• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Abler, D. G. (1991). Campaign Contributions and House Voting on Sugar and Dairy Legislation.

American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 73(1):11–17.

Access (2014). In Abbott, S., editor,Glossary of Education Reforms.

Albert, A. and Anderson, J. A. (1984). On the existence of maximum likelihood estimates in logistic regression models. Biometrika, 71(1):1–10.

Alesina, A., Baqir, R., and Easterly, W. (1999). Public goods and ethnic divisions. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114:1243–1284.

Alesina, A. and Giuliano, P. (2010). Preferences for redistribution. In Benhabib, J., Jackson, M. O., and Bisin, A., editors,Handbook of Social Economics, pages 93–131. The Netherlands:

North Holland.

Alesina, A. and La Ferrara, E. (2005). Preferences for redistribution in the land of opportunities.

Journal of Public Economics, 89:897– 931.

Alesina, A., Stantcheva, S., and Teso, E. (2017). Intergenerational mobility and support for redistribution. Technical report, National Bureau of Economic Research. Working Paper 23027.

American Community Survey (2016). 3-Year Estimates.

Ansolabehere, S., Snyder, J. M., and Tripathi, M. (2002). Are PAC contributions and lob-bying linked? New evidence from the 1995 Lobby Disclosure Act. Business and Politics, 4(2):131–155.

Anzia, S. F. and Moe, T. M. (2014). Collective Bargaining, Transfer Rights, and Disadvantaged Schools. Educational Evaluation and Policy Analysis, 36(1):83–111.

Becker, G. S. (1983). A Theory of Competition Among Pressure Groups for Political Influence.

The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98(3):371–400.

Bellani, L. and Scervini, F. (2015). Heterogeneous preferences and in-kind redistribution: Theory and evidence. European Economic Review, 78:196 – 219.

Bellani, L. and Ursprung, H. W. (2016). The political economy of redistribution policy. WP 6189, CESifo.

Benabou, R. and Ok, E. A. (2001). Social Mobility and the Demand for Redistribution: The POUM Hypothesis. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(2):447–487.

COMPLETE BIBLIOGRAPHY Bernasconi, M. and Profeta, P. (2012). Public education and redistribution when talents are

mismatched. European Economic Review, 56(1):84 – 96.

Bernecker, A. (2014). Divided We Reform? Evidence From US Welfare Policies. CESifo Working Paper Series No. 4564.

Berthold, M. R., Cebron, N., Dill, F., Gabriel, T. R., Kötter, T., Meinl, T., Ohl, P., Sieb, C., Thiel, K., and Wiswedel, B. (2007). KNIME: The Konstanz Information Miner. InStudies in Classification, Data Analysis, and Knowledge Organization (GfKL 2007). Springer.

Besley, T. and Case, A. (1995). Does Electoral Accountability Affect Economic Policy Choices?

Evidence from Gubernatorial Term Limits. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3):769–

98.

Bonesrønning, H. (2013). Public Employees and Public Sector Reform Implementation. Public Choice, 156(1-2):309–327.

Borck, R. (2007). Voting, inequality and redistribution. Journal of Economic Surveys, 21(1):90–

109.

Braga, M., Checchi, D., and Meschi, E. (2013). Educational policies in a long-run perspective.

Economic Policy, 28(73):45–100.

Bureau of Economic Analysis (2014). Regional Economic Accounts.

Bureau of Labor Statistics (2017). Local area unemployment statistics. Published online.

California Department of Education (2016). Staff Data Files.

California State Legislature (2016). Bill Information Archives.

Chaturvedi, A. and Glazer, A. (2005). Competitive proposals of policies by lobbies. Mimeo.

Checchi, D. and Filippin, A. (2004). An experimental study of the POUM hypothesis. In Cowell, F., editor,Inequality, Welfare and Income Distribution: Experimental Approaches (Research on Economic Inequality, Volume 11), pages 115–136. Emerald Group Publishing Limited.

Chetty, R., Hendren, N., Kline, P., and Saez, E. (2014a). Where is the land of opportunity? The geography of intergenerational mobility in the United States. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129(4).

Chetty, R., Hendren, N., Kline, P., Saez, E., and Turner, N. (2014b). Is the United States still a land of opportunity? Recent trends in Intergenerational mobility. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 104(5):141–147.

Congressional Research Service Specialists and Analysts (2007). K-12 Education: Highlights of the No Child Left Behind Act of 2001 (P.L. 107-110). In Olivert, D. P., editor,No child left behind act: Text, interpretation and changes. Novia Science Publishers, Inc.

Corneo, G. and Gruener, H. P. (2002). Individual preferences for political redistribution. Journal of Public Economics, 83(1):83 – 107.

Corrales, J. (1999). The politics of education reform: Bolstering the supply and demand;

Overcoming institutional blocks. InThe Education Reform and Management Series, volume 2.

World Bank.

Cotton, C. and Dellis, A. (2016). Information lobbying and agenda distortion. Queen’s Economics Department Working Paper No. 1348.

Coughlin, P. J., Mueler, D. C., and Murrell, P. (1990). Electoral politics, interest groups, and the size of government. Economic Inquiry, 28(4):682–705.

Council of State Governments (2014). Book of the States 2008-2013.

Danziger, L. and Ursprung, H. W. (2001). Risk Aversion and Social Mobility: The Implausibility of Order-Preserving Income Redistributions. Economics Letters, 71:9–13.

De Donder, P., Le Breton, M., and Peluso, E. (2012). Majority voting in multidimensional policy spaces: Kramer-Shepsle versus Stackelberg. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 14:pp.

879�909.

Democrats for Educational Reform (2015). What we stand for. Retrieved from:

http://dfer.org/about-us/what-we-stand-for/.

Desmet, K., Weber, S., and Ortuño Ortín, I. (2009). Linguistic diversity and redistribution.

Journal of the European Economic Association, 7(6):1291–1318.

Drazen, A. and Grilli, V. (1993). The Benefit of Crises for Economic Reforms. The American Economic Review, 83(3):598–607.

Dreher, A., Lamla, M. J., Lein, S. M., and Somogyi, F. (2009). The impact of political leaders’

profession and education on reforms. Journal of Comparative Economics, 37(1):169 – 193.

Epstein, G. S. and Hefeker, C. (2003). Lobbying contests with alternative instruments.Economics of Governance, 4(1):81–89.

Epstein, G. S. and Nitzan, S. (2004). Strategic restraint in contests. European Economic Review, 48(1):201–210.

COMPLETE BIBLIOGRAPHY Epstein, G. S. and Nitzan, S. (2006a). Lobbying and compromise. Public Choice, 126:317–330.

Epstein, G. S. and Nitzan, S. (2006b). The politics of randomness. Social Choice and Welfare, 27:423–433.

Fabella, V. M. (2016). Political-economic determinants of education reform: Evidence on interest groups and student outcomes. European Journal of Political Economy. Forthcoming.

Felli, L. and Merlo, A. (2006). Endogenous Lobbying. Journal of the European Economic Association, 4(1):180–215.

Finger, L. (2016). Understanding Interest Group Influence: Teachers’ Unions and Education Reform Policymaking. Mimeo.

Gaviria, A., Graham, C., and Braido, L. H. B. (2007). Social mobility and preferences for redistribution in Latin America [with Comments]. Economica, 8(1):55–96.

Gitlin, A. and Margonis, F. (1995). The Political Aspect of Reform: Teacher Resistance as Good Sense. American Journal of Education, 103(4):377–405.

Glazer, A., Gradstein, M., and Konrad, K. A. (1998). The electoral politics of extreme policies.

The Economic Journal, 108(November):1677–1685.

Glewwe, P. W., Hanushek, E. A., Humpage, S. D., and Ravina, R. (2011). School resources and educational outcomes in developing countries: A review of the literature from 1990 to 2010.

NBER Working Paper No. 17554.

Grasse, N. and Heidbreder, B. (2011). The Influence of Lobbying Activity in State Legislatures:

Evidence from Wisconsin. Legislative Studies Quarterly, 36(4):567–589.

Grindle, M. S. (2004).Despite the odds: The contentious politics of education reform. Princeton University Press.

Grossman, G. M. and Helpman, E. (1996). Electoral Competition and Special Interest Politics.

The Review of Economic Studies, 63(2):265–286.

Guillaud, E. (2013). Preferences for redistribution: An empirical analysis over 33 countries. The Journal of Economic Inequality.

Haas, K. H. (2013). Statistics of the presidential and congressional election of November 6, 2012. Technical report, Clerk of the House of Representatives.

Hillman, A. L. and Ursprung, H. W. (1988). Domestic Politics, Foreign Interests, and Interna-tional Trade Policy. The American Economic Review, 78(4):729–745.

Hirschman, A. O. (1973). The Changing Tolerance for Income Inequality in the Course of Eco-nomic Development (with a Mathematical Appendix by Michael Rothschild). The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 87(4):544–566.

Holyoke, T. T., Henig, J. R., Brown, H., and Lacireno-Paquet, N. (2009). Policy dynamics and the evolution of state charter school laws. Policy Sciences, 42(1):33–55.

Horrace, W. C. and Oaxaca, R. L. (2006). Results on the bias and inconsistency of ordinary least squares for the linear probability model. Economics Letters, 90:321–327.

Hoxby, C. M. (1996). How teachers’ unions affect education production. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(3):671–718.

Hoxby, C. M. (1999). The Effects of School Choice in Curriculum and Atmosphere. In Mayer, S. E. and Peterson, P. E., editors, Earning and learning: How schools matter, chapter 11, pages 281–316. Brookings Institution Press.

Hoxby, C. M. (2000). Does competition among public schools benefit student and taxpayers?

American Economic Review, 90(5):1209–1238.

Hoxby, C. M. (2002). Would school choice change the teaching profession? The Journal of Human Resources, 37(4):846–891.

Hoyt, W. H. and Toma, E. F. (1993). Lobbying Expenditures and Government Output: The NEA and Public Education. Southern Economic Journal, 60(2):405–417.

Huberman, A. M. and Miles, M. B. (1984). Innovation up close: How school improvement works. Springer Science & Business Media, New York.

Jennings, C. (2015). Collective choice and individual action: Education policy and social mobility in England. European Journal of Political Economy, 40(B):288–297.

Kang, K. (2014). Policy influence and private returns from lobbying in the energy sector. Mimeo.

Kang, K. (2016). Policy influence and private returns from lobbying in the energy sector.

Working paper. Review of Economic Studies, 83(1):269–305.

Klarner, C., Berry, W. D., Carsey, T., Jewell, M., Niemi, R., Powell, L., and Snyder, J. (2013).

State legislative election returns (1967-2010) ICPSR34297-v1.

Lake, J. (2015). Revisiting the link between {PAC} contributions and lobbying expenditures.

European Journal of Political Economy, 37:86–101.

COMPLETE BIBLIOGRAPHY Lind, J. T. (2007). Does permanent income determine the vote? The B.E. Journal of

Macroeco-nomics, 7(1).

Lindbeck, A. and Weibull, J. W. (1987). Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition. Public Choice, 52(3):273–297.

List, J. A. and Sturm, D. M. (2006). How Elections Matter: Theory and Evidence from Environmental Policy. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(4):1249–1281.

McKelvey, R. D. (1976). Intransitivities in multidimensional voting models and some implica-tions for agenda control. Journal of Economic Theory, 12(3):472 – 482.

McKelvey, R. D. and Patty, J. W. (2006). A theory of voting in large elections. Games and Economic Behavior, 57(1):155 – 180.

Meltzer, A. H. and Richard, S. F. (1981). A Rational Theory of the Size of the Government.

Journal of Political Economy.

Merzyn, W. and Ursprung, H. W. (2005). Voter support for privatizing education: evidence on self-interest and ideology. European Journal of Political Economy, 21(1):33–58.

Mintrom, M. (2000). Policy entrepreneurs and school choice. Georgetown University Press.

Mintrom, M. and Vergari, S. (1998). Policy Networks and Innovation Diffusion: The Case of State Education Reforms. The Journal of Politics, 60:126–148.

Münster, J. (2006). Lobbying contests with endogenous policy proposals. Economics & Politics, 18(3):389–397.

Moe, T. M. (2006). Bottom-up Structure: Collective Bargaining, Transfer Rights, and the Plight of Disadvantaged Schools. Education Working Paper Archive. Department of Education Reform, University of Arkansas.

Moe, T. M. (2012). Teachers Unions and American Education Reform: The Politics of Blocking.

The Forum, 10(1).

Murnane, R. J. and Ganimian, A. J. (2014). Improving educational outcomes in developing countries: Lessons from rigorous evaluations. NBER Working Paper No. 20284.

National Center for Education Statistics (2013). Education bill tracking database.

National Center for Education Statistics (2016). Common core data.

National Conference of State Legislatures (2014). Education bill tracking database.

National Governors Association (2014). Governors’ rosters 2006-2013.

OECD (2017). Public spending on education. DOI: 10.1787/6932ce5c-en. Accessed 07 May 2017.

Office of Labor-Management Standards (2015). Online public disclosure room.

Okun, A. M. (1975). Equality and Efficiency: The Big Tradeoff. The Brookings Institution, Washington, DC.

Olson, M. (1965). The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups.

Harvard University Press.

Persson, T. and Tabellini, G. (2000). Political economics: Explaining economic policies. The MIT Press.

Piketty, T. (1995). Social Mobility and Redistributive Politics. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3):551–584.

Piketty, T. (2014). Capital in the 21st Century. Harvard University Press.

Potters, J. and Sloof, R. (1996). Interest groups: A survey of empirical models that try to assess their influence. European Journal of Political Economy, 12:403–442.

Rainer, H. and Siedler, T. (2008). Subjective income and employment expectations and prefer-ences for redistribution. Economics Letters, 99:449–453.

Ravallion, M. and Lokshin, M. (2000). Who wants to redistribute? The tunnel effect in 1990s Russia. Journal of Public Economics, 76:87–104.

Rodrik, D. (1992). The Rush to Free Trade in the Developing World: Why So Late? Why Now? Will it Last? NBER Working Papers 3947, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. NBER Working Paper No. 3947.

Santner, T. J. and Duffy, D. E. (1986). A note on A. Albert and J. A. Anderson’s conditions for the existence of maximum likelihood estimates in logistic regression models. Biometrika, 73:755–758.

Sarason, S. B. (1977). A "cultural" limitation of system approaches to educational reform.

American Journal of Community Psychology, 5(3):277–287.

Schneider, K., Schuchart, C., Weishaupt, H., and Riedel, A. (2012). The effect of free primary school choice on ethnic groups: Evidence from a policy reform. European Journal of Political Economy, 28(4):430 – 444.

COMPLETE BIBLIOGRAPHY Segal, J. A., Cameron, C. M., and Cover, A. D. (1992). A spatial model of roll call voting:

Sena-tors, constituents, presidents, and interest groups in Supreme Court confirmations. American Journal of Political Science, 36(1).

Sherfinski, D. (2014). Inner-city Democrats warm to school choice as rural Republicans balk.

The Washington Times.

Skaperdas, S. and Vaidya, S. (2012). Persuasion as a contest. Economic Theory, 51:465–486.

Smith, F. J. (1913). The Evolution of the Motion Picture: VI – Looking into the Future with Thomas A. Edison. The New York Dramatic Mirror, page 24.

Snyder, J. M. (1990). Campaign contributions as investments: The U.S. House of Representatives, 1980-1986. Journal of Political Economy, 98:1195–1227.

Snyder, J. M. (1992). Long-term investing in politicians: Or, give early, give often. Journal of Law and Economics, 35:15–43.

Snyder, J. M. (1993). The market for campaign contributions: Evidence from the U.S. Senate 1980-1986. Economics & Politics, 5(3):219–240.

Stratmann, T. (1991). What Do Campaign Contributions Buy? Deciphering Causal Effects of Money and Votes. Southern Economic Journal, 57(3):606–620.

Stratmann, T. (2005). Some talk: Money in politics. A (partial) review of the literature. Public Choice, 124:135–156.

Strauss, V. (2012). Questions Democrats must answer on school choice. The Washington Post.

Tommasi, M. and Velasco, A. (1996). Where are we in the political economy of reform? The Journal of Policy Reform, 1(2):187–238.

Tsebelis, G. (1995). Decision Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism and Multipartyism. British Journal of Political Science, 25:289–325.

Tsebelis, G. (2002). Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work. Princeton University Press, New Jersey.

Tullock, G. (1980). Efficient rent seeking. In James M. Buchanan, Robert D. Tollison, G. T., editor,Toward a theory of the rent-seeking society, pages 97–112. College Station, TX: Texas A&M University Press.

Tyack, D. and Tobin, W. (1994). The "Grammar" of Schooling: Why Has It Been So Hard to Change? American Educational Research Journal, 31(3):453–479.

U.S. Census Bureau (2010). The 2010 Census redistricting data sets.

U.S. Census Bureau (2012). Statistical abstract of the United States: 2012 (131st Edition).

Technical report, U.S. Census Bureau, Washington, D.C.

U.S. Census Bureau (2013). Annual Survey of State Governments. Technical report, U.S. Census Bureau.

U.S. Census Bureau, Population Division (2014). Annual Estimates of the Resident Population by Sex, Race, and Hispanic Origin for the United States, States, and Counties: April 1, 2010 to July 1, 2013. Technical report, U.S. Census Bureau, Population Division.

U.S. Department of Education (2009). Race to the top executive summary. Technical report, U.S. Department of Education.

U.S. Department of Education (2010). Ed Recovery Plan. Technical report, U.S. Department of Education.

U.S. Department of Education (2013). The threat of educational stagnation and complacency:

Remarks of the U.S. Secretary of Education Arne Duncan at the release of the 2012 Programme for International Student Assessment (PISA).

U.S. Department of Education (2014). Race to the top fund.

Wiese, R. (2014). What triggers reforms in OECD countries? Improved reform measurement and evidence from the healthcare sector. European Journal of Political Economy, 34:332–352.

Winkler, A. M., Scull, J., and Zeehandelaar, D. (2012). How Strong Are U.S. Teacher Unions?

A State-by-State Comparison. Technical report, Thomas B. Fordham Institute.

Wong, K. K. and Shen, F. X. (2002). Politics of state-led reform in education: Market competition and electoral dynamics. Educational Policy, 16(1):161–192.

Wright, J. R. (1990). Contributions, lobbying, and committee voting in the U.S. House of Representatives. The American Political Science Review, 84(2):417–438.

Abgrenzung

(Record of Achievement)

Das erste Kapitel "Political-economic determinants of education reform: Evidence on interest groups and student outcomes" habe ich ohne Hilfe Dritter und ohne Benutzung anderer als der angegebenen Hilfsmittel angefertigt.

Das zweite Kapitel "Strategic compromise, policy bundling and interest group power" ist in Zusammenarbeit mit Dr. Luna Bellani von der Universität Konstanz entstanden. Der Anteil meiner eigenen Leistung bei der Erstellung dieser Arbeit beträgt 70 Prozent.

Das dritte Kapitel "Upward mobility and legislator support for education reforms" ist auch in Zusammenarbeit mit Dr. Luna Bellani. Der Anteil meiner eigenen Leistung bei der Erstellung dieser Arbeit beträgt 50 Prozent.