weassestheva- lidityoftheidentifyingvariationbycomputingtheRotembergweights foreachsector.

WefurthersupportexogeneityclaimsregardingΔ ln𝑍𝑛bycompar- ingourresultswiththoseobtainedusinganalternativeshift-sharein- strumentbasedonthedistributionoflanguageshares.24Specifically,for eachneighborhoodwecomputethehistoricalshareoflanguageshares andinteractthemwiththecantonalgrowthoftherespectivelanguage group.25Assumingthattheidiosyncraticutilityshiftercanbedecom- posedas𝐵𝑘𝑛𝑖=𝐵𝑛𝐵𝑖𝑘inEq.(5),wecaninterpretthisinstrumentaspre- dictingdemandchangesviaashiftintheidiosyncraticpreferences𝐵𝑛 toliveinaneighborhood𝑛.

Theno-arbitrageconditionforinvestorspurchasingrealestateassets preventsthatthedemandshockscapturedbyourtwoinstrumentsare tenurespecific(seeSection2.2).Evenifoneofthedemandshockswere morerelevanttoaspecificpartofthepopulationthatismoreinclined torentorown,itwouldpropagateacrosstenuresduetochangesinat- tractivenessofinvestments.InthecontextofSwitzerland,thecloselink betweentherentalandowner-occupiedmarketsisreflectedinahousing marketthatisapproximatelyequallysplitbetweenrenters(56%)and owner-occupiers(44%).Thecloselinkbetweendifferenthousingmar- ketsegmentsissupportedbyrecentworkofMense(2020)forGermany, acountrydisplayingsimilarhousingmarketconditionsasSwitzerland.

Specifically,theauthorshowsthatthelocalconstructionofhigh-quality housingunitslowersrentsthroughouttherentdistributionshortlyafter thenewunitsarecompleted.

Theestimationofthesupplyelasticitywithrespecttorentchanges 𝜖𝑄,𝑅𝑛 followsthesamelogicasbefore.Bysubstitutingtherelationship betweenpricesandrentsarisingfromtheparametrizationofcapitaliza- tionratesintoEq.(8),andisolating𝑅𝑛,weobtain

Δ ln𝑅𝑛=𝛼𝑅+ 1

𝜖𝑄,𝑅Δ ln𝑄𝑛+Δ ln𝑆𝑛𝑅 (11) where𝜖𝑄,𝑅1 =𝜖𝑄,𝑃1𝜖𝑃 ,𝑅,andweassumethatthevector𝐗𝑛capturingthe observablesupplyshiftersdiscussedaboveiscontrolledfor.Thenew errortermisΔ ln𝑆𝑛𝑅= 1

𝜖𝑃 ,𝑅Δ ln𝑆𝑛𝑃.Becausethisnewerrortermequals theoneofEq.(8)timesaconstantstructuralparameter,theprevious discussionoftheidentificationassumptionsstillholds.26

Weconcludethissectionbynotingthataveragehousingsupplyprice andrentelasticityestimatescanunambiguouslyberecoveredfromin- versesupplyequations(8)and(11)simplybytakingtheinverseofthe estimatedvaluefor𝜖𝑄,𝑃1 and𝜖𝑄,𝑅1 ,respectively.27

Housingsupplyelasticityestimatesallowus,inturn,toestimateelas- ticityparameters𝜖𝑃 ,𝑅and𝜖𝑖,𝑅.28

Estimatingtheinversesupplyfunction,ratherthanthedirectone,is acommonapproachintheliterature(e.g.Saiz,2010)thatoffersseveral advantages.First,usingasdependentvariablesquality-adjustedprices andrentsresultingfromahedonicregressiondoesnotrequireadditional

24 Saiz(2007)usesasimilarapproachbycomputingashift-shareinstrument basedonthenumberofimmigrantsmovingintoU.S.cities.

25 SeeOnlineAppendixCforaformaldefinitionoftheinstrument.

26 Theexogenouscomponentofthecapitalizationrate𝑖0iscapturedbythe rent-specificconstant𝛼𝑅inEq.(11).Ifweassumetheparametrizationoflocal capitalizationratesexposedinSection2andallowforlocation-specificcapital- izationrates𝑖0𝑛,theerrorterminEq.(11)becomesΔ ln𝑆𝑛𝑅+𝜖𝑃 ,𝑅1 1+1𝛾𝑃

𝑛Δ ln𝑖0𝑛. Thus,theexogeneityoftheinstrumentmustalsoholdwithrespecttolocation- specificexogenouscapitalizationrates.InSection6,weshowthatincluding severalcontrolsproxyingforΔ ln𝑖0𝑛doesnotaffectourresults.

