• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Essays on Approval Voting and Choice-Induced Attitude Change

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Essays on Approval Voting and Choice-Induced Attitude Change"

Copied!
188
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Dissertation zur Erlangung des

akademishen Grades eines Doktors der

Wirtshaftswissenshaften (Dr. rer. pol.)

vorgelegt von

Grani¢, ura Georg

an der Universität Konstanz

Sektion: Politik-Reht-Wirtshaft

Fahbereih: Wirtshaftswissenshaften

Konstanz, 2013

Tag der mündlihen Prüfung: 12. Juli 2013

Referent: Professor Dr. Alós-Ferrer

Referent: Professor Dr. Ursprung

Konstanzer Online-Publikations-System (KOPS)

(2)
(3)

Introdutionand Summary 1

Einleitungund Zusammenfassung 4

1 Two FieldExperiments onApprovalVoting in Germany 8

1.1 Introdution . . . 9

1.2 Design of the Experiment . . . 13

1.3 Results . . . 17

1.3.1 PartiipationStatistis and Voting Behavior . . . 17

1.3.2 Eletion Results . . . 24

1.3.3 General Disussion . . . 30

1.4 Parliaments . . . 37

1.4.1 Results . . . 38

1.5 Approval Voting for Multi-WinnerEletions . . . 44

1.6 Conlusion . . . 47

1.7 Appendix: AdditionalTables. . . 49

2 Politial SpaeRepresentations with Approval Data 55 2.1 Introdution . . . 56

2.2 The Data Set . . . 60

2.3 Spatial ApprovalVoting . . . 62

2.3.1 Data: Party Vote . . . 63

2.3.2 Data: Candidate Vote . . . 70

2.4 Conlusion . . . 73

2.5 Appendix: Spatial ApprovalVoting . . . 76

2.6 Appendix: Auray of the Spatial Representations . . . 80

3 TheProblemof theDividedMajority: Preferene Aggregation Un-

der Unertainty 89

(4)

3.2.2 The Voting Game . . . 99

3.2.3 Nash Equilibriaand Strategi Voting . . . 100

3.3 Results . . . 103

3.3.1 Eletion Results . . . 103

3.3.2 Condoret-Eieny and Coordination Failures . . . . 105

3.3.3 Duverger's Law, CloseRaes, and Ties . . . 115

3.3.4 Individual Behavior . . . 119

3.4 Conlusion . . . 128

3.5 Appendix: Tables . . . 131

3.6 Appendix: ExperimentalMaterials . . . 145

3.7 Appendix: Pre-Test . . . 149

4 Choies and Preferenes: Evidene from Impliit Choies and Re- sponse Times 151 4.1 Introdution . . . 152

4.2 The Present Researh. . . 154

4.3 Experiment1: Ratingsof Holiday Destinations . . . 157

4.3.1 Method . . . 157

4.3.2 Results . . . 158

4.3.3 Disussion . . . 162

4.4 Experiment2: Rankings of HolidayDestinations . . . 164

4.4.1 Method . . . 164

4.4.2 Results . . . 165

4.4.3 Disussion . . . 168

4.5 General Disussionand Conlusion . . . 169

Referenes 171

(5)

1.1 Partiipation in the experiments. . . 18

1.2 Number of ballotsfor the dierent eletions. . . 22

1.3 Messel: Approval vs. Plurality Voting,Constitueny Vote. . . 25

1.4 Konstanz: Approval vs. PluralityVoting, Constitueny Vote. . 26

1.5 Messel: Approval vs. Plurality Voting,List Vote.. . . 28

1.6 Konstanz: Approval vs. PluralityVoting, ListVote. . . 29

1.7 AV results for dierent groups of voters. . . 36

1.8 Fititious parliaments. . . 46

1.9 Messel: Conditional Frequenies, ListVote. . . 49

1.10 Konstanz: Conditional Frequenies, List Vote. . . 50

1.11 Results for the List Vote in Messel and Konstanz in absolute terms. . . 52

2.1 Assoiation matrix for Parties, Messel. . . 64

2.2 Assoiation matrix for Parties, Konstanz. . . 68

2.3 Assoiation matrix for Candidates,Messel. . . 71

2.4 Assoiation matrix for Candidates,Konstanz. . . 72

2.5 Pereptual dierenes ofthedistanes between the modeland the representation, Messel, Party Vote. . . 81

2.6 Cosines of projetions, Messel, Parties. . . 82

2.7 Perentual dierene of the distanes between the modeland the representation, Konstanz, Party Vote.. . . 83

2.8 Cosines of projetions, Konstanz, Parties.. . . 84

2.9 Perentualdierenes of thedistanes between the modeland the representation, Messel, Candidate Vote. . . 85

2.10 Cosines of projetions, Messel, Candidates. . . 86

2.11 Perentualdierenes of thedistanes between the modeland the representation, Konstanz, Candidate Vote. . . 87

2.12 Cosines of projetions, Konstanz, Candidates. . . 88

(6)

3.2 Payo sheduleand indued preferene prole. . . 99

3.3 Sinere strategies, admissible strategies and Nash Equilibria (NEs). . . 101

3.4 Dierenesinoordinationfailureratesbetweenvotingmethods.108 3.5 Dierenes in Condoret-Eieny between voting methods. . 110

3.6 Ballotsast underAV. . . 120

3.7 Panel probitestimates withrandomeets atindividuallevel for AV. . . 122

3.8 Ballotsast underBC. . . 124

3.9 Panel probitestimates withrandomeets atindividuallevel for BC.. . . 125

3.10 Ballotsast underPV. . . 126

3.11 Panel probitestimates withrandomeets atindividuallevel for PV.. . . 127

3.12 Eletion resultsAVfor the dierent series. . . 131

3.13 Eletionsresults of the AVFI treatment, group level. . . 132

3.14 Eletionsresults of the AVII treatment,group level. . . 133

3.15 Eletion resultsBC for the dierent series. . . 134

3.16 Eletionsresults of the BCFI treatment,group level. . . 135

3.17 Eletionsresults of the BCII treatment, group level. . . 136

3.18 Eletion resultsPV for the dierent series. . . 137

3.19 Eletionsresults of the PVFI treatment,group level. . . 138

3.20 Eletionsresults of the PVII treatment, group level. . . 139

3.21 PairwiseWiloxon-Rank-Sum-Testsfordierenesbetweenvot- ingmethods.. . . 140

3.22 Cuzik's trend tests for learningeets withintreatments. . . 141

3.23 Wiloxon-Rank-Sum-Testsfordierenesbetweeninformation treatments. . . 142

3.24 Distributionof ties inall sixtreatments. . . 143

3.25 Duverger's Law and Close Raes. . . 144

(7)
(8)

1.1 Perentageof voters whoapproved ofagiven numberofalter-

natives, both forConstituenyVote(Candidates)and forList

Vote (Parties).. . . 20

1.2 Fititious Parliamentsbasedonthe results ofthe oialele-

tions and experimentaldata. . . 53

1.3 Seat alloations aording to the oial method, Approval

Voting,and SAV. . . 54

2.1 Three-dimensional projetion of the eight-dimensional party

representation, Messel. . . 65

2.2 Three-dimensionalprojetionoftheten-dimensionalpartyrep-

resentation, Konstanz. . . 69

2.3 Three-dimensionalprojetion of the seven-dimensionalandi-

date representation, Messel. . . 86

2.4 Three-dimensional projetion of the four-dimensional andi-

date representation, Konstanz. . . 87

3.1 The fration of won eletionsineah of the six treatments. . . 104

3.2 Coordination failurerates over the ourseof the experiment. . 107

3.3 Coordination Eieny over the ourse of the experiment. . . 109

3.4 Staked umulativeperentage plots for AV. . . 112

3.5 The fration of won eletionfor eahalternativeunder AV. . . 113

3.6 Staked umulativeperentage plots for BC. . . 114

3.7 The fration of won eletionfor eahalternativeunder BC. . . 114

3.8 Staked umulativeperentage plots for PV. . . 115

3.9 The fration of won eletionfor eahalternativeunder PV. . . 116

3.10 The umulativeshare of votes for the rst ranked and seond

ranked alternative. . . 118

(9)

