• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Evaluation of Danger or How Knowledge Transforms Hazard Rates

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Evaluation of Danger or How Knowledge Transforms Hazard Rates"

Copied!
22
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

NOT FOR QUOTATION WITHOUT PERMISSION OF THE AUTHOR

WAIUATION OF DANGER OR HOW

KNOWLEDGE

TRILNSFOmS HAZARD RATES

October 1983 WP-83-101

Working Papers are interim reports on work of the International Insti- tute for Applied Systems Analysis and have received only limited review. Views or opinions expressed herein do not necessarily represent those of the Institute or of its National Member Organiza- tions.

INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE FOR APPLIED SYSTEMS ANALYSIS 2361 Laxenburg, Austria

(2)

The perception of real or potential risks by individuals shapes the way in which society responds to various opportunities for development. However, this perception often bears little relation to the real danger, being affected not only by different social and cultural traditions but also by the amount of infor- mation available.

In this paper, Anatoli Yashin of the Core Concepts group of the Sys tem and Decision Sciences Area examines how changes in information about the risks associated with possible future events formally transform the chances of these events occurring. He describes a n analytical tool for the probabilistic analysis of hazard rates under various assumptions concerning the available informa- tion.

Andrzej Wierzbicki Chairman

System and Decision Sciences

(3)

EVALUATION OF DANGER OR HOW

KNOWLEDGE TRANSFOWIIS HAZARD RATES

r n O D U C r I O N

Decision making under conditions of uncertainty is based on the analysis of risk. The primary objective of t h s analysis is to increase the manager's abil- ity to respond effectively and appropriately to the problems facing him.

The particular problems that are identified will depend on the manager's knowledge of the subject, the discrepancies between his wishes and reality, and his own perception of the real risks. The priority ranking of the problems will depend on the position of the manager in the herarchy and on his responsibili- ties.

The perception of real or potential risks by individuals in the social environment shapes the social response to real problems. Ths response also plays an important role in determining the preference structure of the manager, through external pressures.

(4)

However, the social perception of risk sometimes bears little relation to the real danger. The various social principles that guide behavior affect the judgement of what danger or problem should be most feared and what risk is worth taking. These social and behavioral aspects of the decision making pro- cess may introduce additional restrictions into the control strategies.

The continued use of tobacco, alcohol and other drugs provides a good example. Everybody knows that smoking increases the risk of lung cancer, that alcohol and drug abuse can lead to alcohol and drug addiction, make accidents more likely, and so on. However, in spite of the success of causal analysis and quantitative calculation in identifying these and many other potentially dangerous activities, many people still continue to ignore the warn- ings. This means that health and social authorities have to resort to various indirect methods of decreasing the hazard r a t e s associated with problems of this type by trying to change t h e social perception of the real dangers.

Differences in social principles and traditions are not the only causes of differences in individual perceptions of danger. Differences in knowledge about a particular situation and the related factors a r e also important in evaluating risk. Often people have different perceptions of the risk of a given course of action simply because they have different information about it. In actual fact, most of the people tend to be unaware of most of the dangers most of the time.

Thus, more exact knowledge creates a better background for the accurate perception of risk. Dissemination of this knowledge can change human prefer- ences in the evaluation of risk and make people more aware of the real dangers that they face.

The study of risk requires two different stages of analysis. The first involves the quantitative determination of the real risk, calculated from specific information on the technological or environmental hazards. The

(5)

second phase involves social and individual decisions about whether the risks are acceptable and how best to manage them.

A n important intermediate stage is concerned with the analysis and corn- parison of formal risk assessments made on the basis of different information about the dangers. In other words, it is necessary to know how changes .in the information about the risks associated with possible future events formally transftrrm the chances of these events occurring. The subsequent evaluation of risk perception in different social groups with different cultural and other trad- itions should then be based on the results of this formal analysis of differences in information.

This paper is a n attempt to provide an analytical tool for the probabilistic analysis of hazard rates under various assumptions concerning the available information.

PROBABILISTIC DESCRIPTION OF RISK

The formal analysis of hazardous situations is based on probability theory.

