• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Concluding Remarks

The argumentation led above had the purpose of demonstrating that the frontal assault of some rationalist authors on the traditional institution of CIL is erroneous, is based on wrong assumptions. Even inside the rationalist para-digm of economic analysis, it is possible to reconstruct and model how CIL operates – in a way that makes sense also under more traditional understand-ings of international law. CIL (if rightly modeled) is not a crude ideology, but a well-operating legal institution. CIL makes sense in coordination games with a repeated game character – and most problems of international relations are of that character. It is easily explainable that states have a mutual interest to agree on a series of coordinating rules even outside the formation of com-plex treaty regimes. The emergence of behavioral regularities is the first deci-sive factor of such gradual emergence of norms out of social practice – behav-ioral regularities that from a certain moment start to create legitimate expectations of other states. The expectation goes towards a calculus that a certain pattern of behavior will continue also in future. Such an expectation

96 See Trachtman (2008), 114.

97 See Mendelson (1998), 270–271, 284–291, as well as Byers (1999), 157–160.

facilitates enormously transactions between states, because it reduces insecu-rity about future behavior, and in the medium term also minimizes transaction costs. Such behavioral regularities only may be attributed legal significance if there is a shared meaning of such usages in a given social environment – but the international community in its diplomatic networks constitutes a relatively close-knit society with a strong degree of shared understanding. Entering into the described dynamic of evolutionary creation of regular patterns of behav-ior, linked shared meanings and – as a result – legitimate expectations is not as implausible as some critical rationalist authors have argued. Just to the con-trary, it is rather plausible under certain conditions of social dilemma situa-tions where productive coordination games are needed. If states accept the expectations raised by their practices and confirm them by relevant communi-cative acts, they inevitably become entangled in a web of mutual expectations that then transforms practice into legal obligations.

The paper has attempted to demonstrate the dynamics of such processes of building converging expectations and of hardening the mutual expectations to legal obligations. At the same time, it has tried to shed some light on decisive issues of the doctrine of CIL that have been left unresolved in traditional in-ternational legal doctrine. The author does not claim to know all the answers to the questions formulated. There is still a lot to do in order to understand the incentive structures that make CIL work. But such work is worthy of being done, since CIL is a relevant category, far from being epiphenomenal in inter-national relations. Our understanding of the operation of CIL could still profit a lot from further studies in terms of economic analysis.

Bibliography

Abbott, K. and D. Snidal (1998), Why States Act Through Formal International Organiza-tions, International Organization 42(1) 3–32.

Ago, R. (1957), Positive Law and International Law, American Journal of International Law 51 (4) 691–733.

Axelrod, R. (1984), The Evolution of Cooperation, New York: Basic Books.

Baker, R. B. (2010), Customary International Law in the 21st Century: Old Challenges and New Debates, European Journal of International Law 21 (1) 173–210.

Brownlie, I. (2004), Some Problems in the Evaluation of the Practice of States as an Element of Custom, in: Studi di diritto internazionale in onore di Gaetano Arangio-Ruiz, Napoli:

Editoriale Scientifica, 313–318.

Byers, M. (1999), Custom, Power and the Power of Rules. International Relations and Cus-tomary International Law, Cambridge: CUP.

Chinen, M. A. (2001), Game Theory and Customary International Law, Michigan Journal of International Law 23 (1) 143–189.

Dahlman, C. (2012), The Doctrine of Opinio Juris in Customary International Law, Nordic Journal of International Law 81 (3) 327–339.

Donaghue, S. (1995), Normative Habits, Genuine Beliefs and Evolving Law, The Australian Yearbook of International Law 16: 327–344.

Donovan, J. M. and H. E. Anderson (2003), Anthropology & Law, New York. Berghahn.

Dumberry, P. (2010), Incoherent and Ineffective: the Concept of Persistent Objector Revisit-ed, International & Comparative Law Quarterly 59 (3) 779–802.

Engel, C. (2010), An Experimental Contribution to the Theory of Customary International Law, Bonn: Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods 2010/13.

