• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Efficient computation of option price sensitivities using homogeneity and other tricks

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Efficient computation of option price sensitivities using homogeneity and other tricks"

Copied!
26
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

für Angewandte Analysis und Stochastik

imForschungsverbund Berline.V.

Preprint ISSN 0946 8633

Ecient Computation of Option Price Sensitivities

Using Homogeneity and other Tricks

Oliver Reiÿ 1

, Uwe Wystup 2

submitted: May24th2000

1

Weierstrass-Institutefor

AppliedAnalysisandStochastics

Mohrenstraÿe39

D -10117Berlin

Germany

E-Mail: reiss@wias-berlin.de

URL:http://www.wias-berlin.de/reiss 2

Commerzbank

TreasuryandFinancialProducts

NeueMainzerStraÿe32-36

D-60261FrankfurtamMain

Germany

E-Mail: wystup@mathnance.de

URL:http://www.mathfinance.de

Preprint No. 584

Berlin2000

WIAS

2000 MathematicsSubjectClassication. 91-08,91B28.

Key words and phrases. Calculation of Greeks, Derivatives of option prices, Homogeneity

propertiesofnancialmarkets.

OliverReiÿ ispartiallyaliatedtoDelft University,bysupportofNWONetherlands.

(2)

WeierstraÿInstitut für Angewandte Analysisund Stochastik (WIAS)

Mohrenstraÿe 39

D 10117 Berlin

Germany

Fax: +49 302044975

E-Mail (X.400): c=de;a=d400-gw;p=WIAS-BERLIN;s=preprint

E-Mail (Internet): preprint@wias-berlin.de

World WideWeb: http://www.wias-berlin.de/

(3)

No front-oce software can survive without providing derivatives of op-

tions prices with respect to underlying market or model parameters, the so

called Greeks. We present a list of common Greeks and exploit homogene-

ityproperties ofnancialmarkets to derive relationshipsbetween Greeksout

of which many are model-independent. We apply the results to European

styleoptions,rainbowoptions,aswellasoptionspricedinHeston'sstochastic

volatility model and avoid exorbitant and time-consuming computations of

derivativeswhicheven strong symboliccalculators failto produce.

1 Introduction

The computation of sensitivities of option prices, the so-called Greeks, is often

cumbersome-both forthe mathematicianand for symboliccalculators. This paper

provides methods to avoid dierentiation as much as possible. Many Greeks are

related among each other. These relations are based on model-independenthomo-

geneity of time and price level of a nancial product on the one hand and model

dependent relationssuchasthe partialdierentialequation thevalue functionmust

satisfy and relations implied by the assumed distribution of the underlying. The

basic marketmodelwe use is the Black-Scholes modelwith stocks paying acontin-

uousdividendyieldandariskless cashbond. This modelsupportsthe homogeneity

properties which are valid in general, but its structure is so simple, that we can

concentrate on the essential statements of this paper. We will also discuss how to

extend our work tomore generalmarketmodels.

We list the commonly used Greeks and their symbols. We do not claim this list

tobe complete, because one can always dene more derivatives of the option price

function.

As special cases we look at the Greeks of European options in the Black-Scholes

modelin one dimension. It turns out, that one only needs to know two Greeks in

orderto calculateallthe otherGreeks withoutdierentiating.

Another interesting example is a European derivative security depending on two

assets. For such rainbow options the analysis of the risk due to changing correla-

tion of the two assets is very important. We will show how this risk is related to

simultaneous changes of the two underlyingsecurities.

Thereare several applications of these homogeneity relations.

(4)

2. It produces a robust implementation compared to Greeks via dierence quo-

tients.

3. It allows to check the quality and consistency of Greeks produced by nite-

dierence-, tree- orMonte Carlo methods.

4. Itadmits a computationof Greeks for Monte Carlo based values.

5. It shows relationships between Greeks which wouldn't be noticed merely by

lookingatdierence quotients.

1.1 Notation

S stock price or stock price process

B cash bond, usually with risk free interest rate r

r risk freeinterestrate

q dividend yield(continuously paid)

volatility of one stock, orvolatilitymatrix of several stocks

correlation inthe two-asset marketmodel

t date of evaluation(today)

T date of maturity

=T t time tomaturity ofan option

x stock price at time t

f() payo function

v(x;t;:::) value of an option

k strike of anoption

l level of anoption

v

x

partial derivation of v with respect tox (and analogous)

The standard normaldistribution and density functions are dened by

n(t)

= 1

p

2 e

1

2 t

2

(1)

N(x)

= Z

x

1

n(t)dt (2)

n

2

(x;y;)

=

1

2 p

1

2 exp

x 2

2xy+y 2

2(1 2

)

!

(3)

N

2

(x;y;)

= Z

x

1 Z

y

1 n

2

(u;v;)dudv (4)

See http://www.MathFinance.de/frontoce.html fora sourcecode to compute N

2 .

(5)

Delta v

x

Gamma v

xx

Theta v

t

Rho v

r

inthe one-stock model

Rhor

r

v

r

inthe two-stock model

Rhoq

q

v

q

Vega v

Kappa v

correlation sensitivity (two-stock model)

Greeks, not so commonly used:

Leverage

x

v v

x

sometimes , sometimes called gearing

Vomma

0

v

Speed v

xxx

Charm v

xt

Color v

xxt

Cross v

x

Forward Delta F

v

F

Driftless Delta dl

e q

Dual Theta Dual v

T

StrikeDelta k

v

k

StrikeGamma k

v

kk

Level Delta l

v

l

Level Gamma l

v

l l

Beta

12

1

2

two-stock model

2 Fundamental Properties

2.1 Homogeneity of Time

Inmostcasesthe priceoftheoptionisnotafunctionof boththecurrenttimetand

the maturity time T,but ratheronly afunction of the time to maturity =T t

implyingthe relations

=v

t

= v

= v

T

= Dual: (5)

Thisrelationshipextends naturallytothe situationof optionsdepending onseveral

intermediate timessuch as compound orBermuda options.