27 Thisrelationshipbetweeninversesupplyequationsandhousingsupplyelas- ticityparameterestimatesispurelymechanicalanddoesnothingeonadditional identificationassumptions.Weobtainidenticalpointestimateswhenestimating non-invertedsupplyequations.

28 Assumingthattheidentificationassumptionsunderlyingthe2SLSestima- tionof𝜖𝑄,𝑃 and𝜖𝑄,𝑅hold,accordingto(3)wecanestimate ̂𝜖𝑃 ,𝑅= ̂𝜖̂𝜖𝑄,𝑅𝑄,𝑃 and

̂𝜖𝑖,𝑅=1−̂𝜖𝑃 ,𝑅.

statisticaltreatment.Thisisnotthecaseifquality-adjustedprices(and rents)areusedasregressors,astheirstandarderrorsarenotvalidand needtobebootstrapped.Second,instrumentalvariablestendtobemore relevantforquantitychangesthanforpriceones,therebyimprovingthe precisionof theestimates.Third, estimatinginversesupplyfunctions allowsustoinstrumentthesamevariable(i.e.,Δ ln𝑄𝑛)torecoverthe responsivenessofhousingsupplytopriceandrentchanges.This,inturn, facilitatesthecomparisonofthecoefficientsacrossspecifications.

3.3. Localsupplyresponsivenessandtheroleofgeographicandregulatory constraints

Eqs.(8)and(11)assumethatinversesupplyelasticitieswithrespect topricesandrentsareconstantacrosslocations.However,ourconcep- tualframeworksuggeststhathousingsupplyelasticityvariesatthelocal level,bothattheintensiveandextensivemarginofresidentialdevelop- ment.Ontheintensivemargin,theempiricalliteraturepointsoutthat supplyelasticitymightvary considerablyaccordingtoregulatoryre- strictions– suchasheightrestriction,floortoarearatios,etc.– adopted bylocalgovernments.AccordingtoHilberandRobert-Nicoud(2013), attractiveplacesarehistoricallymoredevelopedand,asanoutcomeof thepoliticalgamebetweenlanddevelopersandownersofdeveloped land,moreregulated.Ontheextensivemargin,Saiz(2010)pointsout thatsuchconstraintsareempiricallyrelevantonlywhenthereisenough development tomakethembinding.29 Toimplementsuchconsidera- tionsempirically,wethusfollowSaiz(2010)andusethefollowingap- proximation

1

𝜖𝑛𝑄,𝜏𝛽𝑎𝑣𝑔,𝜏+𝛽ℎ𝑖𝑠𝑡,𝜏×𝑄1980𝑛 +𝛽𝑐𝑜𝑛𝑠𝑡𝑟,𝜏× Λ𝑛×𝑄1980𝑛 , 𝜏=𝑅,𝑃, (12) wheretheobservedhistoricstockin1980𝑄1980𝑛 proxiesforregulation constraintson theintensivemargin,accordingtoHilberandRobert- Nicoud(2013).ThevariableΛ𝑛isameasuresummarizingthemostim- portantgeographicandregulatoryconstraintsontheextensivemargin.

InsertingsuchapproximationinEqs.(8)and(11),wethenestimatethe followingequation

Δln(𝜏𝑛)=𝛼𝜏+𝛽𝑎𝑣𝑔,𝜏Δln(𝑄𝑛)+𝛽ℎ𝑖𝑠𝑡,𝜏Δln(𝑄𝑛𝑄1980𝑛

+𝛽𝑐𝑜𝑛𝑠𝑡𝑟,𝜏Δln(𝑄𝑛)× Λ𝑛×𝑄1980𝑛 +Δ ln𝑆𝑛𝜏, 𝜏=𝑅,𝑃, (13) wherewecontrolagainfor𝐗𝑛 (whichincludeshistoricdevelopment 𝑄1980𝑛 )aswellasforthemaineffectofextensivemarginconstraintsΛ𝑛. Tworemarksareworthnoting.First,Λ𝑛 isinteractedwiththehistoric stock level 𝑄1980𝑛 , thusallowing theimpact ofregulatory constraints tobecomemorebindinginmore-developedplaces.Havingestimated the parameters 𝛽𝑎𝑣𝑔,𝜏,𝛽ℎ𝑖𝑠𝑡,𝜏,and𝛽𝑐𝑜𝑛𝑠𝑡𝑟,𝜏, we thenrecover 𝜖𝑄,𝜏𝑛 using Eq.(12).Second,theidentificationassumptionsofthepriceandrent equationinEq.(13)arethesameasinEqs.(8)and(11)provided𝑄1980𝑛 andΛ𝑛areexogenouswithrespecttoΔ ln𝑆𝜏.