Engel, C. and M. Kurschilgen (2011), The Coevolution of Behavior and Normative Expecta-tions. Customary Law in the Lab, Bonn: Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Re-search on Collective Goods 2011/32.

Estreicher, S. and P. B. Stephan (2003), Rethinking the Binding Effect of Customary Interna-tional Law, Virginia Journal of InternaInterna-tional Law 44 (1) 5–17.

Fikentscher, W. (2009), Law and Anthropology. Outlines, Issues, and Suggestions, München:

Verlag der Bayerischen Akademie der Wissenschaften.

Geisinger, A. (2002), A Belief-Change Theory of Expressive Law, Iowa Law Review 88 (1) 35–73.

Goldsmith, J. L. and E. A. Posner (1999), A Theory of Customary International Law, Univ. of Chicago Law Rev. 66 (4) 1113–1177.

Goldsmith, J. L. and E. A. Posner (2000), Understanding the Resemblance between Modern and Traditional Customary International Law, Virginia Journal of International Law 40 (2) 639–672.

Goldsmith, J. L. and E. A. Posner (2005), The Limits of International Law, Oxford: OUP.

Golove, D. M. (2006), Leaving Customary International Law Where It Is, Georgia Journal of International & Comparative Law 34 (2) 333–377.

Guzman, A. T. (2005), Saving Customary International Law, Michigan Journal of Interna-tional Law 27 (1) 115.

Guzman, A. T. (2008), How International Law Works – A Rational Choice Theory, Oxford:

OUP.

Guzman, A. T. and T. J. Meyer (2008), Customary International Law in the 21st Century, in:

R.A. Miller (ed.), Progress in International Law, Leiden: Nijhoff, 197.

Hannikainen, L. (2006), The Collective Factor as a Promoter of Customary International Law, Baltic Yearbook of International Law 6: 125–141.

Henkin, L. B. (1997), How Nations Behave, 2nd ed. New York: Columbia Univ. Press.

Holzinger, K. (2003), Transnational Common Goods. Strategic Constellations, Collective action Problems, and Multi-Level Provision.

International Law Association (2000), Final report of the Commission on Formation of Cus-tomary (General) International Law: Statement of Principles Applicable to the Formation of General Customary International Law, available at: http://www.ilahq.o rg/pdf/CustomaryLaw.pdf

Kammerhofer, J. (2011), Uncertainty in International Law: A Kelsenian Perspective, London:

Routledge.

Kelly, J. P. (2000), The Twilight of Customary International Law, Virginia Journal of Inter-national Law 40 (2) 449–543.

Koh, H. H. (1997), Why Do Nations Obey International Law?, Yale Law Journal 106: 2599.

Kolb, R. (2003), Selected Problems in the Theory of Customary International Law, Nether-lands International Law Review 50 (2) 119–150.

Lepard, B. D. (2010), Customary International Law: A New Theory with Practical Applica-tions, Cambridge: CUP.

McAdams, R. H. (2000), A Focal Point Theory of Expressive Law, Virginia Law Review 86 (4) 1649–1729.

McAdams, R. H. and J. Nadler (2005), Testing the Focal Point Theory of Legal Compliance.

The Effect of Third-Party Expression in an Experimental Hawk/Dove Game, Journal of Empirical Legal Studies 2 (1) 87–123.

Mendelson, M. (1995), The Subjective Element in Customary International Law, The British Yearbook of International Law 66: 177.

Mendelson, M. (1999), The Formation of Customary International Law, Recueil des Cours de l’Académie de Droit International de la Haye 272: 155–410.

Milgrom, P. R., D. C. North, and B. R. Weingast (1990), The Role of Institutions in the Re-vival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs, Economics and Politics, 2(1): 1–23.

Mofidi, M. (2005), Applying Rational Choice Theory to Customary International Law, Ann Arbor: UMI.

Norman, G. and J. P. Trachtman (2005), The Customary International Law Game, American Journal of International Law 99 (3) 541.