(6)

We present theprincipleof the scale-invarianceof time inthis section,becausethis

principle holds in general. In a market model parameters may be quoted on an

annual basis. We illustrate this idea in a Black-Scholes framework, in which the

volatility is such a modelparameter. The same idea can easily be applied toother

marketmodels.

Wemay wanttomeasure time inunitsotherthan years inwhichcase interestrates

and volatilities, which are normally quoted on an annual basis, must be changed

according tothe followingrules for all a>0.

!

a

r ! ar

q ! aq

!

p

a (6)

The option'svalue must be invariant underthis rescaling, i.e.,

v(x;;r;q;;:::)=v(x;

a

;ar;aq;

p

a;:::) (7)

We dierentiate this equationwith respect to a and obtain fora =1

0=+r+q

q +

1

2

; (8)

a general relation between the Greeks theta, rho, rhoq and vega. Based on the

relation

v(x

1

;:::;x

n

;;r;q

1

;:::;q

n

;

11

;:::;

nn )=

v(x

1

;:::;x

n

;

a

;ar;aq

1

;:::;aq

n

; p

a

11

;:::;

p

a

nn

) (9)

weobtain

Theorem 1 (scale invariance of time)

0=+r+ n

X

i=1 q

i

q

i +

1

2 n

X

i;j=1

ij

ij

; (10)

where

ij

denotes the dierentiation of v with respect to

ij .

2.3 Scale Invariance of Prices

Thegeneralidea isthatvalue ofsecurities maybemeasuredinadierentunit, just

like values of European stocks are now measured in Euro instead of in-currencies.

Option contracts usually depend on strikes and barrier levels. Rescaling can have

(7)

types of homogeneity classes. Letv(x;k) be the value function of an option, where

xis the spot (or a vector of spots) and k the strike orbarrier or a vector of strikes

orbarriers. Let a be apositivereal number.

Denition 1 (homogeneity classes) We calla value functionk-homogeneous of

degree n iffor all a>0

v(ax;ak) = a n

v(x;k): (11)

We callan options whose value function is strike-homogeneousof degree 1 a strike-

denedoption andsimilarly an optionwhose valuefunction islevel-homogeneousof

degree 0 a level-dened option.

The value function of a European call or put option with strike K is then K-

homogeneous of degree 1, a digital option which pays a xed amount if the stock

priceis higher than a level L isL-homogeneous of degree 0. The path-independent

barrier call option paying (S k) +

I

fS>Kg

is (k;K)-homogeneous of degree 1. A

power call with cap paying min(C;((S K) +

) 2

) has a homogeneity structure of

v(aS;aK;a 2

C)=a 2

v(S;K;C).

Weshowhowsuchascaleinvariancecanbeusedtodeterminesomerelationsamong

the Greeks. We explain this with two examples. In the rst example we analyze a

strike-denedoptionandinthe secondoneweconcentrateonaleveldened option.

The generalizationtooptions withsome more parameters likethe mentionedpath-

independent barrier call or power-call can easily be done. For the barrier call one

can use the results from the multi-dimensionalstrike-dened option (26) and (27).

2.3.1 Strike-Delta and Strike-Gamma

Fora strike-dened value function we havefor all a;b>0

abv(x;k) = v(abx;abk): (12)

We dierentiate with respect to a and get for a=1

bv(x;k) = bxv

x

(bx;bk)+bkv

k

(bx;bk): (13)

We nowdierentiate with respect tob get for b=1

v(x;k) = xv

x +xv

xx

x+xv

xk k+kv

k +kv

kx x+kv

kk

k (14)

= x+x 2

+2xkv

xk +k

k

+k 2 k

: (15)

Ifwe evaluate equation(13) at b=1 we get

v =x+k k

: (16)

(8)

k

= xv

kx +

k

+k k

; (17)

kxv

kx

= k

2 k

: (18)

Togetherwith equation (15) we conclude

x 2

=k 2 k

: (19)

2.3.2 Level-Delta and Level-Gamma

Fora level-dened value functionwe have forall a;b>0

v(x;l) = v(abx;abl): (20)

We dierentiate with respect to a and get at a=1

0 = v

x

(bx;bl)bx+v

l

(bx;bl)bl: (21)

Ifwe set b =1we get the relation

x+

l

l=0: (22)

Now wedierentiate equation (21) with respect tob and get atb =1

0 = v

xx x

2

+2v

xl xl+v

l l l

2

: (23)

One the other hand we can dierentiate the relation between delta and level-delta

with respect tol and get

v

xl x+l

l

+ l

= 0: (24)

Togetherwith equation (23) we conclude

x 2

+x =l 2 l

+l l

: (25)

In generalwe obtain

Theorem 2 (price homogeneity)

v = n

X

i=1 x

i

i +

m

X

j=1 k

j

k

j

(26)

n

X

i;j=1 x

i x

j ij

= m

X

i;j=1 k

i k

j k

ij

(27)

for strike-dened options and

0= n

X

i=1 x

i

i +

m

X

j=1 l

j

l

j

(28)

n

X

i;j=1 x

i x

j ij +

n

X

i=1 x

i

i

= m

X

i;j=1 l

i l

j l

ij +

m

X

i=1 l

i

l

i

(29)

for level-dened options.

(9)

Model

We start with relations among Greeks for European claims in the n-dimensional

Black-Scholes model

dS

i

(t) = S

i

(t)[(r q

i

)dt+

i dW

i

(t)]; i=1;:::;n (30)

Cov(W

i (t);W

j

(t)) =

ij

t; (31)

wherer isthe risk-freerate, q

i

the dividendrate ofasset i orforeign interest rateof

exchange rate i,

i

the volatility of asset i and (W

1

;:::;W

n

) a standard Brownian

motion (under the risk-neutral measure) with correlation matrix . Let v denote

today's value of the payo f(S

1

(T);:::;S

n

(T)) at maturity T. Then it is known

that v satisesthe Black-Scholes partial dierentialequation

0 = v

rv+ n

X

i=1 x

i (r q

i )v

xi +

1

2 n

X

i;j=1 (Æ

T

)

ij x

i x

j v

xixj

: (32)

3.1 Relations among Greeks Based on the Log-Normal Dis-

tribution

The value function v has a representation given by the n-fold integral

v =e r

Z

f

:::;S

i (0)e

i p

x

i +

i

;:::

g(~x;)d~x; (33)

where

i

=r q

i 1

2

2

i

and g(~x;) is the n-variate standard normal density with

correlationmatrix . Since we donot want to assumedierentiabilityof the payo

f, but we know that the transition density g is dierentiable, we dene a change

the variables y

i

=S

i (0)e

i p

xi+i

, which leads to

v =e r

Z

f(:::;y

i

;:::)g ln

y

i

S

i (0)

i

i p

;

!

d~y

Q

y

i

i p

: (34)

3.1.1 Properties of the Normal Distribution

We collect some properties of the multivariate normal density function g. We sup-

pose that the vector X of n random variables with means zero and unit variances

hasanonsingularnormalmultivariatedistributionwithprobabilitydensityfunction

g(x

1

;:::;x

n

;c

11

;:::;c

nn

)=(2) 1

2 n

jCj 1

2

exp

1

2 x

T

Cx

: (35)

Here C is the inverse of the covariance matrix of X, which is denoted by . Then

thefollowingidentitypublished in[3]canbeproved easilyby writingthe density in

termsof its characteristic function.

(10)

@g

@

ij

=

@ 2

g

@x

i

@x

j

: (36)

In the two-dimensional case this reads as

@n

2

(x;y;)

@

=

@ 2

n

2

(x;y;)

@x@y

; (37)

whichcanbeextendedreadilytothecorrespondingcumulativedistributionfunction,

i.e.,

@N

2

(x;y;)

@

=

@ 2

N

2

(x;y;)

@x@y

=n

2

(x;y;): (38)

3.1.2 Correlation Risk and Cross-Gamma

Usingthe abbreviation g

jk

=

@ 2

g

@x

j

@x

k

the cross-gamma and correlation riskare

@ 2

v

@S

j (0)@S

k (0)

= e r

1

S

j (0)S

k (0)

j

k

Z

f(:::;y

i

;:::)g

jk d~y

Q

y

i

i p

; (39)

@v

@

jk

= e r

Z

f(:::;y

i

;:::)g

jk

d~y

Q

y

i

i p

: (40)

InvokingPlackett's identity (36) saying that g

jk

=g

jk

leads to

Theorem 4 (cross-gamma-correlation-riskrelationship)

@v

@

jk

= S

j (0)S

k (0)

j

k

@ 2

v

@S

j (0)@S

k (0)

: (41)

3.1.3 Interest Rate Risk and Delta

A similarcomputation yields

Theorem 5 (delta-rho relationship)

@v

@q

j

= S

j (0)

@v

@S

j (0)

; (42)

@v

@r

=

0

@

v n

X

j=1 S

j (0)

@v

@S

j (0)

1

A

: (43)

(11)

The rst and second derivativeof the density g satisfy

g

j

= g

n

X

i=1 x

i C

ij

; (44)

g

jk

= g n

X

i=1 x

i C

ij n

X

i=1 x

i C

ik gC

kj

: (45)

Forthe j-th vega we nd thus

j

@v

@

j

= e r

Z

fg n

X

i=1 x

i C

ij x

j 1

!

d~y

Q

y

i

i p

; (46)

x

j

= ln

y

i

S

i (0)

(r q

i +

1

2

2

i )

i p

=x

j

j p

; (47)

where we omit the arguments of f and g to simplify the notation. For the cross

gammaswe derive

j

k S

j (0)S

k (0)

@ 2

v

@S

j (0)@S

k (0)

=e r

Z

fgB

jk d~y

Q

y

i

i p

; (48)

B

jk

= n

X

i=1 x

i C

ij n

X

i=1 x

i C

ik C

kj n

X

i=1 x

i C

ij

k p

Æ

jk

: (49)

We now multiply by

jk

, sum over k, remember that is the inverse matrix of C

and obtain

n

X

k=1

jk

j

k S

j (0)S

k (0)

@ 2

v

@S

j (0)@S

k (0)

=e r

Z

f gD

j

d~y

Q

y

i

i p

; (50)

D

j

= n

X

i=1 x

i C

ij x

j 1

n

X

i=1 x

i C

ij x

j +

n

X

i=1 x

i C

ij x

j

: (51)

In summarywe obtain

Theorem 6 (gamma-vega relationship)

j

@v

@

j

= n

X

k=1

jk

j

k S

j (0)S

k (0)

@ 2

v

@S

j (0)@S

k (0)

: (52)

In dimension one the gamma-vega and delta-rho relationships are also mentioned

in[4]. Shawshows therethat v

S 2

(t)v

S(t)S(t)

satisesthe Black-Scholes partial

dierentialequationand ishenceidenticallyzerofor path-independent options. We

note that the gamma-vega relationship does not hold for barrier options, simply

because gammaand vega are not equalatthe barrier.

(12)

4.1 Results for European Claims in the Black-Scholes Model

We listseveral relationsfor European options.

0 = +r+q

q +

1

2

scale invarianceof time (53)

v = x+k

k

price homogeneity and strikes (54)

x 2

= k 2 k

price homogeneity and strikes (55)

x = l

l

price homogeneity and levels (56)

x 2

+x = l 2 l

+l l

price homogeneity and levels (57)

= (v x) delta-rho relationship (58)

+

q

= v rates symmetry (59)

rv = +(r q)x+ 1

2

2

x 2

Black-Scholes PDE (60)

qv = +(q r)k k

+ 1

2

2

k 2 k

dual Black-Scholes (strike) (61)

rv = +(q r+ 2

)l l

+ 1

2

2

l 2 l

dual Black-Scholes (level) (62)

q

= x delta-rho relationship (63)

= k

k

combination of (63) and (54) (64)

= x

2

gamma-vega relationship (65)

An interpretation of equation (65) can be found in[6]. We would like to point out

thatthisrelationshipisbasedonafactconcerningthenormaldistributionfunction,

namelydening

n(t;)

= 1

p

2 2

e t

2

2 2

; (66)

N(x;)

= Z

x

1

n(t;)dt; (67)

one can verify that

@ 2

xx

N(x;)=@

N(x;): (68)

There are surely more relations one can prove, but the next theorem will give a

deeper insight intothe relationsof the Greeks.

Theorem 7 If the price and two Greeks g

1

;g

2

of a European option are given with

g

1

2 G

1

=f;

k

; l

;;

q

g; (69)

g

2

2 G

2

=f ; k

; l

;;g; (70)

then all the other Greeks (2 G

1 [ G

2

) can be calculated. Furthermore, if and

another Greek from G

2

is given, it is alsopossible, to determine all other Greeks.

(13)

(61) to(63) are conclusions. To get an overview overall these relations,we listthe

appearance of each Greek in all these relations. WithX or O we denote, that the

marked Greek appears in the relation. The relations marked with X show, that

thereisarelationbetween Greeks of G

1

and G

2

and theO shows, thatthis relation

concerns onlythe Greeks of one set.

Greeks2G

1

Greeks2G

2

equation v k

l

q

k l

(53) X X X X

(54) O O O

(55) O O

(56) O O

(57) X X X X

(58) O O O

(59) O O O

(60) X X X X

(61) X X X X

(62) X X X X

(64) O O

(65) O O

(63) O O

Letusnowassumethe optionprice andone Greek fromthe set G

1

are given. Then

a look at the table shows that all Greeks of the set G

1

can be evaluated. If all

Greeks of the set G

1

are known and additionally one Greek of the set G

2

is given,

allother Greeks can be determined. One the other hand, only eight equations are

independent, so the knowledge of two Greeks is also the minimum knowledge one

needs todetermine allten Greeks. This isthe proof of the rst statement.

If and another Greek from G

2

is given, then it is always possible to determine

oneGreek ofthe set G

1

and one appliesthe partof this theorem already proved. If

; k

or l

isgiven, one can use one of the Black-Scholes equations(60) to (62). If

vega is given, one can use (65) to get .

We conclude this sectionwith anexample. In the special case of plain vanilla calls

and puts in a foreign exchange marketall relations for the Greeks presented above

are valid. These formulas are wellknown and can be found in [7].

4.2 A Path-Independent Barrier Call

4.2.1 Value

The payo of a path-independentdown-and-out barrier callisgiven by

f(S

T

;k;K) = (S k) +

I

fS

T

>Kg

(71)

(14)

payocanbewrittenas(S

T k)I

fS

T

>Kg

. WeclaimthatkandK arestrikes,because

this optionhas the scaling behaviorf(aS

T

;ak;aK)=af(S

T

;k;K). Intuitively one

would callK a level; but we dened alevel by its scalingbehavior in section2.3.2,

which is not valid in this case. Therefore the path-independent barrier call is an

examplefor a strike-dened option.

Usingthe abbreviation

d

= ln(

S

0

K

)+(r q) 1

2

2

p

2

; (72)

the value of a path-independent down-and-out barriercall isgiven by

v(S

0

;k;K) = e r

Z

1

K

s k

s p

2 2

exp

(ln(

s

S

0

) (r q) + 1

2

2

) 2

2 2

!

ds

= S

0 e

q

N(d

+ ) ke

r

N(d ): (73)

We now want to calculateall Greeks of this option. We show that Theorem 7 can

beused toorganizethe calculation of the Greeks.

4.2.2 Greeks

Delta. Since dierentiation cannot be avoided entirely, we choose the derivative

with respect to k,which isobviously

v

k

= e

r

N(d ): (74)

Next we dierentiate the integral representation of v with respect to K and

obtain

v

K

= e r

k K

K p

2 2

exp

0

@ (ln(

K

S

0

) (r q) + 1

2

2

) 2

2 2

1

A

=

k K

K 1

p

2

e

r

n(d ): (75)

In Theorem 7 we had assumed only one strike. In our example we have two

strikes, and therefore we need two Greeks from the set G

1

to determine all

other Greeks of this set. >From the price homogeneity we know that the

relation

v = S

0 v

S

0 +kv

k +Kv

K

(76)

holds,whence we obtainfor the spot delta

v

S

0

= e q

N(d

+ )+

K k

S

0 1

p

2

e

r

n(d ): (77)

(15)

v

r

= ke r

N(d )+

K k

p

2

e

r

n(d ); (78)

v

q

= S

0 e

q

N(d

+

)

K k

p

2

e

r

n(d ): (79)

Gamma. We have calculated all Greeks in G

1

. To determine some other Greeks

withoutdierentiationweneedatleastoneGreekofthesetG

2

. Inthetheorem

above we assumed, that the option will be described by one strike, but the

optionwe analyzedepends ontwostrikes. Sowe haveto dierentiate trice to

get alldual gammas.

v

kk

= 0 (80)

v

kK

= 1

K 1

p

2

e

r

n(d ) (81)

v

KK

= k

K 2

e r

p

2

n(d )+

k K

K 2

e r

2

n(d )d (82)

The extensionof (55) to the case of one stock and two strikes isthe equation

(27)with n=1and m =2. In our example this relationis given by

S 2

0

= k 2 kk

+2kK kK

+K 2 KK

: (83)

>From this relation, which follows from the homogeneity of v, we obtain for

the spotgamma withoutdierentiation

v

S

0 S

0

= ke

r

S 2

0 p

2

n(d )+

k K

S 2

0

e r

2

n(d )d : (84)

Vega. >From (65) we get

v

= p

ke r

n(d ) (K k)e r

1

n(d )d : (85)

Theta. >From the scale invariance of time (53) we obtain

v

t

= v

= rke r

N(d )+qS

0 e

q

N(d

+ )

(r q)

K k

p

2

e

r

n(d )

2 p

ke

r

n(d )

+ 1

2

(K k)e r

n(d )d (86)

(16)

Black-Scholes Model

5.1 Pricing of a European Option

Rainbow options are nancial instruments which depend on several risky assets.

Many of them are very sensitive to changes of correlation. We call kappa () the

derivativeof the option value v with respect to the correlation .

Thecomputationaleorttocomputethe kappaishard,eveninasimpleframework,

but in the Black-Scholes model with two stocks and one cash bond we can use the

cross-gamma-correlation-riskrelationshipwhich can be used easilytond kappa.

Letthe stock price processes S

1

and S

2

be described by

ln S

1 ()

S

1 (0)

= (r q

1 1

2

2

1 ) +

1 W

1

; (87)

ln S

2 ()

S

2 (0)

= (r q

2 1

2

2

2 ) +

2 W

1

+

2 q

1

2

W 2

: (88)

W 1

andW 2

are twoindependentBrownianmotionsundertheriskneutralmeasure.

Theprobabilitydensityforthe distributionofS

1

()isdenotedbyh

1

(x)andisgiven

by the log-normaldensity

h

1

(x) =

1

q

2 2

1

1

x exp

A 2

2 2

1

!

; (89)

A

= ln x

S

1 (0)

!

r +q

1 +

1

2

2

1

: (90)

The equationfor the second stock priceprocess can be writtenas

ln S

2 ()

S

2 (0)

= (r q

2 1

2

2

2 ) +

2

1 ln

S

1 ()

S

1 (0)

!

(r q

1 1

2

2

1 )

!

+

2 q

1

2

W 2

: (91)

The conditionaldistribution of S

2

() given S

1

() is thuslog-normalwith density

h

2j1

(yjx) =

1

y q

2 2

2

(1

2

) exp

B 2

2 2

2

(1

2

)

!

; (92)

B

=

"

ln y

S

2 (0)

!

r+q

2 +

1

2

2

2

2

1 A

#

: (93)

The joint distributionof S

1

()and S

2

() isgiven by the productof h

1

and h

2

h(x;y) = h

1 (x)h

2j1

(yjx): (94)

(17)

1 2

v = e r

1

Z

0 1

Z

0

h(x;y)f(x;y)dxdy: (95)

Thisintegralhas exactlythe structure of the integralsstudiedin section3.1. Using

theresultsprovidedabove,onecancollectseveralrelationshipsforthe Greeksinthe

two-dimensional case. Additional, the fundamental symmetry scale invariance of

timeisvalidtoo. BecauseweconcentrateonEuropeanoptions,thetwodimensional

Black-Scholes-PDE also holds.

5.2 Relations among the Greeks

We specialize the relationships among the Greeks found in n dimensions. Some

resultsare

0 =

q

1 +S

1 (0)

1

; (96)

0 =

q2 +S

2 (0)

2

; (97)

0 = q

1

q

1 +q

2

q

2 +

1

2

1

1 +

1

2

2

2 +r

r

+; (98)

0 = rv+(r q

1 )S

1 (0)

1

+(r q

2 )S

2 (0)

2

+ 1

2

2

1 S

1 (0)

2

11

+

1

2 S

1 (0)S

2 (0)

12 +

1

2

2

2 S

2 (0)

2

22

; (99)

=

1

2 S

1 (0)S

2 (0)

12

; (100)

0 =

1

1 +

2

1 S

1 (0)

2

11

; (101)

0 =

2

2 +

2

2 S

2 (0)

2

22

; (102)

0 =

1

1

2

2

2

1 S

1 (0)

2

11 +

2

2 S

2 (0)

2

22

; (103)

r

= (v S

1 (0)

1 S

2 (0)

2

); (104)

0 = v +

q1 +

q2 +

r

: (105)

Of course one can get more relations by combining some relations above. The

relationswehavechosen topresentare eithersimilartothe one-dimensionalcase or

have anothernatural interpretation.

(96) and (97). These relations are a justication for the rough way to deal

with dividends. One subtracts the dividends from the actual spot price and

prices the option with this price and without dividends. This relation is not

eectedby the two-dimensionalityof the problem.

(98). This isthe two-dimensionalversionof thegeneral invarianceundertime

scaling.

(99). This is the Black-Scholes dierential equation. This relation must hold,

because weconcentrated on European claims. It turns out, that the dynamic

(18)

optionis dened as aboundaryproblem.

(100). This is the cross-gamma-correlation-risk relationship;it is remarkable,

that this relationshiphas such a simple structure.

(101)and(102). Thesearethegamma-vegarelationships. Noticethatonecan

determineonlyby knowledgeofsomederivativeswith respect toparameters

which concern only one stock. Of course, there is no dierence between the

rst and the second stock. These relations are valid in the one-dimensional

case with 0.

(103)follows from(100).

(104). This is the delta-rho relationship. The interest rate risk is well known

to be the negative product of duration and the amount of money invested.

The term in the parentheses is exactly the amount of money one would have

toinvest in the cash bond in order todelta-hedge the option.

(105). This relation is the two-dimensional rates symmetry, an extension of

equation(59). It follows from(104), (96) and (97).

Inthefollowingwetreatoneexampleinfulldetail. Furtherexamplessuchasoutside

barrieroptions and spreadoptions are available in[7].

5.3 European Options on the Minimum/Maximum of Two

Assets

We consider the payo

[(min(S

1

(T);S

2

(T)) K)]

+

: (106)

This isa European put orcallonthe minimum ( =+1) ormaximum ( = 1)of

thetwoassetsS

1

(T)and S

2

(T)withstrikeK. Asusual, thebinary variabletakes

thevalue +1foracalland 1foraput. Itsvalue functionhasbeen publishedin[5]

and can be writtenas

v(t;S

1 (t);S

2

(t);K;T;q

1

;q

2

;r;

1

;

2

;;;) (107)

=

h

S

1 (t)e

q

1

N

2 (d

1

;d

3

;

1 )

+S

2 (t)e

q

2

N

2 (d

2

;d

4

;

2 )

Ke r

1

2

+N

2 ((d

1

1 p

);(d

2

2 p

);)

!#

;

2

=

2

1 +

2

2

2

1

2

; (108)

(19)

1

=

2 1

; (109)

2

=

1

2

; (110)

d

1

= ln(S

1

(t)=K)+(r q

1 +

1

2

2

1 )

1 p

; (111)

d

2

= ln(S

2

(t)=K)+(r q

2 +

1

2

2

2 )

2 p

; (112)

d

3

= ln(S

2 (t)=S

1

(t))+(q

1 q

2 1

2

2

)

p

; (113)

d

4

= ln(S

1 (t)=S

2

(t))+(q

2 q

1 1

2

2

)

p

: (114)

5.3.1 Greeks

Delta. Space homogeneity implies that

v =S

1 (t)

@v

@S

1 (t)

+S

2 (t)

@v

@S

2 (t)

+K

@v

@K

: (115)

Usingthisequationoneonlyhastodierentiatetwiceinordertogetalldeltas.

It turns out, that the value function is given in the natural representation,

which ispresented inthe appendix, and one is allowed toread o the deltas:

@v

@S

1 (t)

= e

q

1

N

2 (d

1

;d

3

;

1

); (116)

@v

@S

2 (t)

= e

q

2

N

2 (d

2

;d

4

;

2

); (117)

@v

@K

= e

r

1

2

+N

2 ((d

1

1 p

);(d

2

2 p

);)

:

(118)

Gamma. Computingthegammasisactuallythelastsituationwheredierentiation

isneeded. We use the identities

@

@x N

2

(x;y;) = n(x)N

y x

p

1

2

!

; (119)

@

@y N

2

(x;y;) = n(y)N

x y

p

1

2

!

; (120)

and obtain

(20)

@ 2

v

@(S

1 (t))

2

= e

q

1

S

1 (t)

p

1 n(d

1

)N

d

3 d

1

1

2 p

1

2

n(d

3

)N

d

1 d

3

1

2 p

1

2

!#

; (121)

@ 2

v

@(S

2 (t))

2

= e

q2

S

2 (t)

p

"

2 n(d

2

)N

d

4 d

2

2

1 p

1

2

!

n(d

4

)N

d

2 d

4

2

1 p

1

2

!#

; (122)

@ 2

v

@S

1 (t)@S

2 (t)

= e

q

1

S

2 (t)

p

n(d

3

)N

d

1 d

3

1

2 p

1

2

!

: (123)

Kappa. The sensitivity with respect to correlation is directly relatedto the cross-

gamma

@v

@

=

1

2 S

1 (t)S

2 (t)

@ 2

v

@S

1 (t)@S

2 (t)

: (124)

Vega. We referto (101) and (102)to get the following formulas for the vegas,

@v

@

1

= v

+

2

1 (S

1 (t))

2

v

S

1 (t)S

1 (t)

1

(125)

= S

1 (t)e

q

1

p

"

1 n(d

3

)N

d

1 d

3

1

2 p

1

2

!

+n(d

1

)N

d

3 d

1

1

2 p

1

2

!#

; (126)

@v

@

2

= v

+

2

2 (S

2 (t))

2

v

S

2 (t)S

2 (t)

2

(127)

= S

2 (t)e

q

2

p

"

2 n(d

4

)N

d

2 d

4

2

1 p

1

2

!

+n(d

2

)N

d

4 d

2

2

1 p

1

2

!#

: (128)

Rho. Lookingat(96), (97) and (104) the rhos are given by

@v

@q

1

= S

1 (t)

@v

@S

1 (t)

; (129)

@v

@q

2

= S

2 (t)

@v

@S

2 (t)

; (130)

@v

@r

= K

@v

@K

: (131)

(21)

on(98).

@v

@t

= 1

q

1 v

q1 +q

2 v

q2 +rv

r +

1

2 v

1 +

2

2 v

2

: (132)

6 Generalization to Higher Dimensions

and other Market Models

6.1 Beyond Black-Scholes

Up to now we illustrated our ideas in the Black-Scholes model and in some parts

we used specic properties of this model. Nevertheless there are some properties,

which are so fundamental, that they should hold in any realistic market model.

These fundamental properties are the homogeneity of time, the scale invariance of

timeandthescaleinvarianceofprices. Foreverymarketmodeloneuses,one should

check, if the modelfulllsthese properties.

Anexample for amarket modelwith non-deterministicvolatilityis Heston'sstoch-

astic volatility model[2].

In this more general framework one needs to clarify the notion of vega. A change

of volatilitycould mean a change of the entire underlying volatility process. If the

pricing formula depends on input parameters such as initialvolatility, volatility of

volatility,meanreversionofvolatility,thenonecanconsiderderivativeswithrespect

to such parameters. It turns out that our strategy to compute Greeks can still be

appliedsuccessfully ina stochastic volatilitymodel.

6.2 Heston's Stochastic Volatility Model

dS

t

= S

t

dt+ q

v(t)dW (1)

t

; (133)

dv

t

= ( v

t

)dt+ q

v(t)dW (2)

t

; (134)

Cov h

dW (1)

t

;dW (2)

t i

= dt; (135)

(S;v;t) = v: (136)

The model for the variance v

t

is the same as the one used by Cox, Ingersoll and

Ross for the short term interest rate, see [1]. We think of > 0 as the long term

variance, of > 0 as the rate of mean-reversion. The quantity (S;v;t) is called

the marketprice of volatilityrisk.

Heston providesa closed-formsolutionfor European vanilla optionspaying

[(S

T

K) ] +

: (137)

(22)

the strike in units of the domestic currency, q the risk free rate of asset S, r the

domesticrisk freerate and T the expiration time inyears.

6.2.1 Abbreviations

a

= (138)

u

1

= 1

2

(139)

u

2

= 1

2

(140)

b

1

= + (141)

b

2

= + (142)

d

j

= q

('i b

j )

2

2

(2u

j

'i ' 2

) (143)

g

j

= b

j

'i+d

j

b

j

'i d

j

(144)

= T t (145)

D

j (;')

= b

j

'i+d

j

2

"

1 e d

j

1 g

j e

d

j

#

(146)

C

j (;')

= (r q)'i

+ a

2

(

(b

j

'i+d) 2ln

"

1 g

j e

d

j

1 e d

j

# )

(147)

f

j

(x;v;t;')

= e C

j (;')+D

j

(;')v+i'x

(148)

P

j

(x;v;;y)

= 1

2 +

1

Z

1

0

<

"

e i'y

f

j

(x;v;;')

i'

#

d' (149)

p

j

(x;v;;y)

= 1

Z

1

0

<

h

e i'y

f

j

(x;v;;') i

d' (150)

P

+ ()

=

1

2

+P

1 (lnS

t

;v

t

;;lnK) (151)

P ()

=

1

2

+P

2 (lnS

t

;v

t

;;lnK) (152)

This notation is motivated by the fact that the numbers P

j

are the cumulative

distribution functions (inthe variable y) of the log-spotprice after time starting

atx for some drift. The numbers p

j

are the respective densities.

6.2.2 Value

The value function for European vanillaoptions isgiven by

V = h

e q

S

t P

+

() Ke

r

P () i

(153)

(23)

The probabilitiesP

() correspond to N(d

) inthe constant volatilitycase.

6.2.3 Greeks

Weuse thehomogeneityofprices, toobtainthe deltas. Butwemust show, thatthe

priceis given in itsnaturalrepresentation. Sowe use the following strategy.

We assume, that equation (153) gives the natural price representation, which is

dened inappendix A. Under this assumptionwe can read othe deltas, and from

the deltas we derive the gammas. Using Theorem 8 we show that the assumption

of (153)giving the naturalprice representation was correct.

Spot delta.

=

@V

@S

t

=e q

P

+

() (154)

Dual delta.

K

=

@V

@K

= e

r

P () (155)

Gamma. Under the condition, that the deltas are correct, we obtain for the gam-

mas by dierentiation:

Spot Gamma.

=

@

@S

t

=

@

@x

@x

@S

t

= e

q

S

t p

1 (lnS

t

;v

t

;;lnK) (156)

Dual Gamma.

K

=

@ K

@K

=

@ K

@y

@y

@K

= e

r

K p

1 (lnS

t

;v

t

;;lnK) (157)

Proof of the natural representation assumption >FromTheorem8weknow,

that our initialguess forthe deltasis correct, if the relation

S 2

t

= K

2 K

(158)

holds. In fact, this equation isgiven by

S

t e

q

p

1 (lnS

t

;v

t

;;lnK)=Ke r

p

2 (lnS

t

;v

t

;;lnK); (159)

and this statement is true. Soour calculation for the deltas and gammas has

been nished.

(24)

@V

@r

=Ke r

P (); (160)

@V

@q

= S

t e

q

P

+

(): (161)

Theta. ThetacanbecomputedusingthepartialdierentialequationfortheHeston

vanilla option

V

t

+(r q)SV

S +

1

2 vV

vv +

1

2 vS

2

V

SS

+vSV

vS qV

+[( v) ]V

v

=0; (162)

where the derivatives with respect to initial variance v must be evaluated

numerically.

7 Summary

Wehave learnedhowto employ homogeneity-based methodsto compute analytical

formulas of Greeks for analytically known value functions of options in a one-and

higher-dimensional market. Restricting the view to the Black-Scholes model there

are numerous further relations between various Greeks which are of fundamental

interest. Themethodhelpssavingcomputationtimeforthemathematicianwhohas

todierentiatecomplicatedformulasaswellasforthecomputer, becauseanalytical

results for Greeks are usually faster to evaluate than nite dierences involving at

least twice the computation of the option's value. Knowing how the Greeks are

related among each other can speed up nite-dierence-, tree-, or Monte Carlo-

based computation of Greeks or lead at least to a quality check. Many of the

results are validbeyond the Black-Scholes model. Mostremarkably some relations

oftheGreeksarebasedonpropertiesofthenormaldistributionrefreshingtheactive

interplay between mathematicsand nancialmarkets.

A The Natural Price Representation for Homoge-

neous Options

Weanalyze the followingproblem. Letv(x;k)bethe value ofanoptionand v(x;k)

ishomogeneous of degree1. After Evaluatingthe integral to determine the option-

price,one obtainsthe following formula:

v(x;k) = xf(x;k)+kg(x;k) (163)

One the other hand,weknowfrom the homogeneity of v:

v(x;k) = xv

x

(x;k)+kv

k

(x;k) (164)

(25)

x y

answer is: No, not in general.

Because of v being homogeneous of degree 1 we know, that f(x;k),g(x;k),v

x (x;k)

and v

k

(x;k) are homogeneous of degree 0. Therefore we know that f(x;k) has the

representation f(

x

k

) and so on. Introducing the notation u= x

k

we nd from (163)

and (164) that

uf(u)+g(u) = uv

x

(u)+v

y

(u) (165)

We dene h(u)=v

x

(u) f(u). The answer to the question above would be yes, if

and only if h(u)=0 for all u. One can easilyshow, that the function h(u)has the

following properties:

lim

u!0

h(u) = 0 (166)

lim

u!1

h(u) = 0 (167)

h(u) = uf 0

(u)+g 0

(u) (168)

Sowe come tothe followingdenition:

Denition 2 (Natural Representation of Homogeneous Functions)

Let v(x;k) be a homogeneousfunctionof degree 1. Thenthere is a unique represen-

tation

v(x;k) = xf

x

k

+kg

x

k

with (169)

0 = uf 0

(u)+g 0

(u) (170)

We callthis the naturalrepresentation.

Of course, the denition of the natural representation can be extended to higher

dimensions. The question of this section can now be answered more exactly. One

can read o the deltas if and only if the price formula isgiven in its natural repre-

sentation. This statement alsoholdsinhigherdimensions. Forthe two dimensional

case, wesummarize:

Theorem 8 Let v(x;k) be a homogeneousfunction of degree 1. Therepresentation

v(x;k) = xf(x;k)+kg(x;k) (171)

isthe natural representation if and only if

x 2

@

x

f(x;k) = k 2

@

k

g(x;k) (172)

Theorem 9 Let v(x;k) = xf(x;k)+kg(x;k) be the natural representation of a

homogeneous function of degree 1. Then the followingequations hold:

@

x

v(x;k) = f(x;k) (173)

@

k

v(x;k) = g(x;k) (174)

(26)

[1] COX, J.C., INGERSOLL, J.E.and ROSS, S.A.(1985). A Theory of the Term

Structure of Interest Rates. Econometrica 53, 385-407.

[2] HESTON, S. (1993). A Closed-Form Solution for Options with Stochastic

Volatility with Applications to Bond and Currency Options. The Review of

FinancialStudies, Vol. 6, No.2.

[3] PLACKETT, R. L. (1954).A Reduction Formulafor Normal MultivariateIn-

tegrals.Biometrika. 41, pp. 351-360.

[4] SHAW, W. (1998). Modelling Financial Derivatives with Mathematica. Cam-

bridgeUniversity Press.

[5] STULZ,R.(1982).OptionsontheMinimumorMaximumofTwoAssets.Jour-

nal of Financial Economics.10, pp. 161-185.

[6] TALEB, N. (1996). DynamicHedging. Wiley, New York.

[7] WYSTUP, U. (1999). Vanilla Options. Formula Catalogue of

http://www.MathFinance.de.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

(c) Asian call, Black-Scholes model, = 1.0: Variance reduction factor on a logarithmic scale for an arithmetic Asian call in the Black-Scholes model achieved by importance

meteorite contains C-rich material at some individual measurement po- sitions. The other points can be identi fi ed as a mixture of melilite and albite. 6d) show that the

The argument that bilateral defence cooperation on one of the most sensitive and important front-end military capabilities would somehow lock Australia into a de facto

The known option mispricing puzzle states that mean realized option returns could not be fully explained by standard option pricing models in perfect markets due to extreme

(Are there other important elements? Are these compounds of other things more easily measured?) Note particularly that for given prices of other factors, a given price for deli-

For example, over the period 1986-2012, a test of a linear factor model with the S&amp;P 500 Index as the sole factor on the cross-section of daily- rebalanced index option

A query execution plan (QEP) is a well-formed and executable physical query plan, modeled as a graph, that accepts in input chunks of tuples and control messages, denoted by means

Keywords: Lévy-Processes, estimation of the Greeks, Measure Valued Dierentiation, exotic options, Lookback option, Asian options.. 1 University of Vienna, Department of Statistics