To deal with the dynamic aspects of risk evaluation requires the use of hazard r a t e s , whlch a r e employed quite widely in the applied sciences and are often used in the description of mechanisms generating unexpected changes or unpredictable events, such as death or disaster, famine or failure [I ,2].

Random hazard rates are used to characterize changes with a h g h degree of uncertainty, such as mortality in heterogeneous populations and transition rates in multistate demography [3,4]. These rates can also help to describe discontinuous changes in particular components of multidimensional (e.g., industrial) processes or failures of technical equipment [5,6,7,8,9], and are useful in analyzing causal changes in the social or medical status of individuals [4,10,11,12].

(6)

The most convenient probabilistic models of the dynamics of rapid unex- pected changes or unpredictable events are random point processes or ran- dom jumping processes [13,14,15,16]. The combination of rapid jumps with the relatively slow evolution of systems variables observed in many real situations may be described by a general random process model with piecewise- continuous sampling paths. Several such models have been developed in the framework of the "martingale approach [17,18,19].

Stochastic intensities or compensators or, more generally, dual predict- able projections of integer-valued random measures may be taken as stochas- tic models of hazard rates and can be used in conjunction with martingale theory to formulate many interesting results. Among these are: conditions for the absolute continuity and singularity of probabilistic measures correspond- ing to piecewise-continuous processes [20], formulas for filters [16], con- sistency conditions for Bayesian parameter estimation [21], and weak conver- gence properties [22,23]. Note that to obtain such results it is only necessary to know that random intensities exist, not to know their internal structure.

To apply these results in practice requires the detailed structuring of the random intensities. It is usually most convenient to represent intensities in terms of probability distributions, or more exactly, in terms of conditional pro- bability distributions.

Some results have already been obtained using this type of representatlon [24,25,26]. The more general of these use Jacod's formula for the dual predict- able projection of integer-valued random measures [15]. However, such results cannot be used in some situations where the observer (statistician) has to deal with an increasing volume of information, as is usually the case for recursive estimation and control in a situation with incomplete information.

(7)

In t h s paper we will give a representation of random intensity processes in this more general situation. In a certain sense t h s may be seen as an attempt to formalize the relations between the abstract results of martingale theory and the classical approach t o the analysis of random phenomena. We will also compare the hazard rates perceived by two observers, one of whom has some information about the environmental factors and processes influenc- ing the chance of the random events occurring, whle the other knows only about past events of the same kind.

The algorithms used to estimate the hazard rates depend on the dynamics (stable, continuously evolving, or jumping) of the factors influencing the environment. However, all of these algorithms are similar in that they are gen- erated by the nonlinear filter approach using random observations. This approach is gradually becoming popular in technical fields such as reliability analysis [8,7] and communication theory 1131 as well as being used for social and medical. research in areas such as event history analysis [27,28].

In order to gain a better understanding of the role of martingale theory in the analysis of random intensities, we shall consider the following situation.

Assume that somebody is affected by a sequence of unfavorable (favor- able) events occurring a t random times. T h s person may have observations or measurements of environmental parameters a t various times between succes- sive events; these observations or measurements give h m additional informa- tion about the possible timing of the events and scale of the damage (benefits).

Denote by Ht the information available to the person up to time t . At any time the person can either save some money "for a rainy day" or else spend it. The question is how much money he should save (spend) at time t if he wants to

(8)

compensate exactly for the damage (benefits) expected at some time in the future .

If we denote by Yt the cumulative total of the random damage (benefits) experienced at random times up to time t and by Ct the total sum of money that the person has saved (spent) up to this time, then the process

should have the property

for any t ;+ u , and if

M o

= 0, then

These equalities mean that process C t , t r 0 , may be considered as a com- pensator of the discontinuous changes caused by process

5 ,

t r 0. It turns out that processes like C t , t 2 0 , may be compared to cumulative intensities, and processes such as

M t ,

t 2 0, have the martingale property with respect to information flow Ht , t 2 0 .

Notice that the process Ct satisfying the above conditions is not unique.

However, it is possible to find a unique process corresponding in some sense to the information available up to the current time t . A formal way of construct- ing such a process is given below.