4.1 StandardizedratingspreadsinExperiment1forimpliitpairs

(a, b)

, pooled and onditional on the distane to the alterna-

tives

h

,

l

. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 160

4.2 Average response times in Experiment 1 for all diret pairs,

pooled and onditionalon the distane within the pair. . . 162

4.3 RankingspreadsinExperiment2forimpliitpairs

(a, b)

,pooled

and onditional onthe distane tothe alternatives

h

,

l

. . . . . 166

4.4 Average response times in Experiment 2 for all diret pairs,

pooled and onditionalon the distane within the pair. . . 168

(10)

This dissertation onsists of four self-ontained researh papers, all of

whihwere writteninfulllmentofthe Ph.D requirementsfor the `Dotoral

Programme in Quantitative Eonomis and Finane' at the University of

Konstanz. Eah paper makes up one hapter in this dissertation. Chapter

1, Chapter2, andChapter 3 fous onthe study of one promisingalternative

voting system alled Approval Voting. Chapter 4 is related to the study of

hoie-indued attitudehanges inPsyhology. In the following, I present a

brief overview of the four hapters summarizingthe main ndings.

Chapter 1, entitled `Two Field Experiments on Approval Voting in Ger-

many', is the results of joint work with Carlos Alós-Ferrer (University of

Cologne) and has been published in the Journal Soial Choie and Welfare,

Vol. 39, No. 1, June 2012 , pp. 171-205. To evaluate the empirial onse-

quenesofthe ApprovalVotingmethodinmasseletions,wearriedouttwo

largesale eldexperiments;the rstduringthe2008Hessianstate eletions

in the ommunity of Messel (with 967 partiipants) and the seond during

theBundestageletions2009inKonstanz(with1431partiipants). Wemim-

iked the oial eletionas losely as possible. After asting aballot in the

oialpollingstationsusingthe oialvoting method,theonstituentshad

the opportunity toast a seond vote using ApprovalVoting. The data ol-

letedduringthe twoeldexperimentsallowed ustoexaminethe dierenes

between the outomes of our titiouseletions and the voting system ur-

rentlyinuse. Insummary,ourdataraisethesuspiionthatthetypialimage

of the German politial sene might not faithfully reet voter preferenes,

and that the voting methodurrently employed mightbebiasing it. For in-

stane,inthe aseofKonstanz, the resultsoftheatualeletionandthe one

using ApprovalVoting were radially dierent. Whilein the atual eletion

the onservative CDU won on all fronts, under Approval Voting it was re-

vealed that theGreen Party enjoyed the largest approval, being approved of

(11)

their empirialproperties.

Chapter2isbasedonthe researhpaper`PolitialSpaeRepresentations

with ApprovalData'whihisjointwork withCarlos Alós-Ferrer(University

ofCologne)andisurrentlyintheproessofreviseandresubmitintheJour-

nalEletoralStudies. Theoretialmodelsofspatialompetitionoftenusethe

notion ofleft-rightpositioningof theompetingparties/andidatesin auni-

dimensional politial spae. Estimating the position of parties/andidates

based on mass survey, elite survey or roll all votes data has beome an

importantempirialtask. Reentpubliations providestrong evidenethat,

indeed,positioningoftheompetingatorsfromvariousountriesboilsdown

to a single, left-rightdimensional spatial representation. However, the liter-

ature has paid little attention to atual, i.e., revealed through hoie, data

other than pluralityvoting. Byonsidering spatialrepresentations based on

our ApprovalVotingballot data,we showthatanaurate projetion of the

politial spae requires more than one dimension. Voting methods oer a

piture of the politial opinionof a ountry, state,or ommunity, whih an

be taken as a snapshot of the opinion landsape of a demorati soiety at

a spei point intime. We arguethat suh informationalaspets (e.g., the

aurayofthe snapshot)shouldbetakenintoonsiderationwhenanalyzing

the meritsof dierent voting methods.

Chapter3,entitled`TheProblemoftheDividedMajority: PrefereneAg-

gregation UnderUnertainty',presentstheresultsofaseriesofexperimental

(laboratory) eletionsdesigned toassess and ompare the eletionoutomes

and the individual voting behavior under three voting methods (Approval

Voting, the Borda Count, and Plurality Voting) in a divided majority set-

ting. Divided majority problems are haraterized by an absolute majority

of voters being uniedin strongly opposing one partiular andidate. How-

ever, their support is divided between two (or more) other andidates. If

they fail to ombine eorts and onentrate their support behind one an-

didate, the emerging winner is the andidate they jointly onsider to be

(12)

leaders. Ourresults showthatmulti-votesmethodlike ApprovalVoting and

theBordaCountoutperformPluralityVoting,oordinationfailuresariseless

frequently. Another ruial feature of our design was a manipulationof the

underlying information struture. We departed from a perfet information

framework towards a more realisti setting, in whih (boundedly rational)

voters were only informed about the outomes of previous eletions. The

observed superiority of multi-votes methods is even stronger under inom-

plete information. Our results suggest that, in general, the responsiveness

towards the informationalstruture may serve asanother important dimen-

sion to evaluate the merits of voting methods and an further enrih the

understanding of these methods.

Chapter4,`ChoiesandPreferenes: EvidenefromImpliitChoiesand

Response Times', is the result of joint work with Carlos Alós-Ferrer (Uni-

versity ofCologne), FeiShi(Shanghai JiaoTong University),and Alexander

K. Wagner (University of Cologne) and has been published in the Journal

of Experimental SoialPsyhology, Vol.48,No.6,November2012, pp.1336-

1342. In Eonomis, hoies and preferenes are two sides of the same oin

and formstrong onepts. They are thought of asstable and onsistent. In

Psyhology however, preferenes are a muh softer onept. They merely

reetanindividual'sattitudetowards aset ofobjetsoranevaluativejudg-

mentinthe senseoflikingordislikinganobjet. TheFree-ChoieParadigm

is a lassial paradigm in Psyhology and has been used numerous times

to demonstrate that hoies an feed bak into and alter preferenes. Re-

ently, the Free-Choie Paradigm has been ritiized. It has been argued

that the observed preferene hange might be nothingbut a statistialarti-

fat reated by a self-seletion bias within the paradigm. We design a new

experimentalparadigmwhere hoie-indued preferene hange is measured

and whih improves upon the Free-Choie paradigm by avoiding the sele-

tion bias. Response time measurements in our experiments indiate that

reappraisal proesses are already triggered during deisionmaking.

(13)

DievorgelegteDoktorarbeitbestehtausviereigenständigenForshungsar-

beiten,dieihalsDoktorand imDotoralProgramme inQuantitativeEo-

nomis and Finane an der Universität Konstanz geshrieben habe. Die

einzelnen Forshungsarbeiten stellen jeweils ein Kapitel innerhalb der Dis-

sertation dar. Die ersten drei Kapitel beshäftigen sih thematish mit

der Untersuhung eines alternativen Wahlverfahrens,der sogenannten Wahl

durh Zustimmung. Kapitel 4 ist der aus der Psyhologie bekannten Un-

tersuhung von Einstellungsänderungen, welhe durh Entsheidungen her-

beigeführt werden, zuzuordnen. Es folgt eine kurze Zusammenfassung der

einzelnen Kapitel und der darin enthaltenen Resultate.

