• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Recent Advances in Backward Stochastic Riccati Equations and their Applications

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Recent Advances in Backward Stochastic Riccati Equations and their Applications"

Copied!
25
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Riccati Equations and Their Applications

Michael Kohlmann y

Shanjian Tang z

October 25, 2000

Abstract

ThefollowingbackwardstochasticRiccatidierentialequation(BSRDEinshort)

8

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

<

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

:

dK = [A

0

K+KA+ d

X

i=1 C

0

i KC

i

+Q+ d

X

i=1 (C

0

i L

i +L

i C

i )

(KB+ d

X

i=1 C

0

i KD

i +

d

X

i=1 L

i D

i )(N+

d

X

i=1 D

0

i KD

i )

1

(KB+ d

X

i=1 C

0

i KD

i +

d

X

i=1 L

i D

i )

0

]dt+ d

X

i=1 L

i dw

i

; 0t<T;

K(T) = M:

is motivated, and is then studied. Some properties are presented. The existence

anduniquenessofaglobaladaptedsolutionto aBSRDEhasbeenopenforthecase

D

i

6=0formorethantwodecades. Ourrecentresultsonthistopic aresummarized.

Finally,applicationsare addressed,bothinnanceand control.

Key words: backward stochasticRiccatiequation,stochasticlinear-quadraticcon-

trolproblem,mean-variance hedging, variance-optimalmartingale measure

AMS Subject Classications. 93E20, 60H10, 91B28

Abbreviated title: Backward stochastic Riccati equations and applications

1 Introduction

Let(;F;P;fF

t g

t0

)beaxedcompleteprobabilityspaceonwhichisdenedastandard

d-dimensionalF

t

-adaptedBrownian motionw(t)(w

1

(t);;w

d (t))

0

. Denoteby F

t the

Bothauthors gratefullyacknowledge the support bythe CenterofFinance and Econo-

metrics,University of Konstanz.

y

DepartmentofMathematicsandStatistics,UniversityofKonstanz,D-78457,Konstanz,Germany

z

DepartmentofMathematics,FudanUniversity,Shanghai200433,China. Thisauthorissupported

byaResearchFellowshipfromtheAlexandervonHumboldtFoundationandbytheNational

Natural ScienceFoundation ofChina underGrantNo. 79790130.

(2)

completion,bythetotalityN ofallnullsetsofF,ofthenaturalltrationfF

t

ggenerated

by w.

Consider the following BSRDE:

8

>

>

<

>

>

:

dK = G(t;K;L)dt+ d

X

i=1 L

i dw

i

; 0t <T;

K(T) = M

(1)

where the generator G isgiven by

G(t;K;L) := A 0

K+KA+ d

X

i=1 C

0

i KC

i

+Q+ d

X

i=1 (C

0

i L

i +L

i C

i

)+F(t;K;L) (2)

with

F(t;K;L):= [KB(t)+ d

X

i=1 C

i (t)

0

KD

i (t)+

d

X

i=1 L

i D

i

(t)][N(t)+ d

X

i=1 D

i (t)

0

KD

i (t)]

1

[KB(t)+ d

X

i=1 C

i (t)

0

KD

i (t)+

d

X

i=1 L

i D

i (t)]

0

;

8(t;K;L)2[0;T]S n

+ (S

n

) d

:

(3)

It will be called the BSRDE (A;B;C

i

;D

i

;i = 1;:::;d;Q;N;M) in the following for

convenience of indicatingthe associated coeÆcients. The coeÆcients appearing here will

be dened in Section2.

BSRDEs have atleast the following two motivations.

(1) The control-theoretic motivation. The BSRDE (1) arises from solution

of the optimalcontrolproblem

inf

u2L 2

F (0;T;R

m

)

J(u;0;x) (4)

where fort 2[0;T] and x2R n

,

J(u;t;x):=E F

t

[ Z

T

t [(Nu

s

;u

s

)+(QX t;x;u

s

;X t;x;u

s

)]ds+(MX t;x;u

T

;X t;x;u

T

)] (5)

and X t;x;u

solves the following stochastic dierentialequation

8

>

>

<

>

>

: dX

s

= (AX

s +Bu

s )ds+

d

X

i=1 (C

i X

s +D

i u

s )dw

i

; tsT;

X

t

= x:

(6)

We have the following connection: if the BSRDE (1) has a solution (K;L), the solution

for the above linear-quadratic optimal control problem (LQ problem in short) has the

following closed form(also called the feedback form):

u

s

= (N+ d

X

i=1 D

0

i KD

i )

1

[B 0

K + d

X

i=1 D

0

i KC

i +

d

X

i=1 D

0

i L

i ]X

s

(7)

(3)

V(t;x):= inf

u2L 2

F (t;T;R

m

)

J(u;t;x)=(K(t)x;x); 0tT;x2R n

: (8)

Inthis way, solutionof theabove LQproblemisreduced tosolving the BSRDE (1). The

LQ problemwith a terminalexpected constraint (EX(T)= x

T

for some xed x

T 2R

n

,

for example),is alsoreduced to solutionof a BSRDE.

(2) The nancial motivation. A mean-variance hedging problem is a one-

dimensional, nonhomogeneous, singular stochastic LQ problem. A mean-variance port-

folio selection problem is a one-dimensional, nonhomogeneous, singular stochastic LQ

problem with an expected terminal state constraint. Solution of these two classes of

mathematicalnancialproblemsis reduced tosolutionof the associatedone-dimensional

BSRDEs.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Preliminaries are done in Section

2 where the notation is listed and a solution of a BSRDE is dened. In Section 3, a

historicalreviewisgivenonBSRDEs,and theknown existenceanduniqueness resultdue

to Bismut [5] and Peng [29] is stated. Section 4 collects various properties of BSRDEs.

Section 5 summarizes our recent results on the existence and uniqueness of a global

adapted solutionofBSRDE (1). Finallyinsection6, BSRDEsare appliedtocontroland

nance.

2 Preliminaries

Notation. Throughout this paper, the following additionalnotationwillbe used:

M 0

: the transpose of any vector or matrix M;

jMj : =

q

P

ij m

2

ij

for any vector or matrix M =(m

ij );

(M

1

;M

2

) : the innerproduct of the two vectors M

1

and M

2

;

R n

: the n-dimensionalEuclidean space;

R

+

: the set of allnonnegative real numbers;

S n

: the Euclidean space of allnn symmetricmatrices;

S n

+

: the set of allnn nonnegative denitematrices;

C([0;T];H) : the Banachspace of H-valued continuous functions on[0;T],

endowed with the maximum norm fora given Hilbert space H;

L 2

F

(0;T;H) : the Banachspace of H-valued F

t

-adapted square-integrable

stochastic processes f on[0;T],endowed with the norm

(E R

T

0

jf(t)j 2

dt) 1=2

fora given Euclidean space H;

L 1

F

(0;T;H) : the Banachspace of H-valued, F

t

-adapted, essentially

bounded stochastic processes f on [0;T], endowed with the

norm esssup

t;!

jf(t)j for agiven Euclidean space H;

L 2

(;F;P;H) : the Banachspace of H-valued norm-square-integrable random

variableson the probabilityspace (;F;P) for agiven

Banach space H;

and L 1

(;F;P;C([0;T];R n

)) is the Banach space of C([0;T];R n

)-valued, essentially

(4)

with the norm esssup

!2 max

0tT

jf(t;!)j.

Wemakethe following two basic assumptions.

(A1)ThecoeÆcientsA;B;C

i

, andD

i areF

t

-progressivelymeasurableboundedmatrix-

valuedprocesses,denedon[0;T];of dimensionsnn;nm;nn;nm respectively.