DIRERMINISTIC HAZARD RILTES

We will start with the conventional definition of a hazard rate for a continu- ously distributed random time of occurrence of the events under considera- tion. If F ( 1 ) is the time-of-occurrence distribution function, then the local hazard rate A ( t ) is equal to minus the logarithmic derivative of the function

(9)

t

The cumulative intensity function A(t) = Jh(u)du is then 0

This means that the distribution function may be represented in the following form:

Discontinuities in the time-of-occurrence distribution function modify the definition of the intensity function only slightly:

However, they cause complications in equation (2), which represents the distri- bution function ~ ( t ) as a function of the cumulative intensity function A(t). It can be shown that in t h s case the analog of formula ( 2 ) is as follows:

whch reverts to formula (2) if A ( t ) is not discontinuous.

Discontinuous hazard rates are often produced by the estimation pro- cedure: the Kaplan-Meier estimator is one well-known culprit [29,30]. .

(10)

RANDOM INTENSITY FUNCTIONS

The dependence of the random time of occurrence on various other ran- dom factors representing the state of the environment should also be included somehow in the formula for the hazard rate. The conventional way of doing this is to put the randomness into the intensity function. If t h s randomness is generated by a random variable Z which can be interpreted as an external environmental factor, we can represent the random intensity as a function of the conditional distribution function as follows:

where P ( T

>

u

I Z)

is the conditional probability of the event tT

>

u ] given random variable Z.

Let I ( T s t ) be the indicator of event tT s t ] and HfZ be the past h s t o r y of process Xt = I( T c t ) , t 2 0 , and random variable Z up to time t . It turns out that the process M ( t ) defined by the equality

is martingale with respect to the family of hstories

Ht,

t s 0 and conse- quently

for any t s u .

(11)

COMPENSATOR FOR POINT PROCESSES

For a sequence of random times of occurrence ( a random point process) with random variable Z influencing the flow of random times, the probabilistic representation of the random intensity is as follows:

where H{ is the h s t o r y of the counting process Nt defined by the equality

N, = I (Tn s t )

n =O

up to random time Tp. It turns out that the process

is martingale with respect to the family of hstories H , ~ , t 2 0 , generated by the values of the random process Nt and random variable Z. The process A ( t , Z ) , t 2 0, is called the compensator of the random point process (Tn)n r 0.

JACOD'S FORHULA

A more general form of the random intensity function can be derived for a process involving a sequence of random times of occurrence and random vari- ables (T,, q ) ,

,

o. If Y is some known random variable w h c h influences the sequence ( T , ) , then the formula for the random intensity vw ( ( 0 , t ] , ) , t 2 0, of the process

(12)

where

r

is some subset of the space of values of the random variables ( q ) n

,

O, is as follows:

where

H f

is the history of the process (Tn ,

G ) , ,

up to random time Tp

P

[ 151.

HAZARD

RATES

IN A STABLE ENVIRONMENT

The most interesting results are obtained from a n analysis of the intensity processes that correspond to different levels of knowledge about the random factors influencing the sequence of random times of occurrence and random variables. If, for instance, one observer knows the value of the random variable Z influencing the sequence of random times Tn , n 1 0, while another does not, they will construct different representations of the intensity functions. Denot- ing by h ( t , Z ) and )\(t) the intensities perceived by the two observers, we consider the natural question: what is the relation between A(t ,Z) and A ( t ) ? It turns out t h a t t h s relation is as follows:

where H? is the h s t o r y of the counting process Nt corresponding to the sequence of random times of occurrence Tn , n r 0, up to time t .

(13)

FILTERING F'ORMULA

Equation (7) shows that when the observable process is discontinuous it is necessary to use some sort of estimation algorithm to calculate i t ) . Various estimation procedures of t h s kind based on [13] and [14] have been developed.

The general formula for t h e a posteriori mathematical expectation of some arbitrary integrable function f (Z) of random variable Z when the observations are taken from the sequence (point process)

T,,

n 1 0, of random occurrence times or, equivalently, from the counting process N t , t r 0, is as follows:

t

qu

)

-

1)

1

HZ) (dN, - h ( u ) d u ) E ( f (Z)

1

HtN) = E ( f (Z)

I

H)!