Kapitel 1, mit dem Titel Two Field Experiments on Approval Voting

in Germany,istdas Ergebnis einerZusammenarbeitmitCarlosAlós-Ferrer

(Universität zu Köln) und wurde in der wissenshaftlihen Fahzeitshrift

Soial Choie and Welfare, Vol. 39, No. 1, Juni 2012, pp. 171-205, veröf-

fentliht. Um dieempirishe Tragweite der Wahl durh Zustimmung besser

bewerten zu können, führten wir zwei groÿ angelegte Feldversuhe durh.

Der erste Feldversuh (mit 967 Teilnehmern) fand während der hessishen

Landtagswahl 2008 in der Gemeinde Messel statt, der zweite (mit 1431

Teilnehmern) während der Bundestagswahl 2009 in der Stadt Konstanz.

Dabei stelltenwir die Gegebenheiten der entsprehenden amtlihen Wahlen

so gut wie möglih nah. Im Anshluss an der Teilnahme an der amtlihen

Wahl hatten die Wähler Gelegenheit ein weiteres Mal (ktiv) zu wählen.

Bei dieser zweiten (ktiven) Wahl kam dann die Wahl durh Zustimmung

zum Einsatz. Die gesammeltenDaten ermöglihtenes uns, dieUntershiede

zwishendenErgebnissenderamtlihenWahlundunsererenktiven Wahlen

zu untersuhen. Summa summarum legen unsere Ergebnisse nahe, dass

das typishe Bild der deutshen Parteienlandshaft niht den tatsählihen

PräferenzenderWählershaftentsprihtunddassdieamtliheWahlmethode

(14)

der Erst- als auh bei der Zweitstimme die stärkste Kraft war, waren es

die Grünen, die die meiste Zustimmung auf sih vereinen konnten. Die

enorme Bedeutung dieser Beobahtungen stellt klar, dass die theoretishen

und empirishen Eigenshaften alternativer Wahlmethoden erst vollständig

verstanden werden müssen, bevor man sieder Gesellshaft letztendlih vor-

stellen kann.

Kapitel2basiertaufder inZusammenarbeitmitCarlosAlós-Ferrer(Uni-

versitätzuKöln)erstelltenForshungsarbeitPolitialSpaeRepresentations

with Approval Data. Das entsprehende Manuskript bendet sih inÜber-

arbeitung und wird der Fahzeitshrift Eletoral Studies erneut vorgelegt

(revise and resubmit). Theoretishe Modelle räumlihen Wettbewerbs tr-

een häug die Annahme, dass sih im politishen Wettbewerb zueinan-

der stehende Parteien/Kandidaten in einem eindimensionalen politishen

Raum positionieren. DasShätzeneben dieserPositionenmitHilfevonUm-

frageergebnissen, Expertenmeinungen oder Ergebnissen amtliher Abstim-

mungenhatsihzueinerwihtigenempirishenAufgabeentwikelt. Neueste

Forshungsergebnisse bekräftigendietheoretishen Annahmen dahingehend,

dass sih der politishe Wettbewerb in vielen Ländern tatsählih auf nur

eine Dimension im politishen Raum beshränken lässt. Bei den meisten

Shätzungen spielendieeigentlihen Entsheidungender Wählerjedoheine

untergeordnete Rolle. Wir zeigen, dass eine akkurate Projektion des poli-

tishen Raums mehr als eine Dimension benötigt, wenn man für die tat-

sählihe räumlihe Darstellung Wahlentsheidungen heranzieht, die unter

der Wahl durh Zustimmung getroen wurden. Wahlmethoden bilden die

politishe Meinung eines Landes, eines Staates oder einer Gemeinshaft ab

und liefern uns konkrete Momentaufnahmen der Meinungslandshaft inner-

halb einer demokratishen Gesellshaft. Wir vertreten die Auassung, dass

solhe Aspekte (z.B. wie genau diese Momentaufnahmen ausfallen) bei der

Evaluierung von Wahlmethoden mitberüksihtigt werden müssen.

Kapitel 3, mit dem Titel The Problem of the Divided Majority: Pref-

(15)

dieentsprehend getroenen individuellenWahlentsheidungen dreierWahl-

methoden(WahldurhZustimmung,BordaWahl,Mehrheitswahl)miteinan-

der zu vergleihen. Der Fokuslaghierbeiauf den sogenannten Divided Ma-

jority Problemen. Dieselassensihwie folgtbeshreiben. Füreine absolute

Mehrheit anWählernstellt einbestimmter Kandidatdieeindeutig shleht-

este Lösung dar. Die Mehrheit ist sih jedoh niht darüber einig, welher

Kandidat die beste Lösung darstellt. Gelingt es der Mehrheit niht ihre

Anstrengungen zu bündeln und einen einzigen Kandidatenzu unterstützen,

gewinnt derKandidat, den siealseindeutig shlehteste Optionwahrnimmt.

Das Auftreten eines solhen paradoxen Ergebnisses (Kandidaten gewinnen

eine Wahl, obwohl sie für eine absolute Mehrheit an Wählern das shleht-

este Ergebnis darstellen) kann den demokratishen Prozess im Allgemeinen

behindern, da die politishe Legitimität der gewählten Kandidaten unter-

graben wird. Unsere Ergebnisse zeigen, dass Wahlmethoden wie die Wahl

durh Zustimmung oder die Borda Wahl die Mehrheitswahl in dem Sinne

dominieren,dass dieKoordinationsbemühungenderMehrheit seltenershei-

tern. EinweitererwihtigerAspektunseresExperimentsistdieexpliziteMa-

nipulation derzugrunde liegendenInformationsstruktur. Wirzeigen,dass in

einer realistisheren Umgebung, in denen Teilnehmern nur die Information

bezüglihvergangener Wahlen zur Verfügungsteht, diebeobahtete Domin-

anz sogar noh verstärkt wird. Unsere Ergebnisse legen nahe, dass die In-

formationsstrukturerheblihen Einuss aufWahlergebnissehaben kann und

somit dieInteraktionen zwishen Information und Wahlmethode einen weit-

eren wihtigen Aspektbeider Beurteilungvon Wahlmethoden darstellt.

Kapitel 4, Choies and Preferenes: Evidene from Impliit Choies

and Response Times, ist das Ergebnis einer Zusammenarbeit mit Carlos

Alós-Ferrer (Universität zu Köln), FeiShi (Shanghai JiaoTong Universität)

und Alexander K. Wagner (Universität zu Köln). Die Forshungsarbeit

wurde in der wissenshaftlihe Fahzeitshrift Journal of Experimental So-

ialPsyhology,Vol.48,No.6,November2012,pp.1336-1342,veröentliht.

(16)

ein viel weiheres Konzept. Präferenzen reektieren hier lediglih die Ein-

stellung eines Individuums gegenüber einer Menge an Objekten oder eine

wertende Beurteilung eben dieser. Mit Hilfe des Free-Choie Paradigmas

in der Psyhologie wurde shon häug demonstriert, dass Entsheidungen

Rükkopplungseekte auf Präferenzen ausüben und diese sogar beeinussen

undändernkönnen. InletzterZeitwurdedasFree-ChoieParadigmaoftkri-

tisiert. DiedurhEntsheidungenherbeigeführtenÄnderungenderPräferen-

zen sollen nihts weiter als ein statistishes Artefakt sein, welhe durh

Selbstselektionsprozesse, dieim Paradigmaselbst verankert sind, verursaht

werden. Wir haben diese Kritikpunkte aufgegrien und unsererseits ein

verbessertes Paradigmakonstruiert,welhesSelbstselektionsprozesse vermei-

det undindem Präferenzänderungentrotzdem gemmesenwurden. Die Mes-

sung vonReaktionszeiteninunserem Experimentdeutetdaraufhin,dass die

fürdieNeubewertungzuständigendieProzesseshonwährenddereigentlihen

Entsheidungsndung aktiv sind.