4. Dataanddescriptivestatistics

Theempiricalanalysisreliesonseveraldatasources.Furtherinfor- mationisavailableinOnlineAppendixB.

4.1. Datasources

HousingdataWeusegeo-referenceddataonadvertisedresidential propertiesprovidedbyMeta-Sys.Thedatasetcontainsapproximately 2.1millionpostingsofrentalpropertiesandabout0.8millionpostings ofsellingresidencesforthewholeofSwitzerlandfrom2004to2016.

Inadditiontoaskingrentsandprices,thedatasetincludescompre- hensive informationon housingcharacteristics.The FederalRegister

29Forexample,protectedforestlikelyhinderresidentialdevelopmentonlyif noothertypeofdevelopablelandisavailableintheneighborhood.

(7)

ofBuildingsandHabitationspublishedbytheSwissFederalStatistical Office(FSO)providesacensusoftheresidentialhousingstockofthe country.Changesinthehousingstockaremeasuredeveryfiveyears, providingthreetimeperiods2005,2010,and2015thatoverlapwith ouradvertisementdata.Upto2015,theregistercontainsapproximately 4.8millionhousingunitsforthewholeofSwitzerland,11.5percentof whichwerebuiltbetween2005and2015.The2000BuildingCensus (publishedbytheFSO)providesinformationonwhetheradwellingis aprimaryorsecondaryresidenceinthatyear.

Socio-demographicandeconomicdataWeusetheFederalPopu- lationCensusof2000(publishedbytheFSO)aswellasthePopulation andHouseholdsSurveyfrom2010to2015(publishedbytheFSO)to infergeo-referencedhomeownershipratesandtoobtaininformationon predeterminedlevelsandchangesinthelocalsocio-demographiccom- positioni.e.,nationalityandlanguageofresidentslivinginagivenarea.

The2000FederalPopulationCensusprovidesinformationonthetype of buildingowner,suchaslandlords andinstitutional investors.The FSOpublishesaconstructionindextrackingthecostevolutionofmate- rialandlaborintheconstructionsectorforsevenstatisticalareas.We obtaineddetailedinformationaboutthespatialdistributionofemploy- mentandfirmsbysectorfromtheStructuralBusinessStatistics(STA- TENT).WeusetheNOGA1sectorclassification,whichcomprises16 differentsectorsinthecaseofSwitzerland.30 Wecombinethis infor- mationwithdataaboutroadtraveltimeprovidedbywww.search.chto constructalocalmeasurelabormarketaccess.

RegulatoryandgeographicdataTheLandUseStatisticsofSwitzer- land(publishedbytheFSO)providessatellite-basedlandcoverdata, allowingustoidentifygeographicconstraints,suchaslakes,rocks,and glaciers,andareassubjecttoparticularregulations.Informationabout regulationsontheextensivemarginandprotectedareasinparticular isobtainedfromCantonalofficesof spatialplanningandtheFederal OfficefortheEnvironment(FOEN).

OtherdataWecomplementtheabovedatawithavarietyofdata onSwissadministrativeunitsandmetropolitanareas(publishedbythe FSO)andelevation(EuropeanEnvironmentAgency).Weidentifythe agglomerationsofthe15maincitiesinSwitzerland,asdefinedbythe FSO,andcomputethedistanceofeachneighborhoodtotheclosestcity center.

4.2. Datastructureanddescriptivestatistics

Westructurethedatabypartitioningthewholeterritoryofthecoun- tryintosmall squareneighborhoodsof2x2km.Weaggregate hous- ingstock,socio-demographicandeconomicdata,andgeographicand regulatoryconstraintswithinthese neighborhoods.31 Weassigneach neighborhoodtooneof2324municipalities,whichrepresentthelow- estgovernmentaltierinSwitzerlandandhaveaninfluenceonlanduse regulation.