+ j ~ ( f

(Z) (

x(~)

0

where

-

h ( t ) = E ( h ( t , Z )

1

H ~ ~ ) .

If Z is the finite state random variable Z = ( Z1,

G,

..., ZK) with a priori probabilities p i , i

=

1,2,. ..,K, and the observations are taken from the count- ing process

Nt

with intensity h(t , Z), the formula for the intensity function

-

h ( t ) will be as follows:

where the sri ( t ) , i

=

1,2, ... ,K, are given by the filtering formula:

In the simplest case, in w h c h there is only one random time of occurrence (e.g., time of death or failwe), t h s relation can be transformed t o the equality:

If Z = y2 where Y is a Gaussian random variable with mean a and variance u 2 , and h ( t , Z)

=

Z h ( t ) , t h e n one can write

(14)

where k ( t ) is given by the formula

-

z

( t )

=

m 2 ( t )

+

y ( t ) (9)

and m ( t ) and y ( t ) are the solutions of the ordinary differential equations

These equations show that even when h ( t ) is a constant and the environmental factors do not change over time (the hazard rate perceived by one observer is constant), the hazard rate perceived by another observer may still be time- dependent.

THE

GENERAL M)RM OF

HAZARD

RATES IN A DYNAMIC ENVIRONMENT

In many cases the environmental factors that influence the hazard rate can change over time. T h s section is concerned with results based on the assumption of a randomly changing environment. Let Xt , t 1 0 , be the ran- dom process available for observation and suppose that it includes the sequence of times and events a s well as the additional environmental factors.

Introduce the auxiliary process Xnlt which coincides with the process Xt up to time Tn and does not contain the random occurrence times Tg and ran- dom variables

5

after time Tn . Denoting by

$"

the hstory of the auxili- ary process up to time t and introducing some additional conditions it is pos- sible to prove the following formula for the random intensity

vZ

((0,t

1, F)

of the process p((O,t], i?) introduced earlier:

(15)

In the case of a point process ( a sequence of random times of occurrence T,, n 2 0) the formula for the random intensity A ( t , x i ) corresponding to observable process

Xt

, t 1 0, will be:

Assuming that the distribution of random times is continuous and compar- ing the intensities corresponding to different levels of knowledge leads to the following formula for the intensity ( t ):

Assume that A ( ~ , x ; )

=

f (Xt) and t h a t Xf is the solution of the following stochastic differential equation:

The formula f o r h ( t ) will then be as follows:

However, if instead of a sequence of random times and variables one has only a single random occurrence time T the formula for the random intensity A(t .x;)

(16)

corresponding to the information given by observation

Xt

will be

and the formula f o r ( t ) will be

If A(t

,x;)

= A(Xt) then the formula for h ( t ) will be as follows:

These general formulas can be made more specific if a more detailed descrip- tion of the processes is available

HAZARD RATES IN A CONTINUOUSLY EVOLVING ENVIRONMENT

Environmental factors that are changing continuously may be treated in the following way.

Let ~ ( t ) , t r 0 , be some process that satisfies the linear stochastic dif- ferential equation

d Y ( t )

=

a o ( t ) + a l ( t ) Y ( t ) dt

+

b ( t ) d W ( t ) , Y ( 0 )

=

Y o

where Y o is a Gaussian random variable with mean mo and variance yo.

Assume that random time of occurrence T is related to the process Y ( t ) by the equality

where H t is the history of the process Y ( t ) up to time t

.

It turns out that the

(17)

conditional distribution of Y(t ) given IT r t j is Gaussian. The mean rn ( t ) and variance y ( t ) of this distribution are given by the following equations:

The relation between ( t ) and X(t) is as follows:

-

h ( t )

=

( m 2 ( t ) + Y(t) A(t)

This example shows that two observers may have quite different values for hazard rates. It should therefore come as no surprise that their perceptions of risk a r e different and that the decisions based on these perceptions may also be different.

HAZARD RATES IN A DISCONTINUOUSLY CHANGING ENVIRONWT

Environmental factors can sometimes change discontinuously, i.e., their values jump about a t random. T h s can happen, for instance, when there are several correlated sequences of random occurrence times and variables.