M isanF

T

-measurable,nonnegative,andboundednnrandommatrix,andQandN are

F

t

-progressively measurable, bounded, and nonnegative nn and mm matrixprocesses,

respectively.

(A2) N is uniformly positive. Or

(A3) M and d

X

i=1 D

0

i D

i

are uniformly positive.

Denition 2.1. A solution of the BSRDE (1) is a pair (K;L) of processes such

that

(i) K 2L 1

F

(0;T;S n

)\L 1

(;F

T

;P;C([0;T];S n

)); L2

L 2

F

(0;T;S n

)

d

;

(ii) N(t)+ d

X

i=1 D

i (t)

0

KD

i

(t) is uniformlypositive with respect to(t;!),

(iii)K(t)=M + Z

T

t

G(s;K(s);L(s))ds Z

T

t

L(s)dw(s); 0tT:

When the pair (K;L)is asolutionof the BSRDE (1), we alsosay that itsolves the

BSRDE (1).

3 A Historical Review

First, consider the regular case, i.e., N is assumed to be uniformly positive. When the

coeÆcients A;B;C

i

;D

i

;Q;N;M are all deterministic, then L

1

= = L

d

= 0 and the

BSRDE (1)reduces tothe following nonlinear matrix ordinary dierentialequation:

8

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

<

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

:

dK = [A

0

K+KA+ d

X

i=1 C

0

i KC

i

+Q (KB + d

X

i=1 C

0

i KD

i )

(N + d

X

i=1 D

0

i KD

i )

1

(KB+ d

X

i=1 C

0

i KD

i )

0

]dt; 0t<T;

K(T) = M;

(9)

which was completely solved by Wonham [41] by applying Bellman's principle of quasi-

linearizationand a monotone convergence approach.

The attention to the randomness of the coeÆcients A;B;C;D;Q;N;M is due to

Bismut. Bismut [4, 5] initially studied the case of random coeÆcients, but he could

solve only some special simple cases at that time. Letthe integer d

0

0,and denoteby

fF 2

t

;0tTgtheP-augmentednaturalltrationgeneratedbythe (d d

0

)-dimensional

Brownianmotion(w

d0+1

;:::;w

d

). HeassumedthattherandomnessofthecoeÆcientsonly

comes from the smaller ltration fF 2

t

g, which leads to L

1

= = L

d

0

= 0. He further

assumed in the paper[4] that

C

d

0 +1

==C

d

=0; D

d

0 +1

==D

d

=0; (10)

(5)

8

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

<

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

:

dK = [A

0

K+KA+ d

0

X

i=1 C

0

i KC

i +Q

(KB + d

0

X

i=1 C

0

i KD

i )(N +

d

0

X

i=1 D

0

i KD

i )

1

(KB+ d

0

X

i=1 C

0

i KD

i )

0

]dt

+ d

X

i=d0+1 L

i dw

i

; 0t<T;

K(T) = M;

(11)

and the generator does not involve L atall. In the work [5], he assumed that

D

d0+1

==D

d

=0; (12)

underwhich the BSRDE (1) becomesthe following one

8

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

<

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

:

dK = [A

0

K+KA+ d

X

i=1 C

0

i KC

i

+Q+ d

X

i=d

0 +1

(C 0

i L

i +L

i C

i )

(KB + d

0

X

i=1 C

0

i KD

i )(N +

d

0

X

i=1 D

0

i KD

i )

1

(KB+ d

0

X

i=1 C

0

i KD

i )

0

]dt

+ d

X

i=d0+1 L

i dw

i

; 0t<T;

K(T) = M;

(13)

and the generator depends on the second unknown variable (L

d0+1

;:::;L

d )

0

in a linear

way. Moreover, hismethod was rathercomplicated.

Later, Peng [29] gavea nice treatment onthe proof of existence and uniqueness for

the BSRDE (13), by using Bellman's quasilinear principle and a method of monotone

convergence|a generalizationof Wonham'sapproach tothe random situation.

Thefollowingpropositionstatestheabove-mentionedresultonexistenceandunique-

ness of a globaladapted solutionto the BSRDE (1), due to Bismut [5]and Peng [29].

Theorem 3.1. Let the assumptions (A1) and (A2) be satised. Assume that

all the coeÆcients A;B;C

i

;D

i

;Q and N are F 2

t

-progressively measurable and that M is

F 2

T

-measurable. Then, the BSRDE (13) has a unique F 2

t

-adapted global solution (K;L)

with K(t)0;t2[0;T]:

ThegeneralcasewherethegeneratorofBSRDE(1)isallowedtocontainaquadratic

term of L,turns out tobecomea long-standingproblem. As earlyas in1978, Bismut[5]

commented on page 220 that:"Nous ne pourrons pas demontrer l'existence de solution

pour l'equation(2.49)dans lecas general." (Wecouldnot provethe existenceof solution

for equation (2.49) for the general case.) On page 238, he pointed out that the essential

diÆculty for solution of the general BSRDE (1) lies in the integrand of the martingale

term which appears in the generator in a quadratic way. Two decades later in 1998,

Peng [32] included the above probleminhis listof open problems onBSDEs.

Second, consider the singular case N = 0. Kohlmann and Zhou [20] studied the

following case:

C =0;M =I

nn

;D

i

=I

mm

; i=1;;d:

(6)

and (b) A+A 0

BB

0

. Under the above-described framework, they obtain the existence

and uniqueness of a global solution. Their method is based on an existence criterion of

Chen, Liand Zhou [6].

4 Fundamentals of BSRDEs

This sectioncollects various properties of BSRDEs, most of which turn out tobe helpful

to the proof of the existence and uniqueness of a global adapted solution. They are

consequences of the special structure of BSRDE (1)from dierent points of view.

Forconvenience of followingexposition,we introducethefollowingnotation. Dene

:[0;T]S n

R nd

!R mn

by

(;K;L)= (N + d

X

i=1 D

0

i KD

i )

1

(KB+ d

X

i=1 C

0

i KD

i +

d

X

i=1 L

i D

i )

0

(14)

and

b

A:=A+B (;K;L);

b

C

i :=C

i +D

i

(;K;L); i=1;:::;d: (15)

Consider the following SDE

8

>

>

<

>

>

: dY

s

= b

A(s)Y

s ds+

d

X

i=1 b

C

i Y

s dw

i

(s); t sT;

Y

t

= I

nn :

(16)

In view of Gal'chuk [11], this equation has a unique strong solution (denoted by (;t))

when L2(L 2

F

(0;T;S n

)) d

.

4.1 Regularity

Theorem 4.1. Let (K;L) solve the BSRDE (1). Then,

(;K;L)(;t)2L 2

F

(t;T;R mn

);

:= max

tsT

j(s;t)j2L 2

(;F;P): (17)

Consider the optimalcontrolproblem

inf

u2L 2

F (0;T;R

m

)

J(u;0;x) (18)

where fort 2[0;T] and x2R n

,

J(u;t;x):=E Ft

[ Z

T

t [(Nu

s

;u

s

)+(QX t;x;u

s

;X t;x;u

s

)]ds+(MX t;x;u

T

;X t;x;u

T

)] (19)

and X t;x;u

solves the SDE

8

>

>

<

>

>

: dX

s

= (AX

s +Bu

s )ds+

d

X

i=1 (C

i X

s +D

i u

s )dw

i

; tsT;

X

t

= x:

(20)

(7)

can show that the assumption (A2) or (A3) implies the existence and uniqueness of the

optimalcontrol b

u2L 2

F

(0;T;R m

). From the optimality conditions, wehave

b

u= (;K;L)(;t)x; X t;x;bu

=(;t)x:

Then, Theorem 4.1follows. The reader is referred toSubsection 6.1for more details.