From2005to2015,rentshaveincreasedbyapproximately14per- centwhileprices haveincreasedbyapproximately35percent atthe countrylevel.32Overthesameperiod,thehousingstockgrewbyap- proximately11percent.Despitethesegeneraltrends,stock,rent,and pricedynamicsareheterogeneousacrossspace,asillustratedinFig.1. Specifically,Fig.1shows stock,rent,andpriceindex growthin ma- jorcities(PanelA)andthecountryside(PanelB)from2005to2015, using2005asthebaseyear(=100).Overtheconsideredperiod,hous- ingstockgrewalmosttwiceasmuchinthecountrysideareasthanin cities.Thissuggeststhatincitiesalackofdevelopablelandinconjunc-

30 ThisclassificationcorrespondstothemajorSICindustrygroupsintheU.S.

31 Ourresultsarerobusttoalternativeneighborhoodsizes,asdiscussedin Section6.

32 FornewtenancyagreementsmarketrentsapplyinSwitzerland.Toprevent abusiveincreases,propertyownerscanadjustrentsforexistingtenancyagree- mentsonlyifsomeformalcriteriaaremet.However,severalexceptionsinthe regulationallowlandlordstoadjustrentstolocalmarketlevels.

Fig.1. Rent,price,andstockdynamicsNotes:Citiesinclude2x2kmneigh- borhoodslocatedinoneofthe15mainmunicipalitiesofthecorresponding biggesturbanareasaccordingto2015boundaries.Thetwopanelsshowindex growthfrom2005to2015oftheconsideredvariables,using2005asthebase year(=100).Stockismeasuredasthetotalnumberofdwellings,andrentsand pricesaremeasuredasadvertisedaveragerentsandpricespersquaremeter.

SeeOnlineAppendixB.2foradefinitionofmajorSwissagglomerations.

tionwithgeographicandregulatoryconstraintshindersfurtherdevel- opment.Giventhiscomparativelylowerresponsivenessofhousingde- velopmentincities,itisnotsurprisingthatrentsandpricesgrewmore intheseareasthaninthecountryside.Interestingly,from2007onward, rentsandpricedynamicshavestartedtodivergeconsiderably-with pricesrisingatafasterpace-whichimpliesthatcapitalizationrates havebeenreviseddownwardintheselocations.

InFig.2,weshow themostimportantgeographicandregulatory constraintsfor housingdevelopment inSwitzerland. Geographic fea- tures preventingany form of development areanimportantcompo- nent of the Swisslandscape. Similarlyto Saiz (2010) andLutz and Sand(2019),wedefineundevelopablelandaslandthatislocatedabove 2000 m andwhose landcover corresponds to unproductive vegeta- tion,vegetation-freeareas,orrocks,andglaciers.33 Waterbodiessig- nificantlyreduce theamountofdevelopablelandintheproximityof majoragglomerations,asvirtuallyallmajorCBDsareadjacenttoalake orriver.34

Inadditiontogeographicconstraints,therearesignificantregula- toryrestrictionsinplacethatpreventorhinderdevelopmentinspecific areas.We refertomeasuresthatprevent newconstructiononunde- velopedlandasregulationsontheextensivemargin.Regulationsonthe extensivemarginincludeforests35,UNESCOculturalornaturalheritage sites,parks,andotherhigh-valuenaturalamenityareas.Theserestric- tionsaccountforapproximately49.1percentoftheSwissterritory.Total restrictedareasobtainedbyoverlappinggeographicandregulatorycon- straintsattheextensivemarginamounttoapproximately67.3percent ofthecountry’ssurface.Theremaining32.7percentofthecountry’ssur- face(whiteareainFig.2)isavailablefordevelopmentunderdifferent

33Ourdataallowsustocompilethismeasureatevenfinerscalethanprevious literature.

34Thisismainlyduetothecompetitiveadvantageofareasintheproximityof waterbodiesduringtheIndustrialRevolutionandthesubsequenturbanization ofSwitzerland.

35Inresponsetothegrowingindustrializationofthecountry,in1876,Switzer- landpassedafederallawprohibitingfurtherdeforestation,defactofreezing forestareastothelevelobservedatthattime.Thelawhasremainedmainlyun- changedtothepresentday.Asaconsequence,forestareasinhighlypopulated regionshaveremainedpracticallyunchangedsince1876.

(8)

Fig.2.ConstraintstodevelopmentNotes:Wedefinegeographicconstraintsasundevelopableland,whichcorrespondstoaplotoflandlocatedabove2000m,or whoselanduseclassificationcorrespondstounproductivevegetation,vegetation-freeareas,orrocksandglaciers.Exceptforforests,redareassummarizeregulatory constraintsontheextensivemargin.Swissforestsareprotectedareassince1876.(Forinterpretationofthereferencestocolourinthisfigurelegend,thereaderis referredtothewebversionofthisarticle.)

Table1

Inversehousingsupplyelasticity– averageestimates.