Norman, G. and J. P. Trachtman (2008), Measuring the Shadow of the Future. An Introduc-tion to the Game Theory of InternaIntroduc-tional Law, University of Illinois Law Review 60 (1) 127–153.

Ochoa, C. (2007), The Individual and Customary International Law Formation, Virginia Journal of International Law 48 (19) 119–186.

Onuma, Y. (2009), A Transcivilizational Perspective on International Law, Recueil des Cours / Collected Courses of the Hague Academy of International Law 342: 77–418.

Orakhelashvili, A. (2008), Natural Law and Customary Law, Zeitschrift für ausländisches öffentliches Recht und Völkerrecht 68 (1) 69–110.

Petersen, N. (2007), Customary Law Without Custom? Rules, Principles, and the Role of State Practice in International Norm Creation, American University International Law Re-view 23 (2007), 275–310.

Petersen, N. (2008), Rational Choice or Deliberation? Customary International Law between Coordination and Constitutionalization, Bonn: Preprints of the Max Planck Institute for Research on Collective Goods 2008: 28.

Pospisil, L. (1982), Anthropologie des Rechts: Recht und Gesellschaft in archaischen und modernen Kulturen, München: C.H. Beck.

Risse, T. (1999), International Norms and Domestic Change. Arguing and Communicative Behaviour in the Human Rights Area, Politics & Society 27 (5) 529–559.

Risse, T. (2000), Let’s Argue. Communicative Action in World Politics, International Organ-ization 54 (1) 1–39.

Roberts, A. E. (2001), Traditional and Modern Approaches to Customary International Law, American Journal of International Law 95 (4) 757–791.

Sandler, T. (2004), Global Collective Action, Cambridge: CUP.

Scharf, M. P. (2013), Customary International Law in Times of Fundamental Change, Cam-bridge: CUP.

Stephan, P. B. (2010), Disaggregating Customary International Law, Duke Journal of Com-parative & International Law 21 (1) 191–205.

Stern, B. (2001), Custom at the Heart of International Law, Duke Journal of International &

Comparative Law 11 (1) 89–108.

Taki, Hiroshi (2008), Opinio Juris and the Formation of Customary International Law, Ger-man Yearbook of International Law 51: 447–466.

Tasioulas, J. (2007), Opinio Juris and the Genesis of Custom, The Australian Yearbook of International Law 26: 199–205.

Tomuschat, C. (1999), International Law: Ensuring the Survival of Mankind on the Eve of a New Century. Recueil des Cours de l’Académie de Droit International de la Haye 281: 9.

Trachtman, J. P. (2008), The Economic Structure of International Law, Cambridge, Mass.:

Harvard Univ. Press.

Trachtman, J. P. (2010), Persistent Objectors, Cooperation, and the Utility of Customary International Law, Duke Journal of Comparative & International Law 21 (1) 221–233.

Treves, T. (2009), Customary International Law, in: Max Planck Encyclopedia of Public International Law, ed. by R. Wolfrum, Oxford: OUP (Online edition).

Vagts, D. F. (2004), International Relations Looks at Customary International Law: A Tradi-tionalist’s Perspective, European Journal of International Law 15 (5) 1031–1040.

Voyiakis, E. (2010), Customary International Law and the Place of Normative Considerations, American Journal of Jurisprudence 55 (1) 163–200.

Williamson, O. E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York: Free Press.

Wiener, A. (2008), The Invisible Constitution of Politics. Contested Norms and International Encounters, Cambridge: CUP.

Wiener, A. (2009), Enacting Meaning-in-Use: Qualitative Research on Norms and Interna-tional Relations, Review of InternaInterna-tional Studies 35 (1) 175–193.

Yee, S. (2000), The News that Opinio Juris “is not a Necessary Element of Customary Inter-national Law” is Greatly Exaggerated, German Yearbook of InterInter-national Law 43: 227–

238.

Customary International Law, Coordination and