Examples of such correlated sequences are: changes in the place of residence or work of some particular individual and changes in his health; rapid changes in the weather and the survival chances of living organisms; discontinuous changes in the price or demand structure and structural change in organiza- tions or firms.

Assume that Zt , t 2 0, is a finite-state continuous-time jumping process with transition intensity matrix ri ( t ), i , j E

-

( 1 ,K) , and h ( t , Zt ) = A(t) Zf The relation betweenh(t) and X(t) is then as follows:

(18)

where

Z,

is the i - t h state of process

& ,

and processes ni ( t ) are solutions of the following equations:

where

If instead of a sequence of random occurrence times we have only one random time of occurrence T, the formula for

h ( t )

remains the same but the equation for the ni ( t ) is simplified:

d7ii ( t ) K K

-

= z

n k ( t ) ~ k , i ( ~ ) + ~ ~ i ( t ) (

- z

n k ( t ) Z k ) h ( t ) , i E ( 1 , K ) . (17)

dt k = ] k = l

These equations are useful in the analysis of population heterogeneity.

(19)

REFERENCES

1 . G . G . Berg and H.D. Maillie, "Measurement of Risk". In Environmental Science Research, Vol. 21, Plenum Press, New York and London ( 1 9 8 2 ) .

2. W.J. Petak and A.A. Atkisson, Natural Hazard Risk Assessment and Public Policy, Springer-Verlag, New York, Heidelberg, and Berlin ( 1982).

3. N. Keyfitz and G. Littman, "Mortality in Heterogeneous Populations", Popula- t i o n S t u d i e s , 33, pp. 333-343 ( 1 9 8 0 ) .

4 . J.W. Vaupel and A.I. Yashin, The Deviant Dynamics of Death in Heterogene-

OZLS PbpulatiOm, RR-83-1, International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria ( 1982).

5 . R.E. Barlow and F . Proschan, Statistical Theory of Reliability a n d Life Test- i n g , Holt, Rinehart and Winston, New York ( 1 9 7 5 ) .

6 . H.W. Block and T.H. Savits, "Multivariate Classes of Life Distributions in Reli- ability Theory", Mathematics of m e r a t i o n s Research, 6 ( 3 ) , pp ,453-461 ( l Q 8 l ) .

(20)

7. E. Arjas, "The Failure and Hazard Processes in Multivariate Reliability Sys- tems", Mathematics of m e r a t i o n s Research, 6(4), pp. 551-562 (1981).

8. E. Arjas, "A Stochastic Process Approach t o Multivariate Reliability Systems:

Notions Based on the Conditional Stochastic Order", Mathematics of Operations Research, 6(2), pp. 263-276 (1981).

9.

N .

Langberg, F. Proschan, and A.J. Quinzi, "Estimating Dependent Life Length, with Applications to t h e Theory of Competing Risk", The Annals of S t a t i s t i c s , 9( I), pp. 157- 167.

10. J.J. Heckman and B. Singer, "Population Heterogeneity in Demographc Models". In Advances in Multiregional Demography, Academic Press, New York (1982).

11. J.W. Vaupel, K. Manton, and E. Stallard, "The Impact of Heterogeneity in Individual Frailty on the Dynamics of Mortality", Demography, 16, pp. 439- 454 (1979).

12.

K.

Manton, E. Stallard, and J.W. Vaupel, "Methods for Comparing the Mortal- ity Experience of Heterogeneous Populations", Demography, 18, pp. 389- 410 (1981).

13. D.L. Snyder, R a n d o m Point Processes, John Wiley and Sons, New York (1975).

14. A.I. Y a s h n , "Filtering of Jumping Processes", Automatic and Remote Con- trol, 5, pp. 52-58 (1970).

15. J. Jacod, "Multivariate Point Processes: Predictable Projection, Radon- Nicodim Derivatives, Representation of Martingales", Zeitschrift fuer Wahrscheinlichkeitstheory u n d Veenuandte Gebiete, 31, pp. 235-253 (1975).