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

ΔLog P ΔLog R ΔLog P ΔLog R ΔLog P ΔLog R

ΔLog Q 2.367 ∗∗∗ 0.694 ∗∗ 2.004 ∗∗∗ 0.747 ∗∗∗ 2.084 ∗∗∗ 0.735 ∗∗∗

(0.442) (0.287) (0.342) (0.215) (0.316) (0.191)

Amplification 𝜖𝑃 ,𝑅 3.411 2.683 2.835

Instruments I I L L I & L I & L

Observations 2,498 2,498 2,498 2,498 2,498 2,498

Kleibergen-Paap F 15.61 15.61 71.39 71.39 42.76 42.76

Overidentification - - - - 0.40 0.87

Notes:Standarderrorsinparentheses𝑝<.10,∗∗𝑝<.05,∗∗∗𝑝<.01.Standarderrorsareclusteredatthemunicipalitylevel.Thesamplecoverstheperiod2005–2015.

TheAdãoetal.,2019standarderrorsforcolumns(1),(2),(3),and(4)are0.100,0.048,0.386,and0.198,respectively.Theunitsofobservationsareobtained bypartitioningSwitzerlandin2x2kmneighborhoods.Logrentsandlogpricesarequality-adjustedwithrespecttothelivingsurface,thenumberofrooms,age, agesquared,andbuildingtype.Allregressionscontrolforsupplyshifters,whichincludeelevation,elevationstandarddeviation,log-distancetothenearestCBD, log-housingstockin1980,totalrestrictedareas,andchange(2005–2015)inconstructioncosts.SeeOnlineAppendixEfordetailedestimationresultsandfirststages.

ChangesinhousingstockΔLogQ,areinstrumentedusingashift-shareinstrumentforindustriesIincolumns(1)and(2),ashift-shareinstrumentformainspoken languagesLincolumns(3)and(4),andboththeseinstrumentsI&Lincolumns(5)and(6).

regulatorymeasuresdeterminingtheintensityandtypeofresidential development.

5. Results

5.1. Supplyelasticityestimatesandamplificationmechanism

Table1summarizesaveragesupplyelasticityestimateswithrespect toprice(columns1,3,and5)andrent(columns2,4,and6)changes,re- spectively.Columns1and2reportestimatesbasedontheshift-sharein- strumentΔ ln𝑍𝑛derivedfromhistoricindustryshares(usedasabench- mark).Columns3and4reportthecorrespondingeffectsfortheshift-

shareinstrumentderivedfromhistoriclanguageshares.Columns5and 6showtheresultswhenusingthetwoinstrumentssimultaneously.Since ourmodelframeworkinSection2establisheslabormarketshocksasa source ofshiftsin housingdemand,we refertotheresults basedon industrysharesasourbaselineestimates.

Responsivenessestimatesbasedontheindustryinstrumentareequal to𝜖𝑄,𝑅= 1

0.694 =1.44forrentand𝜖𝑄,𝑃= 1

2.367 =0.42forpricechanges.

These results show that, on average,the housingsupplyin Switzer- landisrelativelyelastictorentchanges,butlesssotopricechanges.

Thecorrespondingamplificationeffectis𝜖𝑃 ,𝑅=𝜖𝑄,𝑅

𝜖𝑄,𝑃 =3.43.Thecoun- try’saverage responseoflocal capitalizationratestorent changesis thus𝜖𝑖,𝑅=1−𝜖𝑃 ,𝑅=−2.43,suggestingthatinvestorsreviselocalrent

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

According to Zhang Shuming, counsellor qualities fall into 2 categories: basic qualities and basic abilities, respectively including political qualities, moral qualities, expertise,

The coefficient estimate suggest that there is one-to-one relationship between changes in tax rate and total income: for every 1 percent rise in the marginal tax rate,

The framework is based on a theoretical model of horizontal differentiation à la Hotelling introduced in (Calveras, A. We modify this model by introducing a demand function

These considerations lead us to the next conclusion that in the residential housing market with a discriminating monopoly, both asking and transaction prices

2009- 2050 yılları arasında kalan dönemde konut talebi yıllık ortalama yüzde 1,48 oranında artarken; söz konusu artışın yüzde 1,08’lik kısmının

Thus, private investors attracted by those structures will not necessarily be interested in social housing investments, unless additional tax advantages are granted

Rezultatele econometrice mai arată slaba influenţă a ratei dobânzii asupra cursului de schimb în condiţiile în care regimul valutar în România este cel de flotare

- primul canal este creat de efectele modificării directe a ratei dobânzii de politică monetară care exercită influențe asupra celorlalte rate de dobândă cum ar fi cele oferite