4.2 The Feynman-Kac Representation

Theorem 4.2. Let (K;L) solve the BSRDE (1). Then,

(K(t)x;x)=V(t;x):= inf

u2L 2

F (t;T;R

m

)

J(u;t;x);8t2[0;T]; x2R n

: (21)

In viewof Theorem 4.1, the proof is straightforward. This theorem plays a crucial

roleinthe proof ofuniqueness: itimmediatelygivesthe uniqueness of K asthe rst part

of the solution. It alsoplays animportant role inthe proof of the closed property of the

solutions(See Theorem 4.9).

4.3 Nonnegativity

Theorem 4.3. If (K;L) solves the BSRDE (1), then K(t)0; 0t T.

Noticing the nonnegativity of M;Q;N, we haveK(t)0from Theorem 4.2.

4.4 Monotonicity

FromTheorem4.2,weimmediatelyobtainthefollowingmonotonepropertyofthesolution

tothe BSRDE (1).

Theorem4.4. Let(K;L)and( f

K;

e

L )bethesolutionstotheBSRDEs(A;B;C

i

;D

i

;i=

1;;d;Q;N;M) and (A;B;C

i

;D

i

;i=1;;d;

e

Q;

f

N;

f

M), respectively. If

e

QQ0;

f

N N >0;

f

M M 0;

then f

K K;a:s:a:e::

4.5 Minimality

Theorem 4.5. Let e

2L 1

F

(0;T;R mn

) and let ( f

K;

e

L ) be the solution of the following

linear BSDE

8

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

<

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

:

dK = [

e

A 0

K +K e

A+ d

X

i=1 e

C 0

i K

e

C

i

+Q+ d

X

i=1 (

e

C 0

i L

i +L

i e

C

i )

+ e

N e

]dt+ d

X

i=1 L

i dw

i

; 0t <T;

K(T) = M

(22)

(8)

e

A:=A+B e

; e

C

i :=C

i +D

i e

; I =1;:::;d: (23)

If (K;L) is the solution to the BSRDE (1), then K f

K;a:s:a:e::

Note that adeterministic version of Theorem4.5 was given by Wonham [41].

For the one-dimensional case, inview of the minimalityof the generator:

G(t;K;L)[ e

A 0

K+K e

A+ d

X

i=1 e

C 0

i K

e

C

i

+Q+ d

X

i=1 (

e

C 0

i L

i +L

i e

C

i )+

e

N e

]; 8 e

2R mn

;

this theorem is an immediate consequence of the existing comparison theory for one-

dimensional BSDEs. For the general multi-dimensional case, it is an immediate conse-

quence of the above monotone theorem 4.4for the BSRDE (A;0;C;0;Q;N;M).

4.6 A priori estimates and the BMO-property.

We have the following a prioriestimate of boundedness.

Theorem 4.6. Let (K;L) solve the BSRDE (A;B;C

i

;D

i

;i = 1;:::;d;Q;N;M):

Then, there is a deterministic positive constant"

0

such thatthe followingestimates hold:

0K(t)"

0 I

nn

; E Ft

Z

T

t jLj

2

ds

!

p

"

0

; 8p1: (24)

Here "

0

depends on the uniform upper bound of all the coeÆcients.

Proof of Theorem 4.6. From Theorem 4.3, we have K 0. Note that (K;L)

satisesthe BSRDE:

8

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

<

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

:

dK =

A 0

K+KA+ d

X

i=1 C

0

i KC

i

+Q+ d

X

i=1 (C

0

i L

i +L

i C

i )

+F(t;K;L)

dt+ d

X

i=1 L

i dw

i

; 0t<T;

K(T) = M:

(25)

UsingIt^o's formula, we get

8

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

<

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

>

:

djKj 2

=

4tr

K 2

A

+ d

X

i=1

2tr (KC 0

i KC

i

)+2tr(KQ)

+ d

X

i=1

4tr (KL

i C

i

)+2tr [KF(t;K;L)] jLj 2

dt

+ d

X

i=1

2tr (KL

i ) dw

i

; 0t<T;

jKj 2

(T) = jMj 2

:

(26)

We observethat since

F(t;K;L)0; K 0;

(9)

2tr [KF(t;K;L)]=2tr h

K 1

2

F(t;K;L)K 1

2 i

0: (27)

Hence,

jKj 2

(t)+ Z

T

t jLj

2

ds jMj 2

+ Z

T

t

4tr

K 2

A

+ d

X

i=1

2tr (KC 0

i KC

i )

+2tr(KQ)+ d

X

i=1

4tr (KL

i C

i )

ds

Z

T

t d

X

i=1

2tr (KL

i ) dw

i

; 0t <T:

(28)

Usingthe elementaryinequality

2aba 2

+b 2

and taking the expectation onboth sides with respect toF

r

for rt, we obtain that

E F

r

jKj 2

(t)+ 1

2 E

F

r Z

T

t jLj

2

ds"

1 +"

1 Z

T

t E

F

r

jKj 2

(s)ds; 0rt<T: (29)

Using Gronwall's inequality, we derive from the last inequality the rst one of the esti-

mates (24). In return, we derivefrom the second lastinequality that

Z

T

t jLj

2

ds"

2 +"

2 Z

T

t

jLjds Z

T

t d

X

i=1

2tr (KL

i ) dw

i

: (30)

Therefore,

E F

t Z

T

t jLj

2

ds

!

p

3 p

"

"

p

2 +"

p

2 E

F

t Z

T

t

jLjds

!

p

+E F

t

Z

T

t d

X

i=1

2trKL

i dw

i

p

#

: (31)

We have fromthe Burkholder-Davis-Gundy inequality the following

E Ft

Z

T

t d

X

i=1

2tr (KL

i ) dw

i

p

2 p

E Ft

Z

T

t jKj

2

jLj 2

ds

p=2

;

while fromthe Cauchy-Schwarz inequality, we have

E Ft

Z

T

t

jLjds

!

p

T p=2

E Ft

Z

T

t jLj

2

ds

!

p=2

:

Finally,we get

E Ft

Z

T

t jLj

2

ds

!

p

3 p

"

p

2 +[3

p

T p=2

"

p

2 +6

p

n p=2

"

p

0 ]E

Ft Z

T

t jLj

2

ds

!

p=2

; (32)

which implies the lastestimateof the lemma.

(10)

Theorem4.7. Let(K;L)solvetheBSRDE (1). Then,

0

L(s)dw(s)isaBMO(P)

martingale.

Proof of Theorem 4.7 From the inequality (30), we get that for any stopping

time T,

Z

T

jLj

2

ds"

5 +"

5 Z

T

jLjds Z

T

d

X

i=1

2tr (KL

i ) dw

i

: (33)

From this it follows that

E F

Z

T

jL(s)j 2

ds":

Then, Theorem 4.7follows.

Notethatasimplecase (where thegeneratorof BSRDE(1)dependsonthe martin-

gale term L in a linear way) of Theorem 4.7 has been obtained by Bismut [5]by aquite

dierent argument. This theorem plays animportantrole in solving a generalnonhomo-

geneous stochastic LQproblemand in solvinga generalmean-variance hedgingproblem.

The readeris referred toSection 6 fordetails.

We have the following a priori estimate of the uniform positivity for the rst part

K of the solution.

Theorem4.8. Lettheassumption(A3)besatised,and(K;L)solvetheBSRDE(1).

Then, there isa deterministic positive constant "

0

such that

K(t)"

0 I

nn

: (34)

The proof is an immediate consequence of a combination of Theorem 4.2 and the

following estimate.

Lemma 4.1. Let the assumption (A3) be satised. Let X t;x;u

solve the SDE (20).