(17)

in Germany

(18)

1.1 Introdution

SoialChoieisadismalsiene. Inanyintrodutorysoialhoieourse,the

young,naïveundergraduateisdeliveredatleasttwoheavyblows. First,heor

sheistoldthatArrow'sImpossibilityTheorem(Arrow,1963)establishesthat

there exists no non-ditatorial voting method satisfying a few mild-looking

onditions. Seond, the student is shown that the Gibbard-Satterthwaite

Theorem (Gibbard, 1973; Satterthwaite, 1975) implies that any reasonable

voting method is manipulable by strategi voters. Afterwards, he or she

mightbeonfronted withaseletionofsomeofthe many otherimpossibility

results whih have been established, while the positive results oered as a

ompensation will typially require stringent assumptions, as e.g. severely

restrited preferene domains.

Few of these fatsseem to have perolated to the generalpubli, and in-

deeddisussionsonthedesignofatualvotingmethodstouseinthepolitial

arenararely involvesoialhoie theorists. One possiblereasonissimplythe

bluntness of the message arriedby impossibilityresults. If all methods are

awed, manyyoungundergraduatesreason,soialhoiehasnothingtooer

to soiety.

Of ourse, some methods are more awed than others, and arguments

havebeen putforwarde.g. fortheBordaCount(Saari,1994)ontheaount

that it (very roughly) minimizes the amount of paradoxes within ertain

sets of votingmethods. OtherargumentsfavorApprovalVoting(Bramsand

Fishburn, 1978), whih is the objet of study in this paper. Again, few of

these arguments have transpired to atual politial eletions. Most of the

eletions inthe western world are run aording toslightly pathed variants

of the plurality voting system, whih an probably be argued to be one of

the most awed systems in existene.

Under plurality voting, eahvoter isonstrained toast a singlevote for

his or her preferred andidate. This way, voters annot express any part of

their preferenes ortastes butanalleged maximum,whihmakes itpartiu-

larly easyfor paradoxesto appear. Insome atual eletions, suh paradoxes

have been partiularly transparent and have resulted in soialand politial

(19)

turmoil. One infamous example ourred in the 2002 Frenh presidential

eletions, where right-extremistJean-MarieLe Pen tookseond plaein the

rst round of the presidential eletions although 80% of voters in the se-

ond round voted against him; arguably, the rst-round outome resulted in

adistorted imageofthe Frenhpolitiallandsapeatthe internationallevel.

Another often-ited example is the ase of the 1998 governor eletions in

Minnesota, where the former professionalwrestler Jesse `the body' Ventura

won, although, allegedly, 64% of voters atually preferred any of the other

two major andidates.

Whether the problems with plurality voting have been understood at a

formal or merely at an intuitive level, some ountries have sought to avoid

these problems by either modifying the eletoral rules, or introduing other

voting systems. Forexample, run-o ballotsinFrane and multiple votes in

Germany (see below) represent attempts by these ountries to give voters a

furtheropportunitytoexpresstheirwisheswhileessentiallykeepingavariant

of pluralityvoting. A prominentexample of analternativevoting methodis

the Australian ase, where the `Single Transferable Vote' (or Instant Run-

o) method is employed. In this system the voters provide a omplete list

in ranking order of their preferred andidates. The results are determined

through an algorithm that progressively eliminates the weakest andidates

until an absolute majority is reahed. However, omplex voting methods

bringnewproblems oftheirown,andithasbeen arguedthattheymighte.g.

make the hanes for strategimisrepresentation ofvoters' preferenes more

obvious, exaerbating the problem identied in the Gibbard-Satterthwaite

Theorem.

In this paper, we are onerned with (the empirial testing of) a very

simple voting method, whih from a sienti point of view oers a viable

alternative to plurality voting. This method is known as `Approval Voting'

(as introdued by Brams and Fishburn, 1978) and is for example used for

the eletionofthegeneralseretaryofthe UnitedNations. InApprovalVot-

ing, the voters may vote for as many andidates asthey wish. To alulate

the eletionresult, the numberof votes for eah andidate are ounted. Ar-

guments have been put forward in the literature that the Approval Voting

(20)

methodprovidesanauratereetionofvoters'wishesandisnotvulnerable

to voter manipulation (see Brams and Fishburn, 1978; Fishburn, 1978a,b;

Brams and Fishburn, 2005; Wolitzky, 2009).

1

Additionally, the Approval

Voting method is more likely to lead to a onsensus vote than polarizing

the eletorate. It also redues the risk of `smear ampaigns' (Brams and

Fishburn, 1978; these often arise in eletions in the U.S. and are beoming

moreprevalentinEurope), beausetheandidatesarealsodependentonthe

approval by voters who alsosupport other politial parties.

There is, however, no universal agreement among soial hoie theorists

as to whih alternativemethod should be put forward as a replaement for

plurality voting. Insofar as analytial results are onerned with rational

deision makers who perfetly understand the involved methods and their

onsequenes, pratial objetions are likely to be raised at any theoreti-

ally solid reommendation. In our opinion, the debate is likely to remain

onstrained to the aademi world unless the sienti ommunity is able

to provide empirial results on the performane of possible alternatives in

real-world voting situations. In other words, we advoate the use of eld

experiments in order to obtain hard data on the outomes and proedural

diultiesoftheoretiallydesignedvotingmethodsunderrealistionditions

(or, toborrowa linefrom psyhology,eologiallyvalid onditions).

Approval Voting has meanwhile been adopted by a number of sienti,

engineering, and professional soieties. This has generated a fair amount

of data on small-saleeletions, whih have been reported on in e.g. Brams

and Fishburn (1988) (Mathematial Assoiation of Ameria), Brams and

Fishburn (2001) (Soial Choie and Welfare Soiety), and Brams and Kil-

gour (2010) (Game Theory Soiety); see Brams and Fishburn (2005) for a

more general perspetive. Movingto politialeletions, Laslier and Van der

Straeten (2004; 2008) and Baujard and Igersheim (2009, 2010) onduted

two eld experiments onApproval Voting during the 2002 and 2007 Frenh

presidential eletions.

1

However,regardingmanipulabilityorstrategy-proofness,ApprovalVotinglearlybe-

longs to a dierent formal framework, and hene not to the domain of voting methods

overedbytheGibbard-SatterthwaiteTheorem (Gibbard,1973;Satterthwaite,1975).

(21)

The empirial evidene olleted in those studies has provided new in-

sights into the atual funtioning of the Approval Voting method, and ad-

ditionally shown that the urrently used voting methods an lead to results

that do not represent the real wishes of the eletorate. For example, whilst

the oial voting methodgave LePen seondplaeinthe 2002 Frenhele-

tions,theApprovalVotingmethodgavehimonly12thplae. Thusaording

to this method, Le Pen would not have been a serious ontender for pres-

ideny, a onlusion whih might have been more in aordane with the

atual wishes of the eletorate asexpressed in the seond round of the 2002

eletions.

Inthis paper,wereportontwoseparateeld experimentswhihwe have

onduted in Germany. The partiularities of the German eletoral system

allowedustosimultaneously olletdata ontwoqualitativelydierentvotes

per experiment. Germany uses a mixed-member proportional representa-

tion system in whih voters are asked to ast two distint votes, one for a

andidate and one for a party. Thus the only natural way to ondut the

experiments was to alsoask voters toprovide approval ballots both for dis-

trit andidates and state or federal parties. Hene we olleted data for a

total of four eletions. This has provided us with a unique data set with

two observations per voter, inludingdata on the performane of Approval

Voting forparty eletions, aontextthe methodwasnot originally designed

for.