16. P. Bremaud, Point Processes and Queues, Springer-Verlag, New York, Heidelberg, and Berlin (1980).

(21)

17. J. Jacod, "Calcules Stochastique e t Probleme de Martingales", Lecture N o t e s in M a t h e m a t i c s , Vol. 714, Springer-Verlag, Heidelberg (1979).

18. P.A. Meyer, P r o b a b i l i t y a n d P o t e n t i a l s , Waltham, Blaisdell (1966).

19. C. Dellacherie, C a p a c i t i e s e t P r o c e s s u s S t o c h a s t i q u e s , Springer-Verlag , Ber- lin and New York (1972).

20. Yu.M. Kabanov, R.S. Liptzer, and A.N. S h r y a e v , "Absolute Continuity and Singularity of Locally Absolutely Continuous Probability Distributions", M a t h . S b o r n i k U S S R (in Russian), 35(5), pp. 631-680 (1979).

21. A.I. Y a s h n , "Convergence of Bayesian Estimations in Adaptive Control Schemas", P r o c e e d i n g s of t h e Workshop o n A d a p t i v e Control, October 27- 29, 1982, Florence, Italy, pp. 51-75 (1982).

22. R . Rebolledo, "Central Limit Theorem for Local Martingales", Zeitschrift f u e r Wahrscheinlichkeitstheorie u n d Verzuandte G e b i e t ~ , 51, pp. 269-286

(1980).

23. R.S. Liptzer and A.N. S h r y a e v , "Functional Central Limit Theorem for Sem- imartingales", P r o b a b i l i t y Theory a n d A p p l i c a t i o n s (in Russian), 25, pp.

667-688 (1980).

24. C.S. Chou and P.A. Meyer, "Sur la Representation des Martingales Comme lntegrales Stochastiques dans les Processus Pounctuels", Lecture N o t e s in M a t h e m a t i c s , Vol. 465, Springer-Verlag, Berlin (1975).

25. R.S. Liptzer and A.N. Shiryaev, S t a t i s t i c s of R a n d o m P r o c e s s e s , Springer- Verlag, Berlin and New York (1978).

26. R. Boel, P. Varaja, and E. Wong, "Martingales on Jump Processes. I1 Representation Results", SIAM Journal of Control, 13(5), pp. 999-1060 (1975).

27. M.T. Hannan and G.R. Carroll, "Dynamics of Formal Political Structure: An

(22)

Event His tory Analysis", A m e r i c a n Sociological R e v i e w , 4 6 , pp . 19-35 (1981).

28. N.B. Turna, M.T. Hannan, and L.P. Groenveld, "Dynamic Analysis of Event Histories", A m e r i c a n J o u r n a l of Sociology, 84, pp. 820-854 (1980).

29. E.L. Kaplan and P. Meier, "Nonparametric Estimation from Incomplete Observations", J o u r n a l of t h e A m e r i c a n S t a t k t i c a l Association, 53, pp.

457-481 (1958).

30. A.V. Peterson, "Expressing the Kaplan-Meier Estimator as a Function of Empirical Subs urvival Functions", J o u r n a l of t h e A m e r i c a n S t a t k t i c a l A s s o c i a t i o n , 72(360), pp. 854-858 (1977).

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

Having discussed what would affect the change of knowledge and having discarded the notion that the rate of change is linear we can now establish a function for determining

Whereas embedded participation describes how economic forecasters produce their forecasts within a network of economists, policy makers, and economic actors, internal participa-

The chapter then offers a comprehensive introduction to the role of knowledge in firms’ internationa- lization processes, and focuses on illustrating how firms acquire foreign market

Unfortunately, current economic theory - even in its 'evolutionary' and 'institutionalist' versions- still falls short of providing comprehensive taxonomies of

Dellacherie, Capacities e t Processus Sochastiques (Capacities and Sto- chastic Processes), Springer-Verlag, Berlin and New York

The three-month treasury bill interest rate was largely influenced by the offered amount of bills set by the issuer, as well as by an estimated market demand, the mandatory bid

The first group, the concerned, believe that knowledge workers will spend more time working from home or local offices, but fear that this shift might reduce business

12 The two percentages do not sum to 100 because of the exclusion of those employed in agricultural and mining occupations... It is evident from the vertical position of the graphs