Then, there is a deterministicpositiveconstant"

0

, which is independent of the control u,

such that

jxj 2

+ 1

2 E

F

t Z

T

t ju

s j

2

dsexp("

0

(T t))E F

t

jX t;x;u

T j

2

; 8u2L 2

F

(t;T;R m

): (35)

4.7 Closedness of solution.

Theorem 4.9. Assume that 8 0 the coeÆcients A

;B

;C

i

;D

i

;Q

; and N

are

F

t

-progressively measurable matrix-valued processes, dened on [0;T]; of dimensions

nn;nm;nn;nm;nn; and mm; respectively. Assume that M

is an F

T -

measurableandnonnegativennrandom matrix. Assume thatQ

isa:s:a:e: nonnegative.

Assumethattherearetwodeterministicpositiveconstants"

1 and"

2

whichareindependent

of the parameter , such that

jA

(t)j;jB

(t)j;jC

i

(t)j;jD

i

(t)j;jQ

(t)j;jN

(t)j;jM

j"

1

and

N

"

2 I

mm :

(11)

Assume that as ! 0, A

(t);B

(t);C

i (t);D

i (t);Q

(t), and N

(t) converge uniformly

in (t;!)to A 0

(t);B 0

(t);C 0

i (t);D

0

i (t);Q

0

(t) andN 0

(t), respectively. Assume thatM

uni-

formly converges to M 0

as ! 0. Assume that 8 >0 the BSRDE (A

;B

;C

i

;D

i

;i=

1;:::;d;Q

;N

;M

) has a unique solution (K

;L

) with K

(t) 0;t 2 [0;T]: Then,

there isa pair of processes (K;L) with

K 2L 1

F

(0;T;S n

+ )\L

1

(;F

T

;P;C([0;T];S n

+

)); L2L 2

F

(0;T;S n

);

such that

lim

!0 K

=K strongly in L 1

F

(0;T;S n

+ )\L

1

(;F

T

;P;C([0;T];S n

+ ));

lim

!0 L

=L strongly in L 2

F

(0;T;S n

);

(36)

and such that (K;L) solves the BSRDE (A 0

;B 0

;C 0

;D 0

;Q 0

;N 0

;M 0

).

If the aboveassumption of uniform convergenceof (A

;C

;Q

;M

) isreplacedwith

the followingone:

lim

!0

esssup

!2 Z

T

0 (jA

A 0

j+jC

C 0

j 2

+jQ

Q 0

j)ds+jM

M 0

j !0: (37)

then the above assertions stillhold.

The proof is referred toKohlmann and Tang [19].

Remark2.1. Whentheassumptionofuniformpositivityonthecontrolweightma-

trixN is relaxed to nonnegativity, Theorem 4.9 stillholds withthe additional assumption

that there is a deterministic positive constant "

3

such that

d

X

i=1 (D

i )

0

D

i "

3 I

mm

; M

"

3 I

nn :

4.8 Transformation of BSRDEs

Let solve the dierentialequation:

8

<

: d

dt

(t) = A(t)(t); t2(0;T];

(0) = I

nn :

Consider the followingtransformation

f

K :=

0

K;

e

L:=

0

L (38)

of the BSRDE (1).

Using It^o's formula, we verify that the BSRDE (A;B;C

i

;D

i

;i =1;:::;d;Q;N;M)

becomesthenewBSRDE(0;

e

B;

e

C

i

; f

D

i

;i=1;;d;

e

Q ;N;

f

M),whichissatisedby( f

K;

e

L).

Here,

e

B :=

1

B;

e

C :=

1

C;

f

D:=

1

D

e

Q:=

0

Q;

f

M :=(T) 0

M(T):

(39)

(12)

Since A isbounded, the resultingtransformation isalsobouned.

It isinterestingtodiscussthemore generaltransformation whichsolvesthe SDE:

8

>

>

<

>

>

:

d (t) = A(t) (t)dt+ d

X

i=1 C

i

(t) (t)dw

i

(t); t2(0;T];

(0) = I

nn :

(40)

This transformation can anneal both A and C in the BSRDE (1). Note that it is not

necessarilybounded thoughA and C=(C

1

;:::;C

d

)are assumed to be bounded.

4.9 The Markov case : a PDE characterization

Sinceoptimal controls or optimalhedging/investing strategies are characterized interms

of the solutions of associated BSRDEs, it is important to characterize the solutions of

BSRDEs. When the coeÆcientsof BSRDEs are Markovian functions of anIt^o's process,

itis naturaltoconnect the solution ofa BSRDE with asystem of parabolicPDEs. Note

thatingeneralthe associated systemof parabolicPDEs contains aquadraticterm of the

gradient. We are not going into the details due to the limitation of space. The reader

is referred to among others, Peng [30, 31], Pardoux and Peng [27], and Pardoux and

Tang [28] for this direction.

5 Recent Advances on Existence and Uniqueness.

Recently, Kohlmann and Tang [17] extended Theorem 3.1to the singular case under the

assumption (A3).

Theorem5.1. Lettheassumption(A3)be satised. Then, Theorem3:1stillholds

even if N =0. Moreover, K(t) is uniformly positive.

KohlmannandTang[18]solvedtheonedimensionalcaseoftheaboveBismut-Peng's

problem.

Theorem 5.2. Let the assumptions (A1) and (A2) be satised, and n = 1:

Then, BSRDE (1) has a unique solution. Further, assume that (A3) is satised. Then,

BSRDE (1) still has a unique solution (K;L) even if N = 0, and moreover, K(t) is

uniformly positive.

This theoremmeetsthe needsforBSRDEs tobeappliedtonance. Anapproxima-

tiontechnique isused,whichismotivatedby theworksof Kobylansky [16],and Lepeltier

and San Martin [22, 23].

Kohlmann and Tang [19] proved the global existence and uniqueness result for

BSRDE(1)forsomemulti-dimensionalcases: They arespecial buttypical, forthegener-

atorcontainsaquadratictermonL. Theresultsarestatedbythefollowingtwotheorems.

Theorem 5.3. (the singular case) Let the assumptions (A1) and (A2) be satis-

ed, and d =1. Assume that there isa deterministic positive constant " such that

M "I

nn

(41)

(13)

D 0

D(t)"I

mm

: (42)

Then, the BSRDE:

8

>

>

>

<

>

>

>

:

dK = [A

0

K+KA+C 0

KC+Q+C 0

L+LC

(KB+C 0

KD+LD)(D 0

KD) 1

(KB+C 0

KD+LD) 0

]dt+Ldw;

0t<T;

K(T) = M:

(43)

has a unique solution (K;L) with K(t;!) beinguniformly positive w.r.t. (t;!):

The main idea for the proof of Theorem 5.3 isto dothe inverse transformation:

f

K :=K 1

; (44)

which turnsout tosatisfy aRiccati equationwhose generatordepends onthe martingale

term ina linear way.

First, since D isinversable, we can rewritethe BSRDE (43) as

8

>

<

>

:

dK = [

e

A 0

K K

e

A+Q K e

BK 1

e

B 0

K LK

1

L

+K e

BK 1

L+LK 1

e

B 0

K]dt+Ldw;

K(T) = M;

(45)

where

e

A := A+BD 1

C;

e

B := BD 1

:

Notethatwehavethefollowingrulefortherstandthe seconddierentialsoftheinverse

of apositivematrix as a matrix-valued function:

d

K 1

= K

1

(dK)K 1

; d 2

K 1

=2K 1

(dK)K 1

(dK)K 1

: (46)

UsingIt^o's formula, we can write the equation for the inverse f

K of K:

(

d f

K = [

f

K e

A 0

+ e

A f

K f

KQ f

K+ e

B f

K e

B 0

+ e

B e

L+ e

L e

B 0

]dt+ e

Ldw;

f

K(T) = M 1

;

(47)

where

e

L:= K 1

LK 1

:

FromTheorem3.1,the aboveBSRDE

e

A;Q 1=2

; e

B;0;0;I

mm

;M 1

has aunique solution

( f

K;

e

L) with f

K 0; which implies that f

K 1

(t) is uniformly positive in (t;!). More-

over, from the fact that f

K(T) = M 1

"

1

1 I

nn

, we derive that f

K is uniformly posi-

tive. This shows that f

K 1

(t) isuniformlybounded. Therefore ( f

K 1

; f

K 1

e

L f

K 1

) solves

BSRDE (43).

