• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

A Has austerity failed in Europe?

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "A Has austerity failed in Europe?"

Copied!
3
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Daniel Gros is Director of the Centre for European Policy Studies. This Commentary was first published by Project Syndicate on 14 August 2013, and disseminated to newspapers and journals worldwide. It is republished here with the kind permission of Project Syndicate.

CEPS Commentaries offer concise, policy-oriented insights into topical issues in European affairs.

The views expressed are attributable only to the author in a personal capacity and not to any institution with which he is associated.

Available for free downloading from the CEPS website (www.ceps.eu)  © CEPS 2013

Centre for European Policy Studies▪ Place du Congrès 1 ▪ B-1000 Brussels ▪ Tel: (32.2) 229.39.11 ▪ www.ceps.eu

Has austerity failed in Europe?

Daniel Gros

16 August 2013

lthough many European governments have announced expenditure cuts and tax hikes, their debt-to-GDP ratios continue to deteriorate. So, if the purpose of austerity was to reduce debt levels, its critics are right: fiscal belt-tightening has failed. But the goal of austerity was not just to stabilise debt ratios.

In fact, austerity has worked as advertised in some cases. Germany temporarily increased the fiscal deficit by about 2.5 percentage points of GDP during the global recession of 2009;

subsequent rapid deficit reduction had no significant negative impact on growth. So it is possible to reduce deficits and keep the debt-to-GDP ratio in check – provided that the economy does not start out with large imbalances and that the financial system is working properly. Obviously, the countries on the eurozone’s periphery do not meet these conditions.

Countries whose governments have either lost access to normal market financing (like Greece, Ireland and Portugal), or face very high risk premia (like Italy and Spain in 2011-12) simply do not have a choice: they must reduce their expenditure or obtain financing from some official body like the International Monetary Fund or the European Stability Mechanism (ESM). But foreign official financing will always be subject to lenders’ conditions – and lenders see no reason to finance ongoing spending at the level that led the country into trouble.

So, in the eurozone periphery, austerity is not a question of fine-tuning demand, but of ensuring governments’ solvency. Economists like to point out that solvency has little to do with the ratio of public debt to today’s GDP, and much to do with debt relative to expected future tax revenues. A government’s solvency thus depends much more on long-term growth prospects than on the current debt-to-GDP ratio.

A reduction in the deficit today might lead in the short run to a fall in GDP that is larger than the cut in the deficit (if the so-called ‘multiplier’ is larger than one), which can cause the debt- to-GDP ratio to rise. But almost all economic models imply that a cut in expenditure today should lead to higher GDP in the long run, because it allows for lower taxes (and thus economic distortions).

Austerity should thus always be beneficial for solvency in the long run, even if the debt-to- GDP ratio deteriorates in the short run. For this reason, the current increase in debt-to-GDP ratios in southern Europe should not be interpreted as evidence that austerity does not work.

A

(2)

2|DANIEL GROS

Moreover, austerity has been accompanied by structural reforms, which should increase countries’ long-term growth potential, while pension reforms are set to reduce considerably the fiscal cost of aging populations. Such reforms promise to strengthen the solvency of all governments that adopt them, including those on the periphery of the eurozone.

More importantly, austerity has been very successful in restoring external balance to the eurozone’s periphery. The current accounts of all southern eurozone countries are improving rapidly and, with the exception of Greece, will soon swing into surplus. This fundamental change has contributed to the reduction in risk premia over the last year, despite the political upheaval that continues in many countries (particularly Italy, Portugal and Greece).

This external aspect is crucial. If public debt is owed to domestic investors, it can be serviced with the taxes levied on GDP. But debt owed to foreigners can be serviced only with goods and services sold abroad – that is, exports. Thus, the key variable for countries that had large current-account deficits, and thus are burdened today with a large foreign debt, is not the debt- to-GDP ratio, but the foreign debt-to-exports ratio (together with the growth prospects for exports).

Here, developments are encouraging. During the boom years, when countries like Greece, Portugal and Spain were running ever-larger external deficits, their exports did not grow quickly, so their foreign debt-to-exports ratio deteriorated steadily, reaching levels that are usually regarded as a warning signal. For example, for Spain and Portugal, the sum of past deficits relative to annual exports reached 300% and 400%, respectively, in 2008, whereas a 250% ratio is often regarded as the threshold at which external-financing problems can arise.

With austerity, imports have crashed everywhere in the periphery, while exports – helped also by falling labour costs – are increasing (except in Greece). As a result, as shown in the figure below, these countries’ current accounts are now moving into surplus and their external solvency is improving rapidly.

Cumulated current account balances as % of exports of goods and services (excluding oil)

Note: Oil excluded from exports because for these countries oil exports consist only of re-exports of crude as refined products and the value-added margin of the refinery is a small fraction of the value of these exports.

Source: Own calculations based on data from Eurostat and the IMF (WEO database).

(3)

THE AUSTERITY DEBATE IS BESIDE THE POINT |3

Indeed, according to the IMF, Spain should record growing current-account surpluses over the next five years, as exports rise strongly, thus cutting the external debt-to-export ratio by half (to about 150% in 2018), while Portugal’s should fall to about 250%. Even Italy, whose external deficits have remained small, will soon record a current-account surplus.

Austerity always involves huge social costs, but it is unavoidable when a country has lived beyond its means and lost the confidence of its foreign creditors. The external fundamentals of the eurozone periphery are now improving rapidly. In this sense, austerity has done exactly what it was intended to do.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

I saw this possibility already in 1977 when I wrote a contribution to the political and ethnic geography of North Pakistan, but I was well aware that the

In Greece, Portugal or Spain, the family performs two basic roles related to economy: firstly, a household functions as a guarantee of social security, family members

Two basic propositions follow from this constitutional train of thought: 1] Developing countries with reasonably well functioning trade policy management and credible trade

Indeed, in many respects one can make the case that Greece merely represents the more extreme end of a spectrum of politics that, across Europe, is bringing a rise in

The one revolution we've seen is the way they voted both in the May European elections and just now at the end of January, which brought in what is the first really for Greece

The real test of the extent to which Spain is not bracketed in the same basket case category as Greece will come if, as expected, Syriza wins and its victory contaminates Spain.

 A recent briefing note by Open Europe claims that German citizens’ tend to trust the European parliament less than their national parliament and detects a trend in the

Key words: Abkhazia, Armenia, Azerbaijan, Caspian Sea oil fields, conflict, conflict resolution, European Union, Georgia, Iran, Nagorno-Karabakh, North Atlantic Treaty