The rst experiment took plae in the town of Messel during the 2008

state eletions in Hesse, while the seond one was onduted in the ity of

Konstanz during the 2009 federal eletions. These eld experiments have

provided uswith a number of insights,whih an beorganized in three at-

egories. First, the experiments themselves serve to establish the pratial

appliability of a given voting method in large eletions. In partiular, it is

importanttoondut experimentsindierentountriesand witheletorates

whihareused todierentvoting systems. Seond, by omparingtheresults

in our experimentsto the ones of the simultaneous, oial eletions, we ob-

tain arediblemeasureofthe degreeofdistortionduetotheoialeletoral

system. Third, the results serve to establish the empirial validity of vari-

(22)

ous theoretialarguments onthe advantages and disadvantagesof Approval

Voting.

The paper isstrutured as follows. Setion1.2desribes howthe experi-

ments were onduted. Setion 1.3presents the data, omparingthe experi-

ments'resultstotheresultsoftheoialvote,restritedtotheonstituenies

we olleted data in. Setion 1.4 then presents titious Parliaments built

aording to our experimental data as a straightforward, graphial way to

examinethepossibleimpliationsofApprovalVoting. Setion1.5brieydis-

usses theimpliationsfortheSatisfationApprovalVoting methodreently

proposedby Bramsand Kilgour(2010). Setion1.6onludes. Inaompan-

ion paper (Alós-Ferrer and Grani¢, 2012a), we use our dataset in order to

obtain spatial representations of parties and andidates in an endogenously

determined politial spae, following the method of Laslier (2006).

1.2 Design of the Experiment

In ooperation with the ompetent state and federal authorities, we devel-

oped a design for the experiments ensuring an absolutely undisturbed and

regular oial eletion. Further, we tried to mimi the oial eletion as

losely as possible. We established one experimentalpolling station ineah

of the preseleted polling stations. Our titious polling stations were set

up in the immediate viinity of the oial ones, i.e. they were loated in

the same buildings, but in separate rooms. In eah of our stations, ballot

boxes were provided by ourtesy of the ommunities. Before the eletion,

all registered voters reeived a letter in whih the methodwas explained to

them and inwhih they were invitedtopartiipateinthe experiment. After

asting a ballotin the oial polling stations, apaper slipwas handed over

to the voters by the polling lerks whih qualied them for partiipation in

the experiment. This proedure ensured that voters' deisions in the o-

ial eletion were not inuened by our presene, and also that only those

onstituents who atually went to the polls ould take part in the titious

vote. Assistants fromthe University of Konstanz were assignedto eah one

of our stations. Theirtask was toollet the partiipationpapers, hand out

(23)

the titiousballot papers, and olletthem bak after the voters had lled

them in. Before the eletion, the ommunities provided us with an oial

ballot paper, so that the same parties and andidates were available in the

experimentsas inthe oialeletions andwere namedand desribed in the

same way.

Germanfederal eletions, andmost of thestate ones,are idiosynrati in

that voters are asked to ast two dierent votes. The rst, for the distrit

eletion(Wahlkreisstimme fortheStateEletioninHesseandErststimme

forthefederalEletioninGermany,respetively)isgiventoaandidate,and

theresultsaredeterminedbythewinner-takes-allproedurewithsimplema-

jority. We will refer to this rst vote as the Constitueny Vote. That is,

eahdistriteletsonememberofparliamentindependentlyofotherdistrits.

Before the eletion, eah parliament has a theoretial number of seats; half

of those seats are alloatedthrough this method (diret seats). The seond

vote, (the Landesstimme for the State Eletion and the Zweitstimme for

the FederalEletion),determines (following aproportionalsystem) the per-

entage of the total seats in the parliament tobe alloatedto eah dierent

partywhihreahesatleast5%ofthevotes.

2

Eahpartyprovidesadditional

andidates(omplementingthediretseats)outofapredeterminedlist,until

the total number of seats it should reeive aording to the seond vote is

reahed. This an atually ause ompliations whih might lead to minor

adjustments in the eetive size of the parliament.

3

We will refer to this

seond vote as the List Vote. The partiularities of the German eletoral

systems allowed ustoolletdata onfoureletionswiththe helpoftwoeld

experiments. Further, in sharp ontrast to the Frenh presidential eletion

experimentsin2002(LaslierandVanderStraeten, 2008)and2007 (Baujard

and Igersheim, 2009, 2010), we ould adopt and test a variant of Approval

Votingwithinaparty-based,proportionalrepresentationframework. Tobest

2

Ifapprovalvotingwouldbeusedinsteadoftheoialmethod, therewouldbequali-

tativelydierentpossibilitiesforthedenitionofsuhthresholds. SeeSetion1.4.

3

Diulties appearifapartymanagestoapturealargernumberofdiretseatsthan

the total perentagewould allow it to have, or if aparty whih does not reah the 5%

barrierobtainssomediretseats. Theseproblemsareessentiallydealtwithbyinreasing

thenumberofseatsin parliament.

(24)

of our knowledge, this possibility has reeived no or very littleattention in

the literature up to this point (Bramsand Kilgour 2010 is a notable exep-

tion). Hene,althoughApprovalVoting istypiallyonsideredforandidate

eletionsonly,itwasnatural,inoursetting,toaskvoterstoprovideapproval

ballots both for distrit andidates and state/federal parties.

OialballotsinGermanyare large sheetsof paperdividedvertially in

twoparts,onefortheConstituenyandonefortheListvote. Theandidates

and parties are listed aordingto the ranking ofthe parties inthe previous

eletion, i.e.the partieswhih obtained the most votes in the previous ele-

tions are at the top of the list. Voters hand in their votes for parties and

andidatessimultaneously,althoughtheyan ofoursedeideindependently

whihpartyand whihandidatetosupport. Forour experiments,the om-

petent authorities requested us not touse exat reprodutions of the oial

ballots in order to avoid any possible onfusion. We agreed to use separate

sheetsofpaper(ofdierentolors)forConstituenyandListvotes,buteah

voter was given both sheets of paper simultaneously and requested to hand

them in within a single envelope. Our experimental ballots were otherwise

identialtothe oialones, downtotheir graphialdesign. Candidatesand

parties werelisted inthesame orderasinthe oialballot,weprovided the

exat same information on parties and andidates (name, address, oupa-

tion), et. The main dierenewas that, ontop of the experimentalballots,

the word Zustimmungsverfahren (Approval Voting)was printed.

Forourrstexperiment,weseletedtheGermanstateofHesse. The2008

eletionsinthisstatewereexpetedtobeverylose,whihmadetheeletion

espeially interesting.

4

Indeed, afterthe eletions, the involved parties were

unable to form a new government and new eletions had to be alled for

almost exatlyone year later.

The experiment was arried out in the relatively small German town of

Messelonstateeletionday,January27 th

2008. Thisommunityisloatedin

South Hesse and belongsto the voting distritDarmstadt-DieburgI. It on-

4

For instane, aording to a survey with 1000 partiipants onduted by the rm

infratest-dimap on January 14-16, 2008 for the German national television, 38% of the

votersplannedtosupportSPD,while37%expressedanintentiontovotefortheCDU.See

http://www.wahlreht.de/umfragen/landtage/hessen.htm,lastaessedMarh14,2011.

(25)

tains three separate polling stationsthat we willrefertoas Messel I, Messel

II, and Messel III.

5

The lastone orresponds to asmall, nearby dependeny

loatedoutside the town.

