• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Covariance Estimation and Testing on the Ex- Ex-istence of Jumps

The Implementation of Models with Jumps and

5.1 Covariance Estimation and Testing on the Ex- Ex-istence of Jumps

We start explaining the concept of realized volatility independently intro-duced by Andersen et al. [2]; Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard [9]; Comte and Renault [34]. Multivariate generalizations (realized co-variation) are given e.g. inBarndorff-Nielsen and Shephard [10]; An-dersen et al. [4] containing asymptotic theory on correlations, regres-sions, and an analysis how covariances may change over time. A good sur-vey paper is Andersen et al. [3]. A partial generalization of the one-dimensional case, the so-called bipower variation, is given in Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard [11]. Roughly speaking, realized volatility con-tains jumps and the remaining continuous elements whereas bipower only contains the continuous part, so that the difference describes the jump part.

151

Hence, one can test upon jumps, seeBarndorff-Nielsen and Shephard [12]. The whole concept is in fact quite difficult as time series are observed on a discrete basis. A finer and finer time grid is necessary. We therefore assume that the underlying stochastic processS is an exponential L´evy pro-cess of finite variation, i.e. logS is a Brownian motion plus a compound Poisson process.

This assumption further implies that the sample moments of the returns satisfy a certain scaling property (see Cont and Tankov [32, Equation 7.52]), a singularity spectrum can be estimated to find out more about the actual continuous/jump relation of return time series, see Cont and Tankov [32, Chapter 7]. Actually this study shows that we are not at the end of the story by either using a geometric Brownian motion or jump-diffusions. Both singularity spectra do not exactly meet the form of the empirical estimate, seeCont and Tankov [32, Section 7.6.2].

Nevertheless, jump-diffusions seem to be the better alternative. This is also confirmed in several of the above articles. Jumps are e.g. often caused by macroeconomic announcements. We therefore continue with a definition of realized covariance.

Remark 5.1.1. In this section, we describe a method to separate variation caused by the continuous and the jump parts of a time series. Moreover, we allow for a certain time dependence that is supposed to be variable on a short time basis which might help to be quick off the mark in daily trading. Clearly, both requests are possible only, if data are observed in very short time intervals to approximate time-continuous observations. The right choice are high-frequency data, i.e. the stock price is observed every time it is traded, optimally we receive tick by tick data. However, on a long term basis, it might be wise to sit out short time volatility in the market. Then it is not important to observe changes based on a daily basis. A reliable and robust estimation on a longer time horizon is preferred. In particular, this is crucial when optimizing the risk-return relation in a credit portfolio. We then rely on our estimation on discrete time series techniques. A famous model is the so-called multivariate GARCH (MGARCH). A high developed literature can be found for all kinds of equity data, see [18; 19; 39; 43; 44; 45; 55; 70; 107].

A good survey is presented inKroner and Ng[83]. A stochastic extension is given by (stochastic) factor models, see e.g.Chib et al. [29]. Moreover, we think for an analysis of credit portfolio management, actual default events on a yearly basis are more natural to be looked at. An extensive treatment is described inBluhm and Overbeck[16] and Niethammer[104, 105].

Realized Covariation

Let ˘X := logS(1), ˘Y := logS(2) be semimartingales and pl be any sequence of random partitions tending to identity (0 = τ0l ≤ τ1l ≤ ... ≤ τkl

l and τil stopping times), then, see e.g.Jacod and Shiryaev[68];Protter [110]:

00+X where ˘Xc denotes the continuous and ˘Xd the discontinuous part of ˘X. Sup-pose that ˘X and ˘Y are discretely measured at the same time points based on intervals of time of lengthδ >0.We obtain a discretized version ˘Xδ/Y˘δ, of ˘X and ˘Y , defined as ˘Xδt

δ/Y˘δt

δ. [⌊x⌋ denotes the Gauß-functional, i.e.

the integer part ofx.] The realized covariance attis then defined as RCtδ( ˘X,Y˘) = As a special case in the Brownian model,dlogS=σdW+µdt,we obtain

RCtδP Z t

t−1

σsσsds.