The uniqueness results from the Feynman-Kac representation result Theorem 4.2.

Infact,assumethat( c

K;

b

L)alsosolvesthe BSRDE(43). Then,fromTheorem 4.2,wesee

that

(K(t)x;x)=V(t;x)=( c

K(t)x;x); a:s:; 8(t;x)2[0;T]R n

:

(14)

So, we have K(t)= c

K(t) almost surely for 8(t;x)2[0;T]R :Set

ÆK :=K c

K; ÆL

i :=L

i b

L

i

; ÆG:=G(t;K;L) G(t;

c

K; b

L ):

Then, wehave ÆK =0. Notethat (ÆK;ÆL) satisesthe following BSDE:

8

>

>

<

>

>

:

dÆK(t) = ÆGdt+ d

X

i=1 ÆL

i (t)dw

i

(t); 0t <T;

ÆK(T) = 0:

(48)

From this, proceedingidenticallyas inthe proof of Theorem 4.6, wehave

E Z

T

t jÆLj

2

(s)dsEjÆK(T)j 2

+"esssup

s;!

jÆK(s)jE Z

T

t

(1+jLj 2

+j b

L j 2

)ds=0: (49)

Hence, ÆL=L b

L=0.

Theorem5.4. (theregularcase) Lettheassumptions(A1)and(A2)besatised.

Further assume that d=1;B =C =0, and D and N satisfy the following

lim

h!0+

esssup

!2

max

t

1

;t

2 2[0;T];jt

1 t

2 jh

jD(t

1

) D(t

2

)j = 0;

lim

h!0+

esssup

!2

max

t

1

;t

2 2[0;T];jt

1 t

2 jh

jN(t

1

) N(t

2

)j = 0:

(50)

Then, the BSRDE:

8

>

<

>

:

dK = [A

0

K+KA+Q LD(N +D 0

KD) 1

D 0

L]dt+Ldw;

0t <T;

K(T) = M:

(51)

has a unique solution (K;L) with K(t)0;8t2[0;T]:

For the regular case, the situation is alittle complex: we easilysee that the above

inversetransformationonthe rstunknown variablecannot eliminatethe quadraticterm

ofthesecondunknown variable. However, wecanstillsolvesomeclassesofBSRDEswith

thehelpofdoingsomeappropriatetransformation. Thewholeproofisdividedintoseveral

propositions.

Proposition 5.1. Assume that QA 0

(D 1

) 0

ND 1

+(D 1

) 0

ND 1

A;m=n; and

D and N are positive constantmatrices. Then, Theorem 5:4 holds.

Proof of Proposition 5.1. Write

c

N :=(D 1

) 0

ND 1

: (52)

Then, the BSRDE (51) reads

8

>

<

>

:

dK = [A

0

K+KA+Q L(

c

N +K) 1

L]dt+Ldw;

0t <T;

K(T) = M:

(53)

(15)

The equation for K :=N+K is

8

>

<

>

: d

c

K = [A

0

c

K + c

KA+Q A 0

c

N c

NA b

L c

K 1

b

L]dt+ b

Ldw;

0t<T;

c

K(T) = c

N +M:

(54)

Notethat c

N+M isuniformlypositive. FromTheorem5.3,itfollowsthattheBSRDE(54)

has a solution( c

K;

b

L). Therefore ( c

K c

N; b

L)solvesBSRDE (51).

Proposition 5.2. Assume thatA =0 andD andN areconstant matrices. Then,

Theorem 5:4 holds.

Proof of Proposition 5.2. First assume m=n. Consider the followingapprox-

imatingBSRDEs:

(

dK = [Q LD

(N +D 0

KD

)

1

D 0

L]dt+Ldw;

K(T) = M

(55)

where

D

:=D+ I

mm

>0;>0:

FromProposition5.1,weseethattheBSRDE(55)hasasolution(K

;L

)forevery>0.

From Theorem 4.9, it follows that K

uniformlyconverges to some K 2 L 1

F

(0;T;S n

+ )\

L 1

(;F

T

;P;C([0;T];S n

+

))andL

stronglyconvergestosomeL2L 2

F

(0;T;S n

),andthat

(K;L)solvesBSRDE (51) when A=0.

Considerthecasen >m. Thenconsiderthennmatrices f

Dwhoserstmcolumns

are D and whose last (n m) columns are zero column vectors, and f

N whichis dened

as

f

N :=

R 0

0 I

!

:

The BSRDE (51) when A=0is rewritten as

(

dK = [Q L

f

D(

f

N + f

D 0

K f

D) 1

f

D 0

L]dt+Ldw;

K(T) = M

From the preceding result, we obtainthe desiredexistence result.

Consider thecase n<m. Then,thereisamm orthogonaltransformationmatrix

T such that

D=[ c

D;0]T;

c

D2R nn

and is non-singular.

Write

f

N :=(T 1

) 0

NT 1

:=

c

N

11 c

N

12

c

N 0

12 c

N

22

!

>0:

Then, c

N

11

>0:The BSRDE (51) whenA =0 isrewritten as

(

dK = [Q L

c

D(

f

N

11 +

c

D 0

K c

D) 1

c

D 0

L]dt+Ldw;

K(T) = M

From the preceding result, we obtainthe desiredexistence result.

(16)

F

t

-adapted bounded matrix processes. Then, Theorem 5:4 holds.

Proof of Proposition 5.3. Since Dand N are piece-wisely constantF

t

-adapted

bounded matrix processes, there is a nitepartion:

0=:t

0

<t

1

<<t

J :=T

suchthatoneachinterval[t

i

;t

i+1

][0;T],DandN areconstantF

ti

-measurablebounded

random matrices. Then, we can solve the BSRDE one interval by one, in an inductive

and backward way.

Proposition 5.4. Assume that A=0:Then, Theorem5:4 holds.

Proof of Proposition 5.4. For an arbitrary positive integer k, consider the

2 k

-partionof the time interval. Dene

D k

(t)=D

i 1

2 k

T

; 8t2

i 1

2 k

T; i

2 k

T

;i=1;2;:::;2 k

;

and

N k

(t)=N

i 1

2 k

T

; 8t2

i 1

2 k

T; i

2 k

T

;i=1;2;:::;2 k

:

For each k, D k

and N k

are are piece-wisely constant, F

t

-adapted, bounded matrix pro-

cesses. Further, since the trajectories of D and N are uniformly continuous in !, D k

(t)

and N k

(t)converge respectively toD and N, uniformlyin(t;!): Thatis, we have

lim

k!1 esssup

!2 max

t2[0;T]

jD k

(t) D(t)j=0; lim

k!1

esssup

!2 max

t2[0;T]

jN k

(t) N(t)j=0:

FromProposition5.3,wesee thattheBSRDE(0;0;0;D k

;Q;N k

;M)hasaglobalsolution

(K k

;L k

), and then fromTheorem 4.9, it follows that Theorem 5.4holds.

Proof of Theorem 5.4. From Proposition 5.4, we see that the

BSRDE (0;0;0;

f

D;

e

Q;N;

f

M) has a global adapted solution( f

K;

e

L ), and thus the pair

((

0

) 1

f

K 1

;( 0

) 1

e

L 1

)

solves the originalBSRDE (A;0;0;D;Q;N;M). Here, f

D;

e

Q; and f

M are dened by (39).

The uniqueness can be proved in the same way as inthe proof of Theorem 5.3.

6 Applications to Control and Finance

6.1 Control-theoretic application

Assume that

2L 2

(;F

T

;P;R n

); q;f;g

i 2L

2

F

(0;T;R n

): (56)

Consider the following optimalcontrolproblem (denoted by P

0 ):

min

u2L 2

F (0;T;R

m

)

J(u;0;x) (57)

(17)

J(u;t;x)= E F

t

(M(X t;x;u

T

);X t;x;u

T

)

+E Ft

Z

T

t

[(Q(X t;x;u

q);X t;x;u

q)+(Nu;u)]ds

(58)

and X t;x;u

solving the followinglinear SDE

8

>

>

<

>

>

: dX

s

= (AX

s +Bu

s

+f(s))ds+ d

X

i=1 (C

i X

s +D

i u

s +g

i

(s))dw

i

; t<sT;

X

t

= x; u2L 2

F

(t;T;R m

):

(59)

The value function V is dened as

V(t;x):= min

u2L 2

F (t;T;R

m

)

J(u;t;x); (t;x)2[0;T]R n

: (60)

Theorem 6.1 Let the two assumptions (A1) and (A2), or (A1) and (A3) be

satised. Let (K;L) solve the BSRDE (1). Then, the BSDE

8

>

>

<

>

>

:

d (t) = [ b

A 0

+ d

X

i=1 b

C 0

i (

i Kg

i

) Kf d

X

i=1 L

i g

i

+Qq]dt+ d

X

i=1

i dw

i

;

(T) = M

(61)

where b

A and b

C

i

are dened by (15),has a unique F

t

-adapted solution ( ;) with

2L 2

F

(0;T;R n

)\L 2

(;F

T

;P;C([0;T];R n

)); 2

L 2

F

(0;T;R n

)

d

: (62)

Moreover, theoptimalcontrol b

u forthenon-homogeneousstochasticLQ problemP

0 exists

uniquely and has the followingfeedback law

b

u = (N+ d

X

i=1 D

0

i KD

i )

1

[(B 0

K+ d

X

i=1 D

0

i KC

i +

d

X

i=1 D

0

i L

i )

c

X

B 0

+ d

X

i=1 D

0

i (Kg

i

i )]

(63)

where c

X :=X 0;x;bu

:

Remark 6.1. Notethat b

A and b

C

i

dependon Lin general, andthus theymightnot

beuniformlybounded. Inthis case,wehavenoavailable|totheauthors'bestknowledge|

theoremtoguaranteethe existence andtheuniquenessof aglobaladaptedsolution,though

the BSDE (61) is linear.

Proof of Theorem 6.1. Our assumptions guarantee that there is a unique

optimalcontrol b

u2L 2

F

(0;T;R m

): The optimality condition implies

B 0

e

p+ X

i=1 D

0

i e

q

i +N

b

u=0

(18)

where (p;q) solvesthe BSDE (calledthe adjoint equation)

8

>

>

<

>

>

: d

e

p(t) = [A 0

e

p(t)+ d

X

i=1 C

0

i e

q

i

(t)+Q(

c

X

t

q(t))]dt+ d

X

i=1 e

q

i (t)dw

i (t);

e

p(T) = M( c

X

T )

(64)

with

e

p2L 2

F

(0;T;R n

)\L 2

(;F

T

;P;C([0;T];R n

));

e

q2

L 2

F

(0;T;R n

)

d

: (65)

ViaIt^o's formula, we check out that the pair ( ;) dened by the following

(t):=K(t) c

X

t e

p(t);

i

(t):=K(t)[C

i c

X

t +D

i b

u

t +g

i

(t)]+L

i c

X

t e

q

i (t)

solves the BSDE (61). It is obvious that 2L 2

F

(0;T;R n

)\L 2

(;F

T

;P;C([0;T];R n

)).

Since R

0

L(s)dw(s) is a BMO(P)-martingale, it follows from Theorem 1.1 (i) and (iii) of

Ba~nuelos and Bennett [1] that R

T

0 L

i (s)

c

X

s dw

i

(s) is square-integrable. Therefore, L

i c

X 2

L 2

F

(0;T;R n

), and

i 2L

2

F

(0;T;R n

):

It is standard to get the explicit formula (63) of b

u from the optimality condition.

The proof iscomplete.

The following can be veried by a pure completion of squares.

Theorem 6.2 Suppose thatthetwo assumptions (A1)and(A2), or (A1)and(A3)

are satised. Let (K;L) solve BSRDE (1). Then, the value function V(t;x);(t;x) 2

[0;T]R n

has the following explicit formula

V(t;x)=(K(t)x;x) 2( (t);x)+V 0

(t); (t;x)2[0;T]R n

(66)

with

V 0

(t):= E F

t

(M;)+E F

t Z

T

t

(Qq;q)ds 2E F

t Z

T

t

( ;f)ds

+E F

t Z

T

t d

X

i=1 [(Kg

i

;g

i

) 2(

i g

i )]ds

E Ft

Z

T

t

((N+ d

X

i=1 D

0

i KD

i )u

0

;u 0

)ds

(67)

and

u 0

:=(N + d

X

i=1 D

0

i KD

i )

1

[B 0

+ d

X

i=1 D

0

i (

i Kg

i

)]; tsT: (68)

6.2 Financial application.

As anapplication of the above results, the mean-variance hedgingproblem withrandom

marketconditions is considered. The mean-variancehedging problemwas initiallyintro-

ducedbyFollmerandSondermann[9],andlater widelystudiedby DuÆeandRichardson

(19)

Pham, Rheinlander and Schweizer [34], Gourieroux, Laurent and Pham [12], and Lau-

rent and Pham [21]. All of these works are based on a projection argument. Recently,

KohlmannandZhou[20]usedanaturalLQtheoryapproachtosolvethecaseofdetermin-

istic market conditions. Kohlmann and Tang [17] used a natural LQtheory approach to

solvethecase ofstochasticmarketconditions,but themarketconditionsare onlyallowed

toinvolvea smallerltrationfF 2

t

g. Kohlmannand Tang [18] completelysolved the case

of random market conditions by using Theorems 6.1 and 6.2, and the optimal hedging

portfolioand the variance-optimalmartingale measure are characterized by the solution

of the associated BSRDE.

Considerthenancialmarketinwhichtherearem+1primitiveassets: onenonrisky

asset (the bond) of price process

S

0

(t)=exp( Z

t

0

r(s)ds); 0tT; (69)

and m risky assets (the stocks)

dS(t)=diag(S(t))((t)dt+(t)dw(t)); 0tT: (70)

Here w =(w

1

;:::;w

d )

0

is a d-dimensional standard Brownian motion dened on a com-

pleteprobabilityspace(;F;P),andfF

t

;0tTgistheP-augmentationofthenatu-

ralltrationgeneratedbythed-dimensionalBrownianmotionw. Assumethattheinstan-

taneousinterestrater,them-dimensionalappreciationvectorprocessandthevolatility

md matrix process are progressively measurable with respect to fF

t

;0 t Tg.

For simplicity of exposing the main ideas, assume that they are uniformly bounded and

there exists a positive constant" such that

0

(t)"I

mm

; 0tT;a:s: (71)

The risk premiumprocess is given by

(t)= 0

( 0

) 1

e

(t); 0t T (72)

where e

m

=(1;:::;1) 0

2R m

; and e

:= re

m :

Foranyx2Rand 2L 2

F

(0;T;R m

),denetheself-nanced wealthprocessX with

initialcapitalx and with quantity invested inthe risky asset S by

(

dX

t

= [rX

t +(

e

;)]dt+ 0

dw; 0<t T;

X

0

= x; 2L 2

F

(0;T;R m

):

(73)

Given a random variable 2 L 2

(;F

T

;P), consider the quadratic optimal control

problem:

Problem P

0;x

() min

2L 2

F (0;T;R

m

) EjX

0;x;

T

j 2

(74)

whereX 0;x;

isthe solutiontothe wealth equation(73). The associated value functionis

denotedbyV(t;x);(t;x)2[0;T]R : TheminimumpointofV(t;x)overx2R forgiven

time t is dened to bethe approximate price for the contingent claim at time t.

(20)

0;x

nance. It is aone-dimensional singular stochastic LQproblem P

0 .

Denote by

i

the i-th column of the volatility matrix . The associated Riccati

equationis a non-linear singularBSDE:

dK = [2rK (e

0

K+ P

d

i=1 L

i

0

i

)(K 0

) 1

(K e

+ P

d

i=1 L

i

i )]dt+

P

d

i=1 L

i dw

i

= [(2r jj 2

)K 2(;L) K 1

L 0

0

( 0

) 1

L]dt+(L; dw); 0t<T

K(T)=1:

(75)

Let( ;) is the F

t

-adapted solution of the BSDE

d = f[r jj 2

(;K 1

L)]

P

d

i=1 [

i +K

1

0

i (

0

) 1

L]

i gdt+

P

d

i=1

i dw

i

;

= f[r jj 2

(;K 1

L)] (+K 1

0

( 0

) 1

L;)gdt+(; dw);

(T)=

(76)

Theorem 6.1 providesanexplicit formulafor the optimalhedging portfolio:

= (

d

X

i=1

i K

0

i )

1

[(e

K+

d

X

i=1

i L

i )X

e d

X

i=1

i

i ]

= (K

0

) 1

[(

e

K+L)X e

]

= (

0

) 1

[(

e

+K 1

L)X e

K 1

K 1

]

(77)

where(K;L) isthe F

t

-adapted solution tothe Riccati equation(75). The value function

V isalso given by

V(t;x)=K(t)x 2

2 (t)x+E Ft

2

E Ft

Z

T

t (

e

+)

0

(K 0

)(e

+)ds (78)

where:=(

1

;:::;

n )

0

:So, theapproximatepricep(t)attimetforthe contingentclaim

is given by

p(t)=K 1

(t) (t): (79)

The abovesolutionneednot introducetheadditionalconcepts oftheso-calledhedg-

ing numeraire and variance-optimal martingale measure, and therefore is simpler than

that ofGourierouxet al[12], and Laurentand Pham [21]. To beconnected tothe latter,

the optimalhedging portfolio(77) is rewritten as

= (

0

) 1

[(

e

+

e

L )(X e

)

e

]: (80)

Here,

e

L:=LK 1

; e

:= K 1

; e

:=K 1

L K 2

: (81)

and the pair ( e

; e

) solves the BSDE:

(

d e

= fr e

+( e

; e

)gdt+( e

; dw); 0t<T;

e

(T) =

(82)

(21)

e

:= [I

0

( 0

) 1

]LK 1

: (83)

Theprocess e

isjusttheapproximatepriceprocess,andtheBSDE(82)istheapproximate

pricing equation.

In view of Theorem 6.1, it follows from Theorem 1.1 (i) and (iii) of Ba~nuelos and

Bennett [1]that

e

2L 2

F

(0;T;R n

)\L 2

(;F

T

;P;C([0;T];R ));

e

2L 2

F

(0;T;R d

): (84)

Note that the optimalhedging portfolio(77) consists of the followingtwo parts:

1

:= (

0

) 1

( e

+

e

L)X (85)

and

0

:=( 0

) 1

[(

e

+

e

L) e

+ e

]; (86)

and satises

=

1

+ 0

: (87)

Therst part 1

istheoptimalsolutionof thehomogeneousmean-variancehedgingprob-

lemP

0;x

(0)(thatisthecase of=0forthe problemP

0;x

()). Thecorrespondingoptimal

wealth process X 0;1;

1

is the solution tothe followingoptimal closed system

(

dX

t

= X

t

[(r jj 2

(;

e

L ))dt (+ 0

( 0

) 1

e

L; dw)]; 0<t T;

X

0

= 1;

(88)

andisjustthehedgingnumeraire. So,thehedgingnumeraireisjustthestate(wealth)tran-

sitionprocess of the optimalclosedsystem (88) fromtime 0,oritis justthe fundamental

solution of the optimalclosed system (88).

To understand the quantity e

, consider the BSDEsatised by (K ;L)

(

dK = f(2r jj 2

)K+2(;L)+K 1

L 0

[I

0

( 0

) 1

]Lgdt+(L; dw);

K (T) = 1

(89)

with K:=K 1

and L := LK 2

. It is the BSRDE for the following singular stochastic

LQproblem (denoted by P 0

0;x ):

Problem P 0

0;x

min

2L 2

F (0;T;R

d

) EjX

0;x;

T j

2

(90)

where X 0;x;

is the solution tothe followingstochastic dierentialequation

(

dX

t

= X

t

[ rdt (; dw)]+([I 0

( 0

) 1

];dw); 0t T;

X

0

= x; 2L 2

F

(0;T;R d

):

(91)

(22)

Its optimalcontrol has the followingfeedback form

b

= K

1

LX =LK 1

X: (92)

TheproblemP 0

0;1

isjustthe so-calleddualproblemof theproblemP

0;1

(0)in[12,21], and

sothe variance-optimalmartingalemeasure is P

dened as

dP

:=exp

Z

T

0 (

e

;dW) 1

2 Z

T

0 j

e

j 2

dt

dP: (93)

P

is anequivalent martingalemeasure.

Note that e

has the followingexplicit formula:

e

(t)=E Ft

exp( Z

T

t

r(s)ds); 0tT: (94)

Here, thenotationE Ft

stands forthe expectationoperatorconditioningonthe -algebra

F

t

with respect to the probability P

. The discounted e

is just the integrand of the

stochastic-integral-representation of the P

-martingale fE Ft

exp( R

T

0

r(s)ds);0 t

Tg(w.r.t. the P

-martingaleW + R

0 e

dt).

As inKohlmann and Zhou[20], again, the formula(80) has aninteresting interpre-

tationintermsof mathematicalnance. The optimalhedgingportfolio in(80)consists

of the two components: (a) ( 0

) 1

~

|it may be interpreted as the perfect hedging

portfoliofor the contingent claim with the risk premiumprocess

~

(that is, under the

variance-optimal martingale measure), (b) ( 0

) 1

(~+

~

L )(

~

X)|it is a generalized

Merton-type portfolio for a terminal utility function c(x) = x 2

(see Merton [24]), which

invests the capital (

~

X) leftover after fulllingthe obligationfromthe perfect hedge

underthe variance-optimalmartingale measure.

Acknowledgement The second author would like to thank the hospitality of

DepartmentofMathematicsand Statistics, andthe Center of FinanceandEconometrics,

UniversitatKonstanz, Germany.

References

[1] Ba~nuelos, R. and Bennett, A., Paraproducts and commutators of martingale trans-

forms. Proceedings of the American Mathematical Society, 103 (1988), 1226{1234

[2] Bellman, R., Functional equations in the theory of dynamic programming,positivity

and quasilinearity, Proc.Nat. Acad. Sci. U.S.A., 41 (1955),743{746

[3] Bismut, J. M., Conjugate convex functions in optimal stochastic control, J. Math.