WiththeexpliitpermissionandfriendlysupportoftheHessianMinistry

for the Interior and for Sport, the head eletion organizer (Mr. Wolfgang

Hannappel), the mayor of the Messel distrit (Mr. Udo Henke), and the

eletionommissioner(Mr.DieterLehr), weinstalledseparate votingbooths

in eah of the three dierent voting areas in the Messel distrit. A total

of 3017 eligible voters, of whih 1909 personally took part in the oial

eletion,were dividedamongstthe threevotingstationsMessel I,II,andIII,

with 1326, 1401 and 290 registered voters respetively.

The seond experiment was arried out on September 27 th

2009 during

the nationwide GermanFederaleletionsinKonstanz,a ityinthe southern

GermanstateofBaden-Württembergwhihispartofthedistritofthesame

name. As in Konstanz itself and most of Germany, the onservative party

(CDU)wasexpetedtoreeiveasimplemajoritybothforthedistriteletion

and the party-list eletion. The relatively large number of registered voters

(57727), fored us to restrit our study to a few of the total 65 polling sta-

tions. Withthe help of the loalauthorities,we identied 6polling stations

that we onsidered as pratial for our purposes (on the basis of represen-

tativeness and pratial riteria) with a total of 5526 registered voters, of

whih2879tookpartintheoialeletionpersonally. Wewillrefertothese

pollingstationsasKonstanzI toKonstanzVI; they had856, 728,810, 1010,

1157, and 965 eligiblevoters respetively.

6

Withthe expliit permissionand

friendly support of the federal eletion organizer (Mr. Roderih Egeler), the

state eletion organizer (Mrs. Christiane Friedrih), the eletion organizer

in the DistritOe (Mr. Manfred Roth), and the eletion ommissionerof

Konstanz (Mr. Raphael Wiedemer-Steidinger), we installed separate voting

booths ineah of the six pre-seleted voting areas in Konstanz.

Before we report on the results of our experiments, we would like to re-

5

TheatualnamesofthestationsareHausderVereine,Kindergarten,andGrube

Messel,respetively.

6

TheatualnamesofthestationsareRathaus,WallgutshuleI,WallgutshuleII,

WallgutshuleIII,ParkstiftRosenau andGeshwister-ShollShule,respetively.

(26)

markthat, asin any othereld experiment, the emphasis wasplaed onob-

taining data underrealisti onditions. Foravoting experiment,this means

arrying out the experiment with atual voters on an atual eletion day.

Hene, we neessarilyhave towork with animpliitwithin design, i.e.our

experimental subjets voted aording to the oial method before taking

part in our experiment. Ideally, one would like to work with a between-

subjet design wherepartiipantsare randomlyassigned toone orthe other

voting method. While this is learly not possible in a eld experiment on

voting (if ondutedon anatualeletion day), between-subjet designs are

perfetly feasible in the laboratory. On the other hand, laboratory exper-

iments have lear disadvantages with respet to eld experiments, e.g. a

smaller number of partiipants and a lower level of external validity. For

these reasons, we vieweld and laboratory experimentsas omplementary.

1.3 Results

1.3.1 Partiipation Statistis and Voting Behavior

All registered voters were informed by a letter about the experiment that

was going to take plae during the Eletion Day on January 27 th

, 2008 in

Messel, respetively onSeptember 27 th

, 2009 inKonstanz, and were invited

to partiipate. The statistis for the partiipation in the experiments are

presented in Table 1.1. Sine only the urn voters are onsidered as being

potential experiment partiipants, we exluded those voters who registered

in order to ast a vote per post (292 in the ase of Messel and 1308 in the

ase ofKonstanz) fromall oialstatistis.

Insummary,of the 1909 voters who atually wenttothe pollsinMessel,

967 partiipants (50.7%)took their time toast their approval ballotin our

experiment. A totalof 6invalidvotes were ast intheexperiment'seletion,

sothat 961ballots areavailableforthe desriptiveanalysisof the results. In

Konstanz, of the 2879 voters who atually went to the polls, 1431 (49.7%)

partiipated in the experiment. Only two invalid ballots were ast for the

Constitueny Vote and one for the List Vote. Our sample thus onsists of

(27)

Table 1.1: Partiipation in the experiments.

Regis- Oial Eletion Approval Voting Eletion

Station tered Parti. Invalid Parti. Invalid %

Messel I 1192 847 20/28 461 4/4 54.4%

Messel II 1256 902 19/20 407 2/2 45.1%

Messel III 277 160 5/5 99 0/0 61.9%

TOTAL 2725 1909 44/53 967 6/6 50.7%

KonstanzI 605 409 3/2 234 0/0 57.2%

KonstanzII 570 389 5/9 165 0/0 42.4%

KonstanzIII 617 376 0/1 218 0/0 58.0%

KonstanzIV 784 532 7/11 261 1/0 49.1%

KonstanzV 860 649 8/8 301 1/1 46.4%

KonstanzVI 782 524 7/10 252 0/0 48.1%

TOTAL 4218 2879 30/41 1431 2/1 49.7%

Invalid: the rstnumber denotesthe invalid votes forthe List Vote, the seond for

the Constitueny Vote. The perentage indiates the share of voters in the oial

eletion who tookpartin the experiment.

(28)

1429 observations for the Constitueny Vote and 1430 observations for the

ListVote. Thisrelativelylargedatasetensures statistialsignianeforthe

omparison between our results andthe oialresults inMessel. Compared

to the eld experiments onduted in Frane, our partiipation rates are

lower. In the 2002 experiment (see Laslier and Van der Straeten, 2008), the

partiipationratewas77.6%,inthe2007experiment(BaujardandIgersheim,

2009, 2010), the rate was 61.6%. The dierenes an mainly be attributed

to the fat that, in addition to the information letter and the artile in

the muniipal bulletin, information meetings were sheduled in eah town

the experimentswere onduted in,whihunfortunately was notfeasible for

our purposes. The 2007 experiment further made use of information spots

transmitted via loal radio and national TV. A stable phenomenon aross

both the eld experiments in Frane and our two eld experiments is the

fat thatthe rates of spoiled ballotsare extremely low(stritly smallerthan

0.7% for allfour eld experiments).

Theommunitiesthemselvesaretoosmalltodrawsigniantimpliations

for the whole (federal) state. In the following, whenever the oial results

areomparedtothoseoftheexperiment,andwheneveronlusionsaremade

fromonetotheotherorpolitialimpliationsaredrawn, theywillbealways

madefortheommunityitself,ortobemorepreise,tothesetofurnvoters,

not the (federal) state.

7

,

8

Twooftheobjetivesofourexperimentsweretotesttheappliabilityand

thegeneralaeptaneofApprovalVotingamongthepopulation. Compared

to the oial voting method,Approval Voting gives voters more options to

express their will. For instane, with six andidates for the Constitueny

Vote inKonstanz, there are sixdierentvalidballotsavoter an ast under

the oial method, and there are

2 6

dierent ways to ast a ballot under

7

However, assuming an equal distribution of List Votes in Hesse and in Messel, the

orresponding

χ 2

goodness-of-ttestwith10degreesoffreedomyieldsa

p

-valueof0.369.

We anonludethatthe ommunityisnot signiantlydierent fromthe stateforthe

ListVoteoutome.

8

AssuminganequaldistributionofListVotesinoursixpre-seletedpollingstationsand

in Konstanz,theorresponding

χ 2

goodness-of-ttest with 12degreesof freedomyields a p-value of 0.477. We an onlude that our six polling stations are not signiantly

dierentfrom thewhole ofKonstanzfortheList Vote.

(29)

Approval Voting. A simpler way to represent the general voting behavior

of the partiipantsis togroup themaording to the numberof alternatives

theyapproved of. Figure1.1givesagraphialrepresentationoftheaggregate

data, andTable1.2presentsthedetaileddataforindividualpollingstations.

Figure 1.1: Perentage of voters who approved of a given number of alternatives,

both for Constitueny Vote (Candidates) and forList Vote (Parties).