So from the dataSδj,j= 1, ...,⌊Tδ⌋, we get a new data setRCtδ,t= 1, ..., T. Moreover, if we set ˘X= ˘Y, we obtain an estimator for the realized volatility of ˘X. So in the one-dimensional case, we can perform a regression, e.g. an ARFIMA(p, d, q), see Andersen et al. [4]:

φ(L)(1−L)d( q

RCtδ−µ) =ψ(L)ut, ut∼ N(0, σ2)

The method becomes quite difficult in a multivariate setting or if jumps are taking into account. Jumps are discussed in the next subsection by filtering out jumps by the bipower variation. In the multivariate setting we face an additional problem; different price processes are non-synchronously traded, see e.g. Hayashi and Yoshida [64]. Moreover, apart from the fact that high frequency data are still discrete, an adjustment with respect to the given market micro structure has to be made, i.e. a bid-and-ask spread has to be smoothed out, see e.g. Hansen et al. [63]. A forecasting model also relying on fractionally integrated ARMA processes is given byChiriac and Voev [30].

We next try to separate jumps from the remaining process:

Bipower Variation

We already know that the realized volatility converges to [ ˘X]. We next describe a measure - bipower variation - that converges to [ ˘Xc] so that the difference with RC describes the jumps. A test on the presence on jumps is then designed by considering the hypothesis [ ˘X] = [ ˘Xc]. Under this hypothesis it is implied thatP

(∆ ˘X)2= 0.The next considerations rely on Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard [12].

The 1,1-order bipower variation process (BPV){X˘}[1,1]t is defined as the probability limit of

δt

X

j=2

|X˘−X˘(j1)δ||X˘(j1)δ−X˘(j2)δ|, δ↓0, (5.1)

provided the limit exists. Under our assumption thatdX˘t=dlogSt=µdt+ σsdW +Jt, where Jt is a compound Poisson process and σ is independent ofW, we have

{X˘}[1,1]t = (E|u|)2[ ˘Xc]t, where u ∼ N(0,1) such that E|u| = 2

π. Hence, [ ˘Xd]t can be consistently estimated by

[ ˘Xδ]t−(E|u|)2{X˘δ}[1,1]t , where{X˘δ}[1,1]t is defined as the realized BPV:

{X˘δ}[1,1]t =

δt

X

j=2

|X˘−X˘(j−1)δ||X˘(j−1)δ−X˘(j−2)δ|.

Barndorff-Nielsen and Shephard [12] further derive the distribution of [ ˘Yδ]−(E|u|)2{X˘δ}[1,1]t and an adjusted feasible statistic to test on [ ˘X] = [ ˘Xc],i.e. no jumps.

The last lines were supposed to give an idea what can be done to es-timate covariance, jumps, and to separate them from the diffusion compo-nent. We refer for further details toBarndorff-Nielsen and Shephard [12];Cont and Tankov [32]. We next assume that the necessary param-eters are already estimated and given:

5.2 Comparison: Brownian vs. L´ evy Model

In this section, we illustrate our results about the optimal exponential port-folio and the convergence of thep-th problem. We start considering a single stock, i.e. N = 1. In the jump component, we consider a Poisson process and vary the intensityγ and the jump sizea. The optimal portfolio (number

of stocks held) w.r.t. an exponential utility function with α = 1 has been proven to be−θeSt1,where θe is the solution of

0 =θeσ2+ ((ea−1)eθe(ea−1)γ+ (µ−r), (5.2) see e.g. Section 4.5. If a is tending to minus infinity, we observe that θe = σ2rγ). We will only consider −θe. It stays constant over time and represents the optimal amount we invest into the stock. −θe will be therefore called optimal exponential portfolio throughout this section.