Anal.Appl., 44 (1973),384{404

[4] Bismut, J. M., Linear quadratic optimal stochastic control with random coeÆcients,

SIAM J. Control Optim.,14 (1976),419-444

[5] Bismut, J.M.,Controledes systems linearesquadratiques: applications de l'integrale

stochastique, Seminaire de ProbabilitesXII, eds : C. Dellacherie, P. A. Meyer etM.

Weil, LNM 649, Springer-Verlag, Berlin1978

(23)

control weight costs, SIAM J. ControlOptim. 36 (1998), 1685-1702

[7] DuÆe, D. and Richardson, H. R., Mean-variance hedging in continuous time, Ann.

Appl. Prob., 1 (1991),1-15

[8] Follmer, H. and Leukert, P., EÆcient hedging: cost versus shortfall risk, Finance &

Stochastics, 4(2000), 117{146

[9] Follmer, H. and Sonderman, D., Hedging of non-redundant contingent claims. In:

Mas-Colell, A., Hildebrand, W. (eds.) Contributions to Mathematical Economics.

Amsterdam: North Holland 1986, pp. 205-223

[10] Follmer,H.and Schweizer,M.,Hedgingof contingentclaimsunderincompleteinfor-

mation.In: Davis,M.H.A.,Elliott,R.J.(eds.)AppliedStochasticAnalysis.(Stochas-

tics Monographs vol.5) London-New York: Gordon &Breach, 1991, pp. 389-414

[11] Gal'chuk, L. I., Existence and uniqueness of a solution for stochastic equations with

respect to semimartingales, Theory of Probability and Its Applications, 23 (1978),

751{763

[12] Gourieroux,C., Laurent,J.P.andPham,H.,Mean-variance hedgingand numeraire,

Mathematical Finance,8 (1998), 179-200.

[13] Heston, S., A closed-form solution for option with stochastic volatility with applica-

tions to bond and currency options. Rev.Financial Studies, 6(1993), 327{343

[14] Hipp, C., Hedging general claims, Proceedings of the 3rd AFIR colloqium, Rome,

Vol. 2,pp. 603-613(1993)

[15] Hull, J. and White, A., The pricing of options on assets with stochastic volatilities.

J. Finance,42 (1987),281-300

[16] Kobylanski, M., Resultats d'existence et d'unicite pour des equations dierentielles

stochastiques retrogrades avec des generateurs a croissance quadratique, C. R. Acad.

Sci. Paris, 324 (1997),Serie I, 81-86

[17] Kohlmann,M.and Tang,S., Optimalcontrolof linear stochasticsystems with singu-

lar costs, and the mean-variance hedgingproblem with stochastic market conditions.

submitted

[18] Kohlmann, M. and Tang, S., Global adapted solution of one-dimensional backward

stochastic Riccati equations, with application to the mean-variance hedging. submit-

ted

[19] Kohlmann,M.andTang,S.,Multi-dimensionalbackwardstochasticRiccatiequations

and applications. submitted

(24)

equations and stochastic controls: a linear-quadratic approach, SIAM J. Control &

Optim.,38 (2000),1392-1407

[21] Laurent, J. P. and Pham, H., Dynamic programming and mean-variance hedging,

Finance and Stochastics, 3 (1999),83-110

[22] Lepeltier, J. P. and San Martin, J., Backward stochastic dierential equations with

continuous coeÆcient, Statistics& Probability Letters,32 (1997),425-430

[23] Lepeltier, J. P. and San Martin, J., Existence for BSDE with superlinear-quadratic

coeÆcient, Stochastics& Stochastics Reports, 63(1998), 227-240

[24] Merton, R., Optimum consumption and portfolio rules in a continuous time model,

J. Econ. Theory, 3 (1971),pp. 373-413;Erratum 6 (1973),213-214.

[25] Monat, P. and Stricker, C., Follmer-Schweizer decomposition and mean-variance

hedging of general claims, Ann. Probab. 23,605{628

[26] Pardoux,E.and Peng, S.,Adapted solutionof backwardstochasticequation, Systems

Control Lett., 14(1990), 55{61

[27] Pardoux,E.andPeng, S.,Backwardstochasticdierentialequationsand quasi-linear

parabolic partial dierential equations, in: Rozovskii, B. L., Sowers, R. S. (eds.)

Stochastic Partial Dierential Equations and Their Applications, Lecture Notes in

Control and Information Science 176, Springer, Berlin,Heidelberg, New York 1992,

pp. 200{217

[28] Pardoux, E. and Tang, S., Forward-backward stochastic dierential equations with

application to quasi-linear partial dierential equations of second-order, Probability

Theory and Related Fields,114 (1999), 123-150

[29] Peng, S., StochasticHamilton-Jacobi-Bellmanequations,SIAM J.Controland Opti-

mization30 (1992) ,284-304

[30] Peng, S., Probabilistic interpretation for systems of semilinear parabolic PDEs,

Stochastics &Stochastic Reports, 37 (1991),61-74

[31] Peng, S., A generalized dynamic programming principle and Hamilton-Jacobi-

Bellman equation, Stochastics &Stochastics Reports, 38 (1992),119{134

[32] Peng, S., Some open problems on backward stochastic dierential equations, Control

of distributed parameter and stochastic systems, proceedings of the IFIP WG 7.2

international conference, June 19-22, 1998, Hangzhou, China

[33] Peng,S.,Ageneralstochasticmaximumprincipleforoptimalcontrolproblems,SIAM

J. ControlOptim., 28(1990), 966-979

[34] Pham,H.,Rheinlander,T.,andSchweizer,M.,Mean-variancehedgingforcontinuous

processes: New proofs and examples, Finance and Stochastics, 2 (1998),173-198

(25)

agement Science, 35(1989), 1045-1055

[36] Schweizer,M.,Mean-variancehedgingforgeneralclaims,Ann.Appl.Prob.,2(1992),

171-179

[37] Schweizer, M., Approaching random variables by stochastic integrals, Ann. Probab.,

22(1994), 1536{1575

[38] Schweizer, M., Approximation pricing and the variance-optimal martingalemeasure,

Ann. Probab., 24(1996), 206{236

[39] Stein, E. M. and Stein, J. C., Stock price distributions with stochastic volatility: an

analytic approach,Rev. Financial Studies, 4 (1991), 727-752

[40] Tang, S. and Li, X., Necessary conditions for optimal control of stochastic systems

with random jumps, SIAM J. Control Optim.,32(1994), 1447{1475

[41] Wonham,W.M.,On amatrixRiccatiequationofstochasticcontrol,SIAMJ.Control

Optim.,6 (1968),312-326

[42] Zhou,X. and Li,D., The continuous time mean-variance selection problem, Applied

Mathematics and Optimization,(2000),

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

The GAE reinforcement scheme (Baba 1983) has been introduced as a class of learning algorithms of stochastic automata operating in a multi- teacher

Deterministic descent methods use the exact values of these functions and their subgradients, stochastic descent methods use only the exact values of functions; deterministic

[r]

Moreover, we give various more speci®c convergence results, which have applications for stochastic equations, statistical estimation and stochastic optimization.. Keywords:

Subsection 2.1 shows that nonsmooth sample performance functions do not necessarily lead t o nonsmooth expectation functions. Unfortunately, even the case when the

To the best of our knowledge, the work of this chapter is the rst which provides the complete explicit solution to a two-dimensional degenerate singular stochastic control problem

tightness is proved by means of compactness properties of fractional integrals, while the identification procedure uses results on preservation of the local martingale property

Abstract: A new proof of existence of weak solutions to stochastic differential equations with continuous coefficients based on ideas from infinite-dimensional stochastic analysis