(a) Messel

(b) Konstanz

The highest number of approvals for the andidates was eight in Messel

(that is, one voter just approved of all andidates) and ve in Konstanz,

respetively eight and seven for the List Vote. A large proportion of the

onstituents ast ballots with one, two or three approvals. Indeed, for all

four experimental eletionsthe mode of approvals perballot is two.

(30)

A signiant group of voters ast single vote ballots for the andidates,

traingthelineaftertherst andidateintheirpreferene proleasthey are

fored to do under plurality voting. Close examination of Table 1.2 for the

Konstanz experimentrevealsadisrepanyof168ballotsbetweenvoterswho

approved of asingle andidate and asingle party. Sine voters handed their

ballots forandidates andparties withinasingle envelope,wean ount the

voters who simultaneously approved of one andidate and one party only.

This amounts to 218 partiipants in Messel and 192 in Konstanz. In other

words, 77.31%of the valid votes inMessel and 86.56% of the validvotes for

the Constitueny Vote, respetively, 86.66% for the List Vote in Konstanz

ame from voters who atually deided to ast ballots whih they are not

allowed toast under pluralityvoting.

9

The meannumber ofapprovalsappears tobe anidiosynrati harater-

isti of eah eletion, most probably aruing to the politial limateof the

moment. Forinstane, voters inKonstanzapproved ofmoreandidatesthan

inMessel. Thisholdstruebothforthe ConstituenyVote(two-samplet-test

with unequal samplesize and variane, p-value 0.041), where atually there

were less available andidates in Konstanz than in Messel, and for the List

Vote, with equal number of available parties (p-value <0.001). The mean

number of approvals, however, does not dier signiantly among polling

stations for a xed experiment (Messel or Konstanz) and type of vote (an-

didate and party).

10

The only exeption is a partiular polling station in

Konstanz (Konstanz V), and only for the ase of ListVote.

11

9

Whethervoterswhoapprovedofonlyoneandidateandonepartyatuallyexpressed

a preferene for doing sois notentirelylear. Some voters might havebeen inuened

by theirpartiipation in theoial vote before taking partin the experiment. Further,

anedotal evidene, in the form of ommentswereeivedduring and after theeletions,

pointsoutthatthis behaviormightarueto simpleresistanetohange: Havingvoted

forsoand somanyyearsinthe pastbygivingonlyonepartymysupport,whyshould I

hangemyvotingbehavior?

10

An alternativeexplanation (suggested by M. Behtel) for the larger number of ap-

provalsin Konstanz is as follows. The Konstanz eletion was a Federal one, while the

Messel onewas astate eletion. Votersmight onsiderstateeletions, ompared to fed-

eralones,to beseondordereletions andhenebelessinformedaboutandidatesand

parties' programs,whihmightinturn resultin alowernumberofapprovals.

11

Weondutedpairwiset-teststo hekfordierenesinthemeansandorretedthe

overallalphafailure withtheHolm-Bonferronimethod. Thenullhypothesis anonlybe

(31)

Table 1.2: Number of ballots for the dierent eletions.

Approvals 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7

8 Mean

Messel: Constitueny Vote (Options: 8)

Messel I 12 148 207 65 21 3 0 0 1 1.891 (0.939)

Messel II 2 151 173 73 5 1 0 0 0 1.830 (0.784)

Messel III 2 38 39 14 6 0 0 0 0 1.838 (0.907)

Overall 16 337 419 152 32 4 0 0 1 1.860 (0.874)

Messel: ListVote (Options: 17)

Messel I 5 106 190 92 40 14 9 0 1 2.306 (1.184)

Messel II 0 113 163 81 35 11 1 1 0 2.198 (1.063)

Messel III 0 31 34 27 3 1 0 3 0 2.202 (1.231)

Overall 5 250 387 200 78 26 10 4 1 2.250 (1.141)

Konstanz: Constitueny Vote (Options: 6)

Konstanz I 3 72 111 41 7 0 0 1.902 (0.803)

Konstanz II 0 43 89 28 5 0 0 1.970 (0.742)

Konstanz III 3 50 116 46 3 0 0 1.982 (0.740)

Konstanz IV 2 78 124 48 7 1 0 1.927 (0.816)

Konstanz V 2 95 148 48 7 0 0 1.877 (0.763)

Konstanz VI 2 62 125 55 8 0 0 2.020 (0.789)

Overall 12 400 713 266 37 1 0 1.943 (0.779)

Konstanz: List Vote (Options: 17)

Konstanz I 0 32 75 73 38 14 0 2 0 2.722 (1.153)

Konstanz II 1 23 69 42 20 6 3 1 0 2.558 (1.167)

Konstanz III 0 29 73 79 22 12 1 2 0 2.662 (1.121)

Konstanz IV 0 45 95 80 26 10 3 2 0 2.533 (1.146)

Konstanz V 0 68 133 61 29 5 4 0 0 2.273 (1.051)

Konstanz VI 0 35 91 75 30 14 6 1 0 2.679 (1.197)

Overall 1 232 536 410 165 61 17 8 0 2.557 (1.148)

Options= available options (8 andidates and 17parties in Messel, 6 andidates

and 17partiesin Konstanz). Mean olumn: Numbers in brakets are Std. errors.

(32)

In partiular, we annot support the onlusion of Laslier and Van der

Straeten (2008) that voters, ingeneral, onaverage approve of three alterna-

tives. Their partiipants on average approved of 3.15 out of 16 andidates

(where atotalof2587ballotswereast). Atually,themeansofapprovalsfor

theListVoteareofomparablemagnitudetotheoneinthe2007Frenhpres-

identialeletion experiment by Baujard and Igersheim (2009,2010) (Laslier

and Van der Straeten 2008 olleted data in the 2002 eletion). In this

experiment, 2813 partiipants on average approved of 2.23 out 12 feasible

andidates. Althoughthe dierenes invotingbehavior between Frenhand

German voters would be worth a study on its own, with the given data it

is impossible to identify the determiningfators without entering the realm

of speulation. Dierent numberof feasible alternatives, polarizingeletions

and the dierent methodsemployed learly play aruial role. On an even

oneive of some as yet not identied psyhologial or ultural fator that

mightalso inuene the dierenes inbehavior.

Sinewe an identify the numberofapprovalsfor andidatesand parties

for eah individual voter, we have data on two approval deisions for eah

voter and an ompute the orrelation between both variables. Pearson's

orrelation between number of approvals for andidates and for parties in

Messel was 0.598 (Spearman's

ρ = 0.652

). In the ase of Konstanz, the or-

relation was 0.483 (Spearman's

ρ = 0.509

). Of ourse, voting deisions for

andidates and for partiesin agiven eletionhave tobe expeted toexhibit

some orrelation. However, these orrelationsan alsoindiatethat individ-

ualvarianeinthenumberofapprovalsfollowspartlypersonalharateristis

of the voters.

The numberof approvalsinreases from Constitueny Vote to ListVote,

both in Messel and in Konstanz. The data set from the rst experiment

shows that 295 eletors approved of more parties than of andidates but

only 59voters did the opposite. ForKonstanz, the numbers are 630 and 90,

respetively. Although one ould formulate the hypothesis that the number

rejetedfortheaseofListVoteinKonstanz,andonlyforomparisonsinvolvingKonstanz

V, whihwasloatedin aresidenefortheelderlyandhadasigniantlyhigheraverage

voteragethanotherpollingstations.

(33)

of approvals is larger in the ase of List Vote simply beause the available

number of alternatives is larger, we annot test this hypothesis beause the

twodeisionsarenotomparable. Castingvotesfortheandidatesisnotthe

same as asting votes for the parties behind those andidates. Forexample,

95 partiipants in Konstanz approved of the SPD andidate, but did not

approve of the party itself.