0 0.2

0.4 0.6

0.8

1 −7 −6 −5 −4 −3 −2 −1 0 1

−2

−1.5

−1

−0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2 2.5

jump size Optimal Exponential Portfolio: Continuous vs. Jump Process,

µ=0.1, σ =0.3

γ

ϑ(t)*S(t−)=−θe vs. ϑ(t)*S(t)=µ/σ2= 1.1111

continuous jump

Figure 5.1: Influence of jump size and intensity on the optimal portfolio Figure 5.1 shows the influence of jump size and intensity upon the op-timal exponential portfolio (−θe) in comparison to the optimal exponential portfolio if no jumps are taken into account (µ−r)/σ2. In detail, we set r= 0, µ= 0.1, σ= 0.3. A numerical solver of Equation 5.2 then yields op-timal exponential portfolios in a model with jumps (−θe, optimal invested amount into the stock) for different jump sizes a and different intensities γ (the black/grey graph). The white graph, a hyperplane parallel to the hyperplane with θe = 0, sets γ = 0 and therefore represents the constant optimal invested amount µ/σ2,if we only consider the geometric Brownian

motion of the jump diffusion. The difference of both graphs thus describes the importance of jumps for the optimal portfolio. Clearly, if the jump height is negative, the optimal portfolio with jumps is less than the portfo-lio if jumps are not considered and vice versa. We next analyze the portfoportfo-lio when jumps are taken into account. We observe that a low constanta, say -2, can be already interpreted as a default. The portfolio with jumps is almost equal to−θe= (µ−r−γ)σ2 . Furthermore, if the intensity is larger than the drift adjusted by the constant interest rate, we try to sell the stock, i.e.

if the intensity is too large relative to the obtained return µ, shortselling is suggested. We obtain a negative optimal portfolio. If the jump size is smaller than a small negative constant, the intensityγ almost solely drives the portfolio. In particular, if the jump size becomes very negative, i.e. sim-ulating a sudden jump to default, the portfolio tends to be equal to µσr2γ. Nevertheless, a stock is always positive, also after a large negative jump.

The stock has still got the chance to recover to an arbitrary high value. A real default corresponds to the case a= −∞ which is not included in the model. In practice however, our Brownian-Poisson- model presents a good approximation. It is not unrealistic to assume that the company might fully recover with a certain small probability after a default. In particular, as in practice it is well-known that definitions of default can vary a lot (failure to pay, restructuring, bankruptcy).

Jumps and variation in the Brownian motion drive the variation of the whole process. Figure 5.2 therefore shows the influence of changes in the intensity and the variance of the Brownian part upon the optimal portfolio while the total variation stays constant. We setµ= 0.1,a=−4, r= 0,and vary γ and σ such that V = σ2+ (ea−1)2γ stays constant. We plot the optimal portfolio for three different values ofV and analyze the changes: if the intensity is lower thanµ, the portfolio is positive. Increasing the intensity causes a lower investment in the stock. A positive portfolio is approximately only obtained ifµ > γ. σ2 only steers the scaling but does not change the sign. That is not surprising as we face an approximate “default scenario”

becausea=−4.A shift of the total variation V, 20% up and down, results in an almost parallel shift.

Summarizing, the graph (Figure 5.2) shows that the portfolio varies a lot dependent on the driver of variation, i.e. caused by a high variation in the diffusion (volatility σ) or the jump part (intensityγ). The separation of jumps and diffusion discussed in Section 5.1 is therefore important.

Finally, we illustrate the convergence of the Girsanov parameters (θq→ θe), in a two and a three-dimensional setting in Figure 5.3 and 5.4. We numerically calculateθq for a reasonable grid ofq in the interval (1,1.5) for multidimensional exponential Poisson processes with a Brownian component (by solving (4.2)). θeis derived as above. We plotq against the components of θq and (1, θe) in the same figure. The used intensity and jump size is given in the figures. We impressively observe convergence. Moreover, the

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0

0.1 0.2

0.3 0.4

0.5

−1.2

−1

−0.8

−0.6

−0.4

−0.2 0 0.2 0.4

σ2

change in portfolio with fixed total variance V V=σ2+(ea−1)2 γ , a=jump size= −4

γ

θ e = optimal portfolio

V=0.4 V=0.4*1.2=0.48 V=0.4*0.8

Figure 5.2: Decomposition of the variance of a stock

obtained optimal portfolios give an intuition how the portfolio changes in a three-dimensional case when jumps are taken into account.

5.3 Concluding Remarks

This chapter explains a method to estimate the parameters of the processes considered in this thesis, i.e. the covariance matrix and the jump measure.

Moreover, we illustrate the results of this thesis.

We just mention one estimation method to give an idea how our mod-els could be implemented. We explain realized covariation/volatility and bipower variation. In the one-dimensional case, the difference of both num-bers indicates if there are jumps in the data. There are many more methods, we refer to the existing literature, see e.g. [32] for a good overview.

In the second part of the chapter, we analyze the influence of the model parameters on the optimal exponential portfolio. We observe that the de-composition of the total variation into jumps and variance is very important for the optimal exponential portfolio. Moreover, our graphs show that also

a credit risk example can be included in our setting. We conclude, that we should invest only, if the drift minus the default intensity and the riskless return is positive.

Finally, we illustrate convergence of the Girsanov parametersθq to θe in a two and three-dimensional setting.

1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7

−0.4677

−0.4676

−0.4676

−0.4676

−0.4676

−0.4676

θ1q

Multidimensional Case:

Probable small positive jump θ1q, unprobable high negative jump θq2

1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7

−0.0961

−0.0961

−0.0961

−0.096

−0.096

θ2q

jump size S1=0.25, jump size S2=−0.75 σ=(0.3 0.1 0.12, 0.1 0.4 0.15 ) µ=[0.05; 0.06]; γ=(0.05,0.0005)

q

q e

q e

Figure 5.3: Convergence of the portfolio in a model with two stocks

1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7

−0.32

−0.31

−0.3

−0.29

θ1 q

Return vs. Negative Shocks

q e

1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7

−0.83

−0.82

−0.81

−0.8

−0.79

θ2 q

jump size S

1=−0.01, jump size S

2=−1, jump size S

3=0.01 σ=(0.3 0.1 0.12 0.11, 0.1 0.5 0.15 0.12, 0.1 0.5 0.6 0.13 )

µ=[0.07; 0.12; 0.05]; γ1=1 γ2=0.01

Optimal portfolio continuous vs. Lévy processes

ϑcexp=( 0.5236 1.0203 −0.6596) vs. ϑdexp=(0.2938 0.8032 −0.4749)

1 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7

0.47 0.48 0.49 0.5

q θ3q

Figure 5.4: Convergence of the portfolio in a model with three stocks

Bibliography

[1] Acerbi, C. and Tasche, D. (2001), On the Coherence of Expected Shortfall, Journal of Banking & Finance, 26, 1487-1503.

[2] Andersen, T.G. and Bollerslev, T. (1998), Answering the Skeptics:

Yes, Standard Volatility Models Do Provide Accurate Forecasts, In-ternational Economic Review, 39, 885-905.

[3] Andersen, T.G., Bollerslev, T., and Diebold, F.X. (2005), Paramet-ric and NonparametParamet-ric Measurement of Volatility. In Y. Ait-Sahalia and L.P. Hansen (Eds.) Handbook of Financial Econometrics: North Holland.

[4] Andersen, T.G., Bollerslev, T., Diebold, F.X., and Labys, P. (2003), Modeling and Forecasting Realized Volatility, Econometrica, 71, 529-626.

[5] Arai, T. (2005), An Extension of Mean-Variance Hedging to the Dis-continuous Case, Finance Stochast., 9, 129-139.

[6] Arai, T. (2006),Lp-Projections of Random Variables and its Applica-tion to Finance, preprint, KESDP No. 06-02.

[7] Artzner, P., Delbaen, F., Eber, J., and Heath, D. (1997), Thinking Coherently, RISK, 10, 11, 68-71.

[8] Artzner, P., Delbaen, F., Eber, J., and Heath, D. (1999), Coherent Measures of Risk, Math. Finance, 9, 3, 203-228.

[9] Barndorff-Nielsen, O. E. and Shephard, N. (2001), Non-Gaussian Ornstein-Uhlenbeck-based Models and some of their Uses in Financial Economics (with Discussion), Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series B 63, 253-280.

[10] Barndorff-Nielsen, O. E. and Shephard, N. (2004a), Econometric Anal-ysis of Realized Covariation: High Frequency Based Covariance, Re-gression, and Correlation in Financial Economics, Econometrica, 72, 3, 885-925.

161

[11] Barndorff-Nielsen, O. E. and Shephard, N. (2004b), Power and Bipower Variation with Stochastic Volatility and Jumps (with Dis-cussion), Journal of Financial Econometrics, 2, 1-48.

[12] Barndorff-Nielsen, O. E. and Shephard, N. (2006) , Econometrics of Testing for Jumps in Financial Economics using Bipower Variation, Journal of Financial Econometrics, 4, 1, 1-30.

[13] Becherer, D. (2006), Bounded Solutions to Backward SDE’s with Jumps for Utility Optimization and Indifference Hedging, Ann. Appl.

Probab. 16, 4, 2027-2054.

[14] Bender, C. and Niethammer, C.R. (2008) , On q-optimal Martingale Measures in Exponential L´evy Models, submitted.

[15] Biagini, S. and Frittelli, M. (2007), The Supermartingale Property of the Optimal Wealth Process for general Semimartingales, Finance Stoch., 11, 253-266.

[16] Bluhm, C. and Overbeck, L. (2003), Estimating Systematic Risk in Uniform Credit Portfolios, Credit Risk. Hrsg.: G.Bol et al. Contribu-tions to Economics Physica-Verlag, Heidelberg.

[17] Bluhm, C., Overbeck, L., and Wagner, C.K.J. (2002), An Introduction to Credit Risk Modeling, Financial Mathematics Series, Chapman &

Hall/CRC, London.

[18] Bollerslev, T. (1990), Modeling Coherence in Short-Run Nominal Ex-change Rates: a multivariate Generalized ARCH Model, Review of Economics and Statistics, 72, 498-595.

[19] Bollerslev, T., Engle, R. and Wooldridge, J. (1988), A Capital Asset Pricing Model with Time Varying Covariances, Journal of Political Economy, 96, 116-131.

[20] Bowden, R. J. (2006), The Generalized Value at Risk Admissible Set: Constraint Consistency and Portfolio Outcomes, Quantitative Finance, 6, 2, 159-171.

[21] Briand, Ph., Delyon, B., Hu, Y., Pardoux, E., and Stoica, L. (2003), Lp-Solutions of Stochastic Differential Equations, Stochastic Process.

Appl., 108, 109-129.

[22] Briand, Ph. and Hu, Y. (2006), BSDE with Quadratic Growth and Unbounded Terminal Value, Probab. Theory. Related Fields, 136, 4, 604-618.

[23] Brooks, C., Burke, S., and Persand, G. (2003), Multivariate GARCH Models: Software Choice and Estimation Issues, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 18, 6, 725 - 734.

[24] B¨urkel, V. (2005), Linear Isoelastic Stochastic Control Problems and Backward Stochastic Differential Equations of Riccati Type, disserta-tion, University of Konstanz.

[25] Buraschi, A., Porchia, P., and Trojani, F. (2006), Correlation Risk and Optimal Portfolio Choice, preprint, Imperical College/University of St. Gallen.

[26] Campbell, J.Y., Lo, A.W. and MacKinlay, A.C. (1997), The Econo-metrics of Financial Markets, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.

[27] Chan, T. (1999), Pricing Contingent Claims on Stocks driven by L´evy Processes, Ann. Appl. Probab., 9, 504-528.

[28] Chan, T., Kollar, J. and Wiese, A. (2006), Mean-Variance Hedging in L´evy models with Stochastic Volatility, preprint.

[29] Chib, S. , Nardari, F., Shephard, N. (2006), Analysis of High Dimen-sional Multivariate Stochastic Volatility Models, Journal of Economet-rics, 134, 2, 341-371.

[30] Chiriac, R. and Voev, V. (2007), Long Memory Modelling of Re-alized Covariances Matrices, (March 4, 2007), Available at SSRN:

http://ssrn.com/abstract=981331.

[31] Choulli, T., Stricker, C., and Li, J. (2007), Minimal Hellinger Martin-gale Measures of Orderq, Finance Stoch., 11, 399-427.

[32] Cont, R. and Tankov, P. (2004), Financial Modeling with Jump Pro-cesses, CRC Financial Mathematics Series, Chapman & Hall: CMAP-Ecole Polytechnique, F-91128 Palaiseau, France.

[33] Cont, R. and Tankov, P. (2006), Retrieving L´evy processes from Op-tion Prices: RegularizaOp-tion of an Ill-Posed Inverse Problem, SIAM J.

Control & Optim., 45, 1-25.

[34] Comte, F. and Renault, E. (1998), Long Memory in Continuous-Time Stochastic Volatility Models, Math. Finance, 8, 291-323.

[35] Cvitani´c, I. (1975), I-Divergence Geometry of Probability Distribu-tions and Minimization Problems, Ann. Prob. 3, 146-158.

[36] Delbaen, F., Grandits, P., Rheinl¨ander, T., Samperi, D., Schweizer, M., and Stricker, C. (2002), Exponential Hedging and Entropic Penal-ties, Math. Finance, 12, 2, 99-123.

[37] Delbaen, F. and Schachermayer, W. (1996), Attainable Claims with pth Moments, Ann. Inst. H. Poincar´e, Math. Stat., 32, 6, 743-763.

[38] Deutsch, H.-P. (2005), Quantitative Portfoliosteuerung - Konzepte, Methoden, Beispielrechungen, Sch¨affer/Poeschel, d-fine.

[39] Diebold, F. X. and Nerlove, M. (1989), The Dynamics of Exchange Rate Volatility: A Multivariate Latent Factor ARCH Model, Journal of Applied Econometrics, 1, 1-21.

[40] Duffie, D. and Richardson, H. (1991), Mean-Variance Hedging in Con-tinuous Time, Ann. Appl. Probab., 14, 1-15.

[41] El Karoui, N. and Quenez, M.-C. (1995), Dynamic Programming and Pricing of Contingent Claims in an Incomplete Market, SIAM J. Con-trol & Optim., 33, 1, 29-66.

[42] Embrechts, P., Furrer, H., and Kauffmann, R. (2007), Different Kinds of Risk, in Handbook of Financial Time Series, Eds. Anderesen, Davis, Kreiss, and Mikosch.

[43] Engle, R. (2001), Dynamic Conditional Correlation - a Simple Class of Multivariate GARCH Models, Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 20, 339-350.

[44] Engle, R. and Kroner, F. (1995), Multivariate Simultaneous General-ized ARCH, Econometric Theory, 11, 122-150.

[45] Engle, R., Ng, V., and Rothschild, M. (1995), Asset Pricing with a Factor-ARCH-Covariance Structure: Empirical Estimates for Trea-sury Bills, Journal of Econometrics, 45, 213-238.

[46] Esche, F. and Schweizer, M. (2005), Minimal Entropy Preserves the L´evy Property: How and Why, Stochastic Process Appl. 115, 299-237.

[47] F¨ollmer, H. (1973), On the Representation of Semimartingales, the Annals of Probability, 1,4, 580-589.

[48] F¨ollmer, H. and Kabanov, Yu. M. (1998), Optional Decomposition and Lagrange Multipliers, Finance Stoch., 2, 61-81.

[49] F¨ollmer, H. and Schied, A. (2004), Stochastic Finance - An Intro-duction in Discrete Time, de Gruyter Studies in Mathematics, 2nd Edition, Berlin New York.

[50] F¨ollmer, H. and Schweizer, M. (1991), Hedging of Contingent Claims under Incomplete Information, Davis, M. H. A. and Elliott, R. J.

(eds.), Applied Stochastic Analysis, Stochastic Monographs, Vol. 5, Gordon and Breach, London/New York, 389-414.

[51] Francis, J.C. (1976) Investments: Analysis and Management, McGraw-Hill, New York.

[52] Frittelli, M. (2000), The Minimal Entropy Martingale Measure and the Valuation Problem in Incomplete Markets, Math. Finance, 10, 39-52.

[53] Frittelli, M. and Biagini, S. (2007), A Unified Framework for Util-ity Maximization Problems: an Orlicz Space Approach, Ann. Appl.

Probab., forthcoming.

[54] Fujiwara, T. and Miyahara, Y. (2003), The Minimal Entropy Martin-gale Measure for Geometric L´evy processes, Finance Stoch., 7, 509-531.

[55] Gallant, A.R. and Tauchen, G. (2002), SNP: A Program for Nonpara-metric Time Series Analysis, User’s Guide Version 8.8.

[56] Goll, T. and R¨uschendorf, L. (2001), Minimax and Minimal Distance Martingale Measures and their Relationship to Portfolio Optimization, Finance Stoch., 5, 557-581.

[57] Gouri´eroux, C., Laurent, and J.P., Pham, H. (1998), Mean-Variance Hedging and Num´eraire, Math. Finance, 8, 179-200.

[58] Grandits, P. (1999), The p-Optimal Martingale Measure and its Asymptotic Relation with the Minimal Martingale Measure, Bernoulli, 5, 225-247.

[59] Grandits, P. and Krawczyk, L. (1998), Closedness of Some Spaces of Stochastic Integrals, S´eminaire de Probabilit´es XXXII, Lect. Notes in Math. 1686, Springer-Verlag Berlin, 73-85.

[60] Grandits, P. and Rheinl¨ander, T. (2002a), On the Minimal Entropy Martingale Measure, Ann. Probab., 30, 3, 1003-1038.

[61] Gregory, J. and Laurent, J.-P. (2005), Basket Default Swaps, CDOs and Factor Copulas, Journal of Risk, 7, 4, 103-122.

[62] Hakansson, N.H. (1971), Capital Growth and the Mean-Variance Ap-proach to Portfolio Selection, J. Financial and Quantitative Analysis, 6 , 517-557.

[63] Hansen, P.R., Lunde, A., and Voev, V. (2007), Integrated Covari-ance Estimation Using High-Frequency Data in the Presence of Noise, Journal of Financial Econometrics, 5, 68-104.

[64] Hayashi, T. and Yoshida, N. (2004), On Covariance Estimation for High-Frequency Financial Data, Financial Engineering and Applica-tions, Proceeding, 437-801.

[65] Hu, Y., Imkeller, P., and M¨uller, M. (2005), Utility Maximization in Incomplete Markets, Ann. Appl. Probab., 15, 1691-1712.

[66] Hubalek, F. and Sgarra, C. (2006), Esscher Transforms and the Mini-mal Entropy Martingale Measure for Exponential L´evy Models, Quan-tative Finance, 6 , 2, 125-145.

[67] Jacod, J. (1979), Calcul Stochastique et Probl`eme de Martingales, Lecture Notes in Mathematics, 714, Springer-Verlag Berlin.

[68] Jacod, J. and Shiryaev, A.N. (1987), Limit Theorems for Stochastic Processes, Springer-Verlag, Berlin.

[69] Jeanblanc, M., Kl¨oppel, S., and Miyahara, Y. (2007), Minimal FQ -Martingale Measures for Exponential L´evy Processes, Ann. Appl.

Probab., 17, 5/6, 1615-1638.

[70] Jondeau, E. and Rockinger, M. (2001), The Copula-GARCH Model of Conditional Dependencies: An International Stock-Market Appli-cation, Journal of Money and Finance, 25, 5, 827-853.

[71] Kabanov, Y. M. and Stricker, C. (2002), On the Optimal Portfolio for the Exponential Utility Maximization: Remarks to the Six-author Paper, Math. Finance, 12 ,2, 125-134.

[72] Kallsen, J. (2000), Optimal Portfolios for Exponential L´evy processes, Math. Meth. Oper. Res. , 51, 357-374.

[73] Kallsen, J. (2007), “L´evy-Prozesse anschaulich”, Manuscript, Univer-sity of Kiel, www.numerik.uni-kiel.de/∼jk/personen/kallsen/levy.ps (downloaded in 2007).

[74] Karatzas, I., Lehoczky, J.P. and Shreve, S.E. (1987), Optimal Portfolio and Consumption Decisions for a Small Investor on a Finite Horizon, SIAM J. Control Optim., 25 , 1557- 1586.

[75] Kobylanski, M. (2000), Backward Stochastic Differential Equations and Partial Differential Equations with Quadratic Growth, Ann.

Probab. 28, 2, 558-602.

[76] Kohlmann, M. and Niethammer, C. R. (2007), On Convergence to the Exponential Utility Problem, Stochastic Process. Appl., 117,12, 1813-1834.

[77] Kohlmann, M. and Tang, S. (2003), Minimization of Risk and Linear Quadratic Optimal Control Theory, SIAM J. Control & Optim., 42, 3, 1118-1142.

[78] Kohlmann, M. and Xiong, D. (2007), Thep-Optimal Martingale Mea-sure when there Exist Inaccessible Jumps. J. Pure Appl. Math., 37, 3, 321-348.

[79] Kohlmann, M. and Xiong, D. (2007), The p-Optimal Measures with Jumps and its Convergence to the Minimal Entropy Measure by means of a BSDE Approach, preprint.

[80] Kohlmann, M. and Xiong, D. (2007), The Mean-Variance Hedging when the Variance-Optimal Measure is not Equivalent toP in a gen-eral Jump Model, preprint.

[81] Kohlmann, M. and Zhou X. Y. (2000), Relationship between Back-ward Stochastic Differential Equations and Stochastic Control Linear-Quadratic Approach, SIAM J. Control & Optim., 38, 5, 1392-1407.

[82] Kramkov, D. and Schachermayer, W. (1999), The Asymptotic Elas-ticity of Utility Functions and the Optimal Investment in Incomplete Markets, Ann. Appl. Probab., 9, 904-950.

[83] Kroner, K.F. and Ng, V.K. (1998), Modeling Asymmetric Comove-ments of Asset Returns, Review of Financial Studies, 11, 4, 817-844.

[84] Kunita, H. (2004), Representation of Martingales with Jumps and Ap-plications to Mathematical Finance, Stochastic Analysis and Related Topics in Kyoto, in: Kunita, H. et al. (eds.), Stochastic Analysis and Related Topics in Kyoto: In honour of Kiyosi Itˆo, Advanced Studies

[84] Kunita, H. (2004), Representation of Martingales with Jumps and Ap-plications to Mathematical Finance, Stochastic Analysis and Related Topics in Kyoto, in: Kunita, H. et al. (eds.), Stochastic Analysis and Related Topics in Kyoto: In honour of Kiyosi Itˆo, Advanced Studies