• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

ROBUSTNESS CHECKS Table 1.8. Electoral cycle

(1) (2) (3)

School Reforms Teacher Reforms Student Reforms

VARIABLES Access Quality Access Quality Access Quality

Union Expenditures (in millions)

Lobbying 0.0682 -0.318*** -0.0110 -0.0865 -0.0223 -0.119

(0.0436) (0.117) (0.0216) (0.0779) (0.136) (0.0838) Contributions, Gifts & Grants -0.0109 -1.505** 0.222* -1.032** 1.339* -0.0452

(0.232) (0.623) (0.115) (0.414) (0.724) (0.445) Representational Activities 0.0225 0.341*** -0.00594 0.198** -0.195 0.0722 (0.0491) (0.132) (0.0244) (0.0877) (0.154) (0.0944)

First year of term 0.0753 0.188 0.246** 0.0882 0.455 0.335

(0.236) (0.635) (0.117) (0.421) (0.738) (0.453)

Second year of term 0.0414 -0.108 0.0296 -0.472* -0.00225 0.594**

(0.141) (0.381) (0.0701) (0.253) (0.442) (0.272)

Third year of term -0.0453 -0.794 0.181 0.173 0.350 0.408

(0.254) (0.684) (0.126) (0.454) (0.795) (0.488)

Observations 179 179 179 179 179 179

R-squared 0.517 0.841 0.396 0.663 0.897 0.653

Notes: All regressions include a constant, year and state fixed effects, political and economic variables and other demographic and education controls. Standard errors in parentheses. ***p <0.01, **p <0.05, *p <0.1

Table 1.6 presents the results of this robustness check. One observation is that the significances are reduced, particularly for the coefficients of contributions, divided government and term limits, suggesting that these variables may have an influence on the mere mention of reforms in legislation. Nevertheless, after correcting for directional differences in policy, the most interesting findings pull through. We find a cleaner result for the influence motive, that is, contributions affect only teacher reforms, which yielddirectbenefits, while lobbying affects only school reforms, which yieldindirectbenefits. The educational crisis effect, yielding a negative estimate of math scores in Model 3, and the policy momentum effect, yielding a positive estimate of math scores in Model 1, survive the correction.

A third robustness check would be to test whether the results are robust to other measures of teachers’ union strength, in particular, union membership. In Table 1.7 we regress the same specification as presented in equations (1.1) and (1.2), but instead of union expenditures, we use the number of voting union members as a proportion of public school teachers in the state.

We consider only members of the AFT and the NEA, the two largest teachers’ unions in the U.S. Interestingly, the only reforms union membership has an effect on are the ones that have a direct impact on teachers. The data reveal that union membership influences only teacher quality reforms, the sign being negative. The fact that membership is found to affect only quality reforms is in line with Segal et al. (1992) and Kang’s (2016) finding that support for a reform has a weaker effect than opposition to a reform.

Next we check the robustness of our results to the fluctuations in the electoral cycle. To this

end we add to the baseline regressions dummy variables for the years within an electoral term.

The base year for these dummy variables is the election year. Table 1.8 produces the estimation results for this test. The point estimates for electoral term dummies reveal an increase in teacher access reforms in the first year of mandate. We also find a positive and significant effect on student quality reforms on the second year of the term, suggesting that politicians only manage to enact quality reforms once the dust from elections has settled. The main results regarding union expenditures survive the inclusion of these electoral term variables.

Table 1.9. Fiscal position

(1) (2) (3)

School Reforms Teacher Reforms Student Reforms

VARIABLES Access Quality Access Quality Access Quality

Union Expenditures (in millions)

Lobbying 0.0694 -0.359*** 0.000852 -0.0641 -0.0173 -0.147

(0.0455) (0.127) (0.0234) (0.0847) (0.144) (0.0913) Contributions, Gifts & Grants 0.134 -1.281** 0.241** -1.084** 1.047 0.0423

(0.228) (0.639) (0.118) (0.425) (0.724) (0.458) Representational Activities -0.0456 0.285** -0.0213 0.188** -0.0497 0.0741 (0.0509) (0.142) (0.0262) (0.0947) (0.161) (0.102) State tax revenues (in billions) 0.0329 -0.0543 0.0163 0.0323 -0.0821 -0.0301 (0.0220) (0.0615) (0.0113) (0.0409) (0.0697) (0.0441) State outstanding debt (in billions) 0.0448** 0.0781 -0.000189 -0.00446 -0.104* 0.0103

(0.0180) (0.0505) (0.00929) (0.0336) (0.0572) (0.0362)

Observations 179 179 179 179 179 179

R-squared 0.546 0.838 0.388 0.656 0.901 0.645

Notes: All regressions include a constant, year and state fixed effects, political and economic variables and other demographic and education controls. Standard errors in parentheses. *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1

The final robustness check explores whether our results are subject to variations in the fiscal position of state governments. Since access reforms are more expensive for the government to implement than quality reforms, taxation and debt may matter for their enactment. We check this by adding to the base regressions variables for state tax revenues and state outstanding debt, both measured in 2009 dollars.

Table 1.9 presents the results of this exercise, revealing that debt indeed plays a role for certain types of education reforms. Government debt correlates positively with school access reforms and negatively with student access reforms, suggesting that a substitution occurs between student and school access reforms. Note that examples of student access reforms include providing student scholarships. Such reforms impose spending obligations on the government that have longer terms than school access reforms, which provide, say, improvements in school infrastructure.

Since government debt is highly persistent, high outstanding debt urges governments to enact less long-term, and more short-term access reforms. Regardless of this effect, the coefficients on union expenditures on education reforms remain unchanged.

1.10. CONCLUSIONS

1.10 Conclusions

This study identifies the factors affecting the enactment of primary and secondary public edu-cation reform proposals, and disaggregates eduedu-cation reforms into two general reform types:

access reformsthat aim at broadening the coverage of education andquality reformsthat aim at improving the effectiveness and productivity of education.

We find that the number of enacted quality and access reforms responds differently to various political-economic factors. For instance, both student quality reforms respond positively to times of deteriorating education outcomes. The data also suggests that there is some policy momen-tum in school-related access and quality policies. That is, improved educational performance encourages politicians to improve school infrastructure as well as enact more school choice reforms.

This study also finds evidence for the fact that teachers’ union strength correlates positively with access reforms and negatively with quality reforms. This is the first study that provides empirical support for the differential effect of teachers’ unions on access and quality reforms.

The results moreover elucidate the inner workings of the teachers unions, distinguishing the political activities that have the strongest effects on reforms. Both lobbying and contributions are effective at opposing school quality reforms, while only contributions are effective at influencing teacher reforms. This finding aligns with the “influence motive” emphasized by the campaign contributions literature. Contributions of an interest group affect only the policies that directly serve the group’s interest. These main results are robust to simultaneity, different measures of the reform and union variables, and variations to the political cycle and the fiscal environment.

A puzzling finding of this study is the positive correlation between union representational activities, which involve collective bargaining and contract negotiations, and the number of enacted quality reforms. One avenue for further research would be to explore the mechanisms behind this relationship in more detail. Another possible extension could be to address the inability of our reform data to distinguish between progressive or regressive policy changes within access or quality reforms. Counting the number of bills containing quality- or access-related terms in their summary effectively considers as equivalent the bills that, say, allow more charter schools and the bills that limit the number of charter schools. Since such subtleties have differential effects on the behavior of interest groups, an interesting refinement would be to take these distinctions into account.

References

Abler, D. G. (1991). Campaign Contributions and House Voting on Sugar and Dairy Legislation.

American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 73(1):11–17.

Access (2014). In Abbott, S., editor,Glossary of Education Reforms.

Ansolabehere, S., Snyder, J. M., and Tripathi, M. (2002). Are PAC contributions and lob-bying linked? New evidence from the 1995 Lobby Disclosure Act. Business and Politics, 4(2):131–155.

Anzia, S. F. and Moe, T. M. (2014). Collective Bargaining, Transfer Rights, and Disadvantaged Schools. Educational Evaluation and Policy Analysis, 36(1):83–111.

Bernecker, A. (2014). Divided We Reform? Evidence From US Welfare Policies. CESifo Working Paper Series No. 4564.

Besley, T. and Case, A. (1995). Does Electoral Accountability Affect Economic Policy Choices?

Evidence from Gubernatorial Term Limits. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3):769–

98.

Bonesrønning, H. (2013). Public Employees and Public Sector Reform Implementation. Public Choice, 156(1-2):309–327.

Braga, M., Checchi, D., and Meschi, E. (2013). Educational policies in a long-run perspective.

Economic Policy, 28(73):45–100.

Bureau of Economic Analysis (2014). Regional Economic Accounts.

Congressional Research Service Specialists and Analysts (2007). K-12 Education: Highlights of the No Child Left Behind Act of 2001 (P.L. 107-110). In Olivert, D. P., editor,No child left behind act: Text, interpretation and changes. Novia Science Publishers, Inc.

Corrales, J. (1999). The politics of education reform: Bolstering the supply and demand;

Overcoming institutional blocks. InThe Education Reform and Management Series, volume 2.

World Bank.

Coughlin, P. J., Mueler, D. C., and Murrell, P. (1990). Electoral politics, interest groups, and the size of government. Economic Inquiry, 28(4):682–705.

Council of State Governments (2014). Book of the States 2008-2013.

Democrats for Educational Reform (2015). What we stand for. Retrieved from:

http://dfer.org/about-us/what-we-stand-for/.

REFERENCES Drazen, A. and Grilli, V. (1993). The Benefit of Crises for Economic Reforms. The American

Economic Review, 83(3):598–607.

Dreher, A., Lamla, M. J., Lein, S. M., and Somogyi, F. (2009). The impact of political leaders’

profession and education on reforms. Journal of Comparative Economics, 37(1):169 – 193.

Epstein, G. S. and Nitzan, S. (2004). Strategic restraint in contests. European Economic Review, 48(1):201–210.

Gitlin, A. and Margonis, F. (1995). The Political Aspect of Reform: Teacher Resistance as Good Sense. American Journal of Education, 103(4):377–405.

Glewwe, P. W., Hanushek, E. A., Humpage, S. D., and Ravina, R. (2011). School resources and educational outcomes in developing countries: A review of the literature from 1990 to 2010.

NBER Working Paper No. 17554.

Grasse, N. and Heidbreder, B. (2011). The Influence of Lobbying Activity in State Legislatures:

Evidence from Wisconsin. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 36(4):567–589.

Grindle, M. S. (2004).Despite the odds: The contentious politics of education reform. Princeton University Press.

Grossman, G. M. and Helpman, E. (1996). Electoral Competition and Special Interest Politics.

The Review of Economic Studies, 63(2):265–286.

Haas, K. H. (2013). Statistics of the presidential and congressional election of November 6, 2012. Technical report, Clerk of the House of Representatives.

Holyoke, T. T., Henig, J. R., Brown, H., and Lacireno-Paquet, N. (2009). Policy dynamics and the evolution of state charter school laws. Policy Sciences, 42(1):33–55.

Hoxby, C. M. (1996). How teachers’ unions affect education production. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(3):671–718.

Hoxby, C. M. (1999). The Effects of School Choice in Curriculum and Atmosphere. In Mayer, S. E. and Peterson, P. E., editors, Earning and learning: How schools matter, chapter 11, pages 281–316. Brookings Institution Press.

Hoxby, C. M. (2000). Does competition among public schools benefit student and taxpayers?

American Economic Review, 90(5):1209–1238.

Hoxby, C. M. (2002). Would school choice change the teaching profession? The Journal of Human Resources, 37(4):846–891.

Hoyt, W. H. and Toma, E. F. (1993). Lobbying Expenditures and Government Output: The NEA and Public Education. Southern Economic Journal, 60(2):405–417.

Huberman, A. M. and Miles, M. B. (1984). Innovation up close: How school improvement works. Springer Science & Business Media, New York.

Jennings, C. (2015). Collective choice and individual action: Education policy and social mobility in England. European Journal of Political Economy, 40(B):288–297.

Kang, K. (2016). Policy influence and private returns from lobbying in the energy sector.

Working paper. Review of Economic Studies, 83(1):269–305.

Lake, J. (2015). Revisiting the link between {PAC} contributions and lobbying expenditures.

European Journal of Political Economy, 37:86–101.

List, J. A. and Sturm, D. M. (2006). How Elections Matter: Theory and Evidence from Environmental Policy. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4):1249–1281.

Meltzer, A. H. and Richard, S. F. (1981). A Rational Theory of the Size of the Government.

Journal of Political Economy.

Merzyn, W. and Ursprung, H. W. (2005). Voter support for privatizing education: evidence on self-interest and ideology. European Journal of Political Economy, 21(1):33–58.

Mintrom, M. (2000). Policy entrepreneurs and school choice. Georgetown University Press.

Mintrom, M. and Vergari, S. (1998). Policy Networks and Innovation Diffusion: The Case of State Education Reforms. The Journal of Politics, 60:126–148.

Moe, T. M. (2006). Bottom-up Structure: Collective Bargaining, Transfer Rights, and the Plight of Disadvantaged Schools. Education Working Paper Archive. Department of Education Reform, University of Arkansas.

Moe, T. M. (2012). Teachers Unions and American Education Reform: The Politics of Blocking.

The Forum, 10(1).

Murnane, R. J. and Ganimian, A. J. (2014). Improving educational outcomes in developing countries: Lessons from rigorous evaluations. NBER Working Paper No. 20284.

National Center for Education Statistics (2013). Education bill tracking database.

National Conference of State Legislatures (2014). Education bill tracking database.

National Governors Association (2014). Governors’ rosters 2006-2013.

REFERENCES Office of Labor-Management Standards (2015). Online public disclosure room.

Olson, M. (1965). The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups.

Harvard University Press.

Potters, J. and Sloof, R. (1996). Interest groups: A survey of empirical models that try to assess their influence. European Journal of Political Economy, 12:403–442.

Rodrik, D. (1992). The Rush to Free Trade in the Developing World: Why So Late? Why Now? Will it Last? NBER Working Papers 3947, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. NBER Working Paper No. 3947.

Sarason, S. B. (1977). A "cultural" limitation of system approaches to educational reform.

American Journal of Community Psychology, 5(3):277–287.

Schneider, K., Schuchart, C., Weishaupt, H., and Riedel, A. (2012). The effect of free primary school choice on ethnic groups: Evidence from a policy reform. European Journal of Political Economy, 28(4):430 – 444.

Segal, J. A., Cameron, C. M., and Cover, A. D. (1992). A spatial model of roll call voting: Sena-tors, constituents, presidents, and interest groups in Supreme Court confirmations. American Journal of Political Science, 36(1).

Sherfinski, D. (2014). Inner-city Democrats warm to school choice as rural Republicans balk.

The Washington Times.

Smith, F. J. (1913). The Evolution of the Motion Picture: VI – Looking into the Future with Thomas A. Edison. The New York Dramatic Mirror, page 24.

Snyder, J. M. (1990). Campaign contributions as investments: The U.S. House of Representatives, 1980-1986. Journal of Political Economy, 98:1195–1227.

Snyder, J. M. (1992). Long-term investing in politicians: Or, give early, give often. Journal of Law and Economics, 35:15–43.

Snyder, J. M. (1993). The market for campaign contributions: Evidence from the U.S. Senate 1980-1986. Economics & Politics, 5(3):219–240.

Stratmann, T. (1991). What Do Campaign Contributions Buy? Deciphering Causal Effects of Money and Votes. Southern Economic Journal, 57(3):606–620.

Stratmann, T. (2005). Some talk: Money in politics. A (partial) review of the literature. Public Choice, 124:135–156.

Strauss, V. (2012). Questions Democrats must answer on school choice. The Washington Post.

Tommasi, M. and Velasco, A. (1996). Where are we in the political economy of reform? The Journal of Policy Reform, 1(2):187–238.

Tsebelis, G. (1995). Decision Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism and Multipartyism. British Journal of Political Science, 25:289–325.

Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.

Tyack, D. and Tobin, W. (1994). The "Grammar" of Schooling: Why Has It Been So Hard to Change? American Educational Research Journal, 31(3):453–479.

U.S. Census Bureau (2012). Statistical abstract of the United States: 2012 (131st Edition).

Technical report, U.S. Census Bureau, Washington, D.C.

U.S. Census Bureau (2013). Annual Survey of State Governments. Technical report, U.S. Census Bureau.

U.S. Census Bureau, Population Division (2014). Annual Estimates of the Resident Population by Sex, Race, and Hispanic Origin for the United States, States, and Counties: April 1, 2010 to July 1, 2013. Technical report, U.S. Census Bureau, Population Division.

U.S. Department of Education (2009). Race to the top executive summary. Technical report, U.S. Department of Education.

U.S. Department of Education (2010). Ed Recovery Plan. Technical report, U.S. Department of Education.

U.S. Department of Education (2013). The threat of educational stagnation and complacency:

Remarks of the U.S. Secretary of Education Arne Duncan at the release of the 2012 Programme for International Student Assessment (PISA).

U.S. Department of Education (2014). Race to the top fund.

Wiese, R. (2014). What triggers reforms in OECD countries? Improved reform measurement and evidence from the healthcare sector. European Journal of Political Economy, 34:332–352.

Wong, K. K. and Shen, F. X. (2002). Politics of state-led reform in education: Market competition and electoral dynamics. Educational Policy, 16(1):161–192.

Wright, J. R. (1990). Contributions, lobbying, and committee voting in the U.S. House of Representatives. The American Political Science Review, 84(2):417–438.