12

1.3.2 Eletion Results

The atual hoies in the experiments are presented in Tables 1.3 to 1.6.

These tables are organized as follows. The olumn Votes lists the share

of partiipants who diretly approved of a party or andidate. Hene, the

perentages in this olumn do not add up to 100%. In the seond olumn,

Z-Share, we present the normalized share of approvals for eah party and

andidate,i.e.approvalsforapartyorandidatedividedbythetotalnumber

of approvals given by the voters. These results an be diretly ompared

with the oial outome. In order to easily see the hanges between the

outomes of the two methods, the olumnsZ-Rank and O-Rank indiate

the rankof eah alternative aording tothe ApprovalVotes reeived in the

experiment and aording to the share of total votes reeived in the oial

eletion, whih isitself presented in olumnO-Share. In ase of ties in the

(rounded) vote shares,the rankis determinedfollowingtheabsolutenumber

of approvals,whihislistedinTable 1.11inthe Appendix. Allresultsof the

oial eletion refer to personal eletors (i.e. without those who registered

to ast their vote per post) from the set of polling stations the experiment

took plae in, i.e. the whole of Messel for the rst experiment, and our six

seleted polling stationsin the ase of Konstanz.

Constitueny Vote, Messel (Table 1.3). There were 8 andidates in

the distrit eletions in Messel, eah representing one of the major parties:

12

Attheaggregatelevel,itisreasonabletoexpetalargeraveragenumberofapprovals

forparties thanforandidates,simplybeausenotallpartiesappointandidatesforthe

distrit eletion. If oneonsiders only parties whih did haveandidates in thedistrit

eletion, the average number of approvals was 1.937 in Messel (ompared to 1.860 for

andidates)and1.983inKonstanz(omparedto1.943forandidates).

(34)

Candidate Votes Z-Share Z-Rank O-Share O-Rank

Hofmann, SPD 58.0 31.2 1 45.9 1 -14.7

Milde, CDU 41.8 22.5 2 37.9 2 -15.4

Harth, Greens 31.4 16.9 3 4.5 4 +12.4

Dr. Krug, FDP 30.3 16.3 4 6.0 3 +10.3

Deistler, Left 10.4 5.6 5 3.4 5 +2.2

Herrmann, FV 7.4 4.0 6 0.8 7 +3.2

Bauer, REP 3.9 2.1 7 1.1 6 +1.0

Zeuner, NPD 2.8 1.5 8 0.3 8 +1.2

Total 186.0

The

olumnshowsthedierenebetweenZ-shareandO-Shareof theandidates.

All data exept ranks are given in %.

the CDU (onservative), the SPD (soialdemorats), the Greens, the FDP

(liberal), the Republians (extreme right), the Left (extreme left), the Free

Voters(FV)andtheNPD(extremeright). TheandidatefortheSPDParty,

Miss Hofmann, wonthe diretseat.

Under approval voting, Miss Hofmann is still the top ranked andidate.

Although the shareof votes dereased from45.9%to 31.2%,we see that she

was able toreeive the assent of an absolutemajorityof 58% of the eletors

and that she was the only one who did so.

13

Unfortunately, this sort of

informationis lostunder the oial method.

Thereare twoswithes inrankings,onebetweentheFDPandtheGreens

andidates and one between those ofthe REPand the Free Voters. Further,

thegapbetweenthetwoandidatesofSPDandCDUandtheothersbeomes

smaller. Theshare of votes inreases from 4.5%forthe Greens and from6%

13

Under Approval Voting, it is theoretially possible that more than one andidate

reeivesan absolute majority of approvals. However, in eah of the three experimental

pollingstations,MissHofmannwastheonlyandidateapprovedofbyanabsolutemajority

ofpartiipants.

(35)

for the FDP andidate to 16.9% and 16.3% respetively, while the share of

the CDU's and SPD's andidates dereases. Essentially, the dierenes in

vote shares for andidates in the enter of the politial spetrum derease.

The andidates ranked on the last positions (7 and 8) are those from the

far-right parties.

Constitueny Vote, Konstanz (Table 1.4). For the distrit vote in

Konstanz, sixandidateswereavailable,eahrepresentingamajorparty: the

CDU, the SPD,the FDP,the Greens,the Left andthe NPD. The andidate

of the CDU (Mr. Jung) reeived the most votes and won the diret seat for

his party.

Under Approval Voting, however, the results are radially dierent. A

major swith in rankings ours between the Greens' andidate, Mr. Seiler,

and the CDU andidate, Mr. Jung. While ranked on third position in

the oial eletion, Mr. Seiler is approved of by an absolute majority and

learlyistheAV-winner. Mr. Jungdropsfromrstpositionundertheoial

to third position in the AV-ranking. Not only did AV alter the andidate

ranking, a dierent andidate than the one suggested by the oialmethod

would have won the diret seat for hisparty under AV.

Table 1.4: Konstanz: Approval vs. Plurality Voting, Constitueny Vote.

Candidate Votes Z-Share Z-Rank O-Share O-Rank

Seiler, Greens 50.6 26.0 1 19.0 3 +7.0

Friedrih, SPD 46.5 23.9 2 25.6 2 -1.7

Jung, CDU 45.1 23.2 3 37.8 1 -14.6

Homburger,FDP 33.7 17.4 4 10.7 4 +6.7

Stier, Left 17.4 9.0 5 6.5 5 +2.5

Louis, NPD 1.0 0.5 6 0.4 6 +0.1

Total 194.3

The

olumnshowsthedierenebetweenZ-shareandO-Shareof theandidates.

All data exept ranks are given in %.

(36)

Similarly to our observations from the rst experiment in Messel, the

andidatesofthetwomajorparties,CDUandSPD,aretheonlyalternatives

losing in terms of share when the method is swithed from PV to AV. The

share of the SPD andidate dereases from25.6%to 23.9%,the share of the

CDU andidate from 37.8% to 23.2%. There is no dierene in the rank of

the remainingandidates between the oial eletion and the experiment's

results.

List Vote, Messel (Table 1.5). In the state eletion in Messel, there

were 17 dierent parties from whih to hoose: the CDU, the SPD, the

Greens, the FDP, the Republians, the Animal Protetion Party, the Civil

Liberties Party, the PSG (ommunist), the Popular Vote Party, the Grey

Party(orientedtowards seniorissues), theLeft,the VioletParty,the Family

Party, the Free Voters, the NPD, the `Hessian Pirates' (an organization of

omputer hakers), and the UB Party.

14

Fortheomparison between plurality voting and approvalvotingresults,

weroughlyobservethesamepatternasfortheConstituenyVote. TheSPD

remainsthe strongest partysupportedbyanabsolutemajorityof approvals,

followed by the seond-ranked CDU. Additionally,those arethe onlyparties

whih lose in terms of share under approval voting. Again there is a swith

in ranks between the FDP and the Greens. The parties from both ends of

the politialspetrumlose in termof ranks. The NPD drops fromrank7 to

11, the REPfrom 6 to9 and the far-left party PSG from15 to16.

A simple onsideration shows whih parties gain the most. On average,

eletorsinMesselast2.25partyapprovalsperballot. Toobtaintheapproval

votesoftheaverageparty,weansimplymultiplyitsperentageofvotesfrom

the oial eletionby a fator of 2.25. We an also ompute the individual

fator of a party by dividing the number of approvals per partiipant it

14

Usually, it is less likely to observe ties in the party ranking the larger the mass of

onstituents. If wekeepin mind therelativelysmall numberof experimentpartiipants

and urnvoters,itisnotsurprisingthatseveraltiesourintheexperimentaswellasin

theoialMesselvote. E.g.,theAnimalProtetionPartyