• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Definitions of the middle class based on money metric measures

A quantitative perspective from South Africa

2.4. Literature Review

2.4.1. Definitions of the middle class based on money metric measures

While mainstream approaches in economics define the middle class based on money metric measures, alternative approaches have recently been suggested that build more closely on the sociological class literature. In what follows, we first review the most prominent definitions based on absolute or relative monetary thresholds. Alternative non-money metric measures will be discussed in Section 2.4.3.

Relative thresholds

The lowest common denominator in the debate on who constitutes the middle class is that its members should be “somewhere in the middle.” Proceeding from this assumption, relative definitions locate the middle class in the literal middle of the income distribution.

Two different concepts can be distinguished in this regard. First, a range of studies locate the middle class according to particular segments of the cumulative income or consumption distribution. In this regard, for example, Alesina and Perotti (1996) use the third and fourth quintile (the 40th to 80th percentiles), Partridge (1997) uses only the third quintile (the 40th to 60th percentiles), Easterly (2001) and Foster and Wolfson (2009) refer to the three middle quintiles (the 20th to 80th percentiles), and Solimano (2008) uses the third to tenth decile (the 30th to 90th percentiles). For the specific case of South Africa, Finn et al.

(2013b) and Levy et al. (2014) use income decile groups four to seven to define the middle class (the 40th to 70th percentiles), groups eight and nine to define the upper class and decile ten to identify the top income group. The main drawback of these purely relative approaches is that the population share of the middle class is held constant over time, which means that the relative share of the middle class will neither grow nor shrink in response to economic and social conditions, increased polarisation, or other distributional changes.

Second, “central tendency” measures define the middle class in a specific symmetric range around the median of the income distribution. In this regard, for example, Birdsall, Graham, & Pettinato (2000) draw on a definition that was first proposed by Thurow (1987).

They consider those individuals to be middle class, who have between 75 and 125 per cent of the per capita median income at their disposal. By comparison, other authors choose a wider range from 50 to 150 per cent (Visagie & Posel, 2013, based on Davis & Huston, 1992) or even from 60 to 225 per cent (Blackburn & Bloom, 1985) of the per capita median income.

There are several reasons why one may be interested in the median earner of society and those households who fall within a specific range of the median: As Visagie (2013) argues in the South African context:

30 Chapter 2

“First, evidence suggests that the relative growth of the share of total income of those in the actual middle of the income distribution leads to greater political stability, to a citizenry with higher levels of human development (including better education and health) and even to higher levels of economic growth (Perotti, 1996; Easterly, 2001, 2007). Secondly, changes in the middle income interval would help to assess whether growth has benefited the

‘average South African’ in post1994 South Africa” (Visagie, 2013: 2).

However, in developing economies typically characterised by a high concentration of the population at the lower end of the income distribution, this middle will likely still be poor in absolute terms and “is unlikely to be the middle class as either historically defined or understood” (Bhalla, 2007: 94). That is, while central tendency measures can be useful in assessing the degree of polarization or inequality in the income distribution, they do not adequately capture the actual welfare of the middle class. This is especially true in a high inequality country such as South Africa, where “thinking about what it means to be middle class is complicated by the low average and median levels of incomes in the country and the very wide distribution of income. Households who have achieved a modest standard of living are actually near the top of the national income ladder” (Visagie, 2013: 1).

Absolute thresholds

Alternatively, the middle class has commonly been identified according to an absolute income or expenditure range seen as adequate to be considered middle class. The main question that has been fuelling a heated debate on the definition of these thresholds is what it actually means to be middle class. In other words, where does poverty end and the middle class start, and when can somebody be considered rich? The important decision researchers are confronted with in this regard is whether those who move above the poverty line automatically enter the middle class, or whether there should be some intermediate group that separates those who can satisfy their most basic needs (but remain on the verge of falling into poverty) from a more economically stable middle class.

Several scholars, such as Banerjee and Duflo (2008) and Ravallion (2010), in fact define the middle class in the developing world simply as those who are no longer poor by international standards, using the two-dollar-a-day poverty line as the relevant threshold.

What this implies is that someone living on the equivalent of $1.99 a day (in 2005 purchasing power parities (PPPs)) would still be considered poor, while just one additional cent would push the same person into the middle class. The main argument for using this definition is that

despite being admittedly still very poor, those within this range are still much better off than the poorest in society, who live below the poverty line. However, as noted by Ravallion (2010), those falling into this classification still remain at a high risk of poverty.

Picking up on this notion, other scholars have argued that the middle class should actually only comprise “those ‘comfortably’ clear of being at-risk-of-poverty” (Atkinson &

Brandolini, 2013: 83). With this in mind, Rose (2016) defines the middle class in the United States (US) as families with incomes of at least 150 per cent of the national poverty line. In reference to recent polls conducted by the Pew Research Centre, in which 1 to 2 per cent of the US population self-identified as upper class, he defines an upper cut-off that excludes the top 1.8 per cent of income earners from being middle class. Alternatively, Sawhill and Haskins (2009) locate the US middle class in an income range from 100 to 700 per cent of the poverty line, subdivided into three groups: “lower middle” (100-299 per cent), “middle” (300-499 per cent), and “upper middle” (500-699 per cent).

Most prominently in the African context, the African Development Bank released a report in 2011, which – following a similar idea – suggests three subdivisions of the African middle class: “floating” ($2–$4), “lower middle” ($4–$10), and “upper middle” ($10–$20) (in 2005 PPPs). Combining these three groups, the report estimates that 34.3 per cent of all Africans belonged to the middle class in 2010. However, when excluding the floating class, the size of the middle class shrinks by almost two-thirds to 13.4 of the African population (see Ncube et al., 2011).

While appealing in their simplicity, a main limitation of these suggested approaches is that the boundaries that differentiate the “actual” middle class from the poor and the lower middle class are chosen arbitrarily. To address this shortcoming and derive a more robust and theoretically sound definition, López-Calva and Ortiz-Juarez (2014) pioneered an empirical strategy to defining the middle class anchored in the notion of economic security. Using panel data from Chile, Mexico, and Peru, households are ranked by their estimated probability of remaining in or falling into poverty within the next three to five years. In contrast to Banerjee and Duflo (2008), who cap the middle class at a maximum daily per capita income of $10, López-Calva and Oritz-Juarez (2014) argue that a minimum income level of $10 a day (in 2005 PPPs) is required for being middle class. At this threshold, people are estimated to face a maximum chance of 10 per cent of falling into poverty in the near future, which they consider an acceptable degree of vulnerability for the middle class. The upper cut-off is (arbitrarily) fixed at $50 a day (in 2005 PPPs).

32 Chapter 2

The derived lower threshold is consistent with Kharas’ definition of the global middle class, which he locates in a range of $10 to $100 a day (in 2005 PPPs) (Kharas, 2010; UNDP, 2013).7 Similarly, combining absolute and relative measures, Birdsall (2010) defines the middle class in developing countries as those with a minimum income of $10 a day (in 2005 PPPs), excluding the top 5 per cent of the national income distribution. While the absolute lower bound is meant to identify those individuals who are too poor to be middle class in any society, the upper threshold excludes those who are considered rich at least by their own country standards.

Following a similar vein as López-Calva and Ortiz-Juarez’s (2014) ambition for a more theoretically founded class analysis, there are an increasing number of studies that use the ownership of tangible and intangible assets, employment status, occupation, education, or possibilities for upward social mobility as criteria for class identification (see Section 2.4.3).

Among these, Visagie and Posel (2013) locate South Africa’s “affluent” middle class in an income range of R1,400 to R10,000 per person per month (in 2008 money terms), equivalent to about $8 to $58 a day (in 2005 PPPs). These thresholds correspond to the expected income interval for households in which the highest income earner is in an occupation that has typically been associated with the middle class.8

2.4.2. The size of South Africa’s middle class under alternative money metric measures