• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Stochastic Detection Time Concept and its Economic Implications

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Stochastic Detection Time Concept and its Economic Implications"

Copied!
28
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Stochastic Detection Time Concept and its Economic Implications

M. Makowski, T. Ermolieva, M. Jonas, Y. Ermoliev

IFIP/IIASA/GAMM Workshop on Coping with Uncertainty (CwU)

Robust Decisions, December 10-12 2007, IIASA, Laxenburg, Austria

(2)

1. Kyoto protocol and detection of emissions

4. Variability of emissions: “fast” and “slow” systems

5. Emission signal detectability: stochastic detection techniques 6. Emissions trading markets;

b. insurance of carbon credits transactions

Outline

2. Uncertainty (Variability) matters

3. Practical Example: Long time data series

(3)

Kyoto protocol and detection of emissions

Kyoto –

binding commitments to limit or reduce the emissions of six GHGs or groups of gases (CO2, CH4, N2O, HFCs, PFCs, and SF6).

Each Party of the protocol calculates how much of gases its country emits by adding together estimates/reported emissions from individual sources.

Often estimated/reported emissions are inaccurate:

M. Gillenwater & F. Sussman & J. Cohen: Practical Policy Applications of Uncertainty Analysis for National Greenhouse Gas Inventories.

In many countries, agreed emission changes are smaller than their underlying uncertainty.

In IPCC practice, emission/emission changes are reported, but without rigorous signal detection

(4)

S

The key questions:

1. Whether reported emissions outstrip uncertainty and can be “verified/detected” ?

2. What percentage of all possible emissions can be detected within a given time ?

The KP requires that net emission changes be “verified” on the

spatial scale of countries by the time of commitment, relative to

a specified base year.

(5)

Uncertainty (variability) matters

Source: M. Jonas et. al.

Below the target, larger uncertainty

Below the target, smaller uncertainty

Net Emissions

Below the target, larger uncertainty

Above the target, smaller uncertainty

Net Emissions

(6)

Variability matters

Net Emissions

95th confidence =

a ± 2 δ

(7)

95th confidence

A

B

Net Emissions

Base year

Commitment year/period

C

B C

95thconfidence

Variability matters

(8)

Practical examples

Longer data time series on FF, LUC and OU taken from global carbon budget:

http://lgmacweb.env.uea.ac.uk/lequere/co2/carbon_budget.htm

Fossil Fuel Emissions (FF) are estimated from data on the global consumption of coal, oil, and natural gas.

The Land Use Change (LUC) are estimated using a bookkeeping model

updated in August 2006 using revised data from the FAO of the United Nations.

The mean Ocean Uptake (OU) for 1959-2005 is estimated using an ocean general model forced by observed atmospheric conditions of weather and CO2 concentration.

The terrestrial uptake is estimated as a residual of all the sources minus the ocean uptake and atmosphere increase

(Assessment Report 4, WG 1, Ch. 7, 2007, p. 519).

(9)

Variability of emissions:

“fast” and “slow” emissions dynamics

Net Terrestrial Balance

y = 0.1019x + 2.7158 R2 = 0.9845

y = 0.0544x + 1.5985 R2 = 0.9132

y = 0.0236x + 1.3588 R2 = 0.9015

y = 0.0239x - 0.2415 R2 = 0.6931

-4.0 -2.0 0.0 2.0 4.0 6.0 8.0

1959.5 1964.5 1969.5 1974.5 1979.5 1984.5 1989.5 1994.5 1999.5 2004.5

Time

Fluxes to Balance [Pg C/yr]

ff_plus

ffplus_smooth atm_growth atm_smooth ocean_sink ocean_smooth net_terr

net_terr_smooth Fossil Fuels:

strong dynamics, small variability

Net terrestrial:

slow dynamics, large variability

http://lgmacweb.env.uea.ac.uk/lequere/co2/carbon_budget.htm

(10)

Data series

-0.30 -0.25 -0.20 -0.15 -0.10 -0.05 0.00 0.05 0.10 0.15 0.20

Data De-trended Trend

1961 1963 1965 1967 1969

y = 0.0239x - 0.2415 R2 = 0.6931

Net Emissions

(11)

Slow dynamics vs large variability:

Net terrestrial uptake, 1960-1970

More emissions below average ! a±2δ

0 2 4 6 8 10 12

-0.23 -0.21

-0.19 -0.16

-0.14 -0.12

-0.09 -0.07

-0.05 -0.02

0.00 0.02

0.05 0.07

0.09 0.11

0.14

Frequency

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

Frequency Cumulative %

Average: -0.13

95th percentile value: 0.06

Net Emissions Pg C/yr

(12)

More emissions above average ! a±2δ

Slow dynamics vs large variability:

Net terrestrial uptake, 1985-1995

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18

0.09 0.14

0.19 0.24

0.28 0.33

0.38 0.43

0.47 0.52

0.57 0.62

0.66 0.71

0.76 0.81

0.85

Frequency

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

Frequency Cumulative %

Average: 0.6

95th percentile value: 0.79

Net Emissions Pg C/yr

(13)

More emissions below average ! a±2δ

Fast dynamics vs small variability:

Fossil fuel emissions, 1960-1970

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16

2.80 2.83 2.87 2.90 2.93 2.96 2.99 3.02 3.05 3.09 3.12 3.15 3.18

Frequency

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

Frequency Cumulative %

Average: 0.3

95th percentile Value: 0.3

Net Emissions Pg C/yr

(14)

More emissions above average ! a±2δ

Fast dynamics vs small variability:

Fossil fuel emissions, 1985-1995

0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16

5.621 5.650 5.679 5.708 5.737 5.766 5.796 5.825 5.854 5.883 5.912 5.942 5.971

Frequency

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

Frequency Cumulative %

Average: 5.8

95th percentile Value: 6

Net Emissions Pg C/yr

(15)

The need for “detection” of emission shapes

1. In 1960 to 1970, the terrestrial system was mostly a sink.

2. Average flow -0.13. Higher likelihood of flows larger than average.

3. More of probability mass below average

4. In 1985 to 1995, it turned to source. Average flow 0.6.

5. More of probability mass above average.

(16)

Emission signal: detectability

Detect time when emission outstrips the uncertainty represented by a symmetrical interval

t

2

time

t

1

ε ΔF

ΔF> ε at t*=DT

t*=DT

t

2

time

t

1

Net Emissions

(17)

Emission signal: detectability

DT > t2

time

t1 t2

c)

Net Emissions

ε1

ε2

t1 t2

time

b)

Net Emissions

ε1

ε2

DT = t2

t1 t2

time

a)

Net Emissions

ε1

ε2

DT < t2

1 1

2

) ( 1

t t

net

dt d dt

dF t t

 

 

− 

>

∆ ε

ε

(18)

Stochastic detection of emission signal

time

t1 DT < t2 t2

Fmin Fmax

DT > t2

Net Emissions

ε

1

ε

2

(19)

E-sided vs stochastic detection, slow dynamics and large variability:

Net terrestrial uptake, 1965 – 1985

Years

E-sided approach: 7.9 Mean

0.0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

0.00 4.21 8.42 12.63 16.83 21.04 25.25 29.46 33.67 37.88 42.09 46.30 50.50 54.71 58.92 63.13 67.34

Average: 17.7

95th percentile Value: 54.7

Median: 15

E-sided approach: 7.9

(20)

Example 1.

F(t

1

) -0.13 Pg C yr-1

F(t

2

) 0.18 Pg C yr-1

ε(t

1

) 0.16 Pg C yr-1

ε(t

2

) 0.39 Pg C yr-1

dt 20 Pg C yr-1

dε=ε(t

2

)-ε(t

1

) 0.23 Pg C yr-1

|dF

net

|=|F(t

2

)-F(t

1

)| 0.32 Pg C yr-1

VT 7.9 yr

1965–1985

E-sided vs stochastic detection, slow dynamics and large variability:

Net terrestrial uptake, 1965 – 1985

(21)

E-sided vs stochastic detection, fast dynamics vs small variability:

Fossil fuel emissions, 1965 – 1985

Years 0.0

0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 1.0

0.0 0.3 0.5 0.8 1.1 1.4 1.6 1.9 2.2 2.5 2.7 3.0 3.3

95th percentile Value: 3

Median: 0.9 Average: 1.1

E-sided approach: 0.9 Mean

(22)

Economic implications of emissions uncertainties:

stochastic detection techniques

1. Emissions are tradable commodities.

2. Variability of emissions is a key element for pricing commodities:

2.a. Inclusion of various systems (forestry and land use CDMs) in emission trading markets: Carbon Market Europe, 21, 2006. (Available on request)

2.b. Slow dynamic systems (forestry, land use) long response times.

(The “must” for an appropriate emission detection technique - affects prices.) 2.c. Emissions banking: temporal discounting of emissions

2.d. Emissions borrowing

2.e. Initial allowance allocation:

grandfathering,

equal emissions per capita, equal emissions per unit GDP;

spatio-temporal discounting of emissions uncertainties, fairness.

Stochastic detection: what percentile of possible emissions is detectable within a given time interval. This allows to compare and rank the parties in terms of their compliance potential (risks of not compliance).

(23)

Emissions banking and borrowing

Emissions banking: complements emission trading programs

Allows inter-temporal trading of emissions

Effective banking improves environmental performance and reduces cumulative compliance costs

Banking provides flexibility to deal with many uncertainties associated with emissions trading market

http://www.pewclimate.org/docUploads/emissions_trading.pdf Alternative emission trading schemes:

(1) reduction credit trading,

(2) emission rate averaging, and (3) cap-and-trade programs,

Reliability of emissions estimates plays essential role in Inter-temporal discounting and trading of emissions

(24)

A deterministic and a stochastic technique is proposed to find the cost-effective vector of emissions through adaptation of emission charges in successive steps.

Ermoliev, Y., G. Klaassen and A. Nentjes (1996): The design of cost effective

ambient charges under incomplete information and risk. In: E.C. van Ierland and K. Gorka (eds.) Economics of Atmospheric Pollution, NATO ASI Series, Partnership Sub-Series,

2. Environment, V. 14, 123–151, Springer, Berlin, Germany.

Applications of emission detection and

verification techniques for emission control policies

Ermoliev, Y., M. Michalevich and A. Nentjes (2000): Markets for tradable emission and ambient permits: A dynamic approach. Environ. Res. Econ., 15, 39–56.

Sequential trading schemes in pollution permit markets are discussed in stochastic settings. The paper emphasized the need for an appropriate treatment of uncertainties and risks associated with emissions by designing specific risk-adjusted goal functions. Was shown that in order to reach the least-cost solution, the parties must reduce their emissions uncertainties.

Godal O., Y. Ermoliev, G. Klassen and M. Obersteiner (2003): Carbon trading with

imperfectly observable emissions. Environmental and Resource Economics, 25, 151–169.

(25)

 Scheme of sequential bilateral trade (in cap-and-trade scheme) takes into account safety constraints, i.e., risks of underestimating and overestimating real emissions.

 Global least cost solution for all parties.

 Cooperation through the bilateral trading reduces not only the aggregate cost, but this is achieved in a mutually beneficial way reducing individual costs.

 All participating parties create the stable coalition.

 In sequential trading, a stochastic detection technique (SDT) provides information as to what percentile of emissions and variability of a party is detectable in a certain time.

 The (SDT) “informs” the economic model of sequential bilateral trading as to how much and what is the likelihood of “free” emissions that a party can trade.

Sequential bilateral trading of emissions

(26)

Summary

Stochastic detection technique:

Percentage of possible emissions detectable within a given time Contrary to e-sided, captures variability of emissions

Applicable for/to evaluation of carbon related financial instruments (emission trading, investments, Kyoto related mechanisms)

On-going research:

Development of specific risk-adjusted pricing procedures for emissions-related products Clean Development Mechanisms (CDM), Joint Implementation (JI) projects.

CDM (including emission trading) insurance: emissions uncertainties are prices.

Insurance of “skewed” risks of emissions trading is similar to Catastrophic risks insurance.

Emission trading and endogenous discounting: credibility of parties is translated into discounting of emissions permits

Principles for allocation of emissions allowances: pros and cons of grandfathering, fairness, temporal discounting of emission reduction technologies

(27)

Jonas, M., S. Nilsson, R. Bun, V. Dachuk, M. Gusti, J. Horabik, W. Jęda and Z. Nahorski, 2004:

Preparatory Signal Detection for Annex I Countries under the Kyoto Protocol―A Lesson for the Post-Kyoto Policy Process. Interim Report IR-04-024, International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria, pp. 91. Available at:

http://www.iiasa.ac.at/Publications/Documents/IR-04-024.pdf.

Jonas, M. and S. Nilsson, 2007: Prior to an economic treatment of emissions and their uncertainties under the Kyoto Protocol: Scientific uncertainties that must be kept in mind. Water, Air & Soil Pollution: Focus.

Available at: http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11267-006-9113-7.

Nahorski, Z., J. Horabik and M. Jonas, 2007: Compliance and emissions trading under the Kyoto Protocol: Rules for uncertain inventories. Water, Air & Soil Pollution: Focus. Available at:

http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11267-006-9112-8.

Nilsson, S., M. Jonas, V. Stolbovoi, A. Shvidenko, M. Obersteiner and I. McCallum, 2003:

The missing “missing sink”. The Forestry Chronicle, 79(6), 1071−1074.

Pearce, F., 2006: Kyoto promises are nothing but hot air. New Scientist, 22 June.

Available at:

http://environment.newscientist.com/channel/earth/mg19025574.000-kyoto-promises-are-nothing-but-hot-air.html.

Rödenbeck, C., S. Houweling, M. Gloor and M. Heimann, 2003: CO2 flux history 1982–2001 inferred from atmospheric data using a global inversion of atmospheric transport. Atmos. Chem. Phys., 3, 1919–1964.

References

(28)

References

Ermoliev, Y., Klaassen, G., Nentjes, A. The design of cost effective ambient charges under incomplete information and risk. NATO ASI Series, Partnership Sub-Series, 2. Environment, V. 14: Economics of Atmospheric Pollution. Edited by Ekko C. van Ierland and Kazimierz Gorka, Springer Verlag, Berlin-Heidelberg, 1996.

Ermoliev, Y., M. Michalevich and A. Nentjes, 2000: Markets for tradable

emission and ambient permits: A dynamic approach. Environmental and Resource Economics 15, 39–56.

Gillenwater, M., F. Sussman and J. Cohen, 2007: Practical policy applications of

uncertainty analysis for national greenhouse gas inventories. Water, Air & Soil Pollution:

Focus. Available at: http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/s11267-006-9118-2.

Godal, O., 2000: Simulating the carbon permit market with imperfect observations of emissions: Approaching equilibrium through sequential bilateral trade.

IIASA Interim Report IR-00-060, International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis,

Laxenburg, Austria, pp. 25. Available at: http://www.iiasa.ac.at/Publications/Documents/IR-00-060.pdf.

House, J.I., I.C. Prentice, N. Ramankutty, R.A. Houghton and M. Heiman, 2003:

Reducing apparent uncertainties in estimates of terrestrial CO2 sources and sinks.

Tellus 55B, 345–363.

Hudz, H., 2003: Verification Times Underlying the Kyoto Protocol: Consideration of Risk.

Interim Report IR-02-066, International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg,

Austria, pp. 34. Available on the Internet: http://www.iiasa.ac.at/Publications/Documents/IR-02-066.pdf.

Jonas, M., S. Nilsson, M. Obersteiner, M. Gluck and Y. Ermoliev, 1999: Verification Times Underlying the Kyoto Protocol: Global Benchmark Calculations. Interim Report IR-99-062, International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria, pp. 43.

Available on the Internet: http://www.iiasa.ac.at/Publications/Documents/IR-99-062.pdf.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

Plasma and serum brain-derived neurotrophic factor (BDNF) levels and their association with neurocognition in at-risk mental state, first episode psychosis and chronic

DESIGN AND ELEXENTATION OF A STOCHASTIC PROGRAMMING OPTIMIZER WlTH RECOURSE AND

We consider second stage (dynamic stochastic) scheduling problems which are variants of QlpmtnlE£rnax and Q\pmtnlELfj· Even under distributional assumptions on

TABLE 6 Information displayed during iterations 2-1200 (facility location problem, adaptive automatic step size

When we estimate the efficiency gains for regions when moving from the ‘No trading’ to the ‘Domestic sectoral trading’ experiments, we find that regions that gain the most

It would, however, be a mistake to see the “expression ” and “ mood” of this language of mythological poetry as expounded by Novalis to be identi ­ cal with the

Given the definition of the range of typical systems be- haviour in terms of the model output (p. 12), the initial data space should separate in regions giving rise to that be-

Human donor bone of D1 quality (Os femoris) was cut to appropriate size and 6 Conelog implants (Camlog) of 3.8mm diameter (3 implants of osseointegrative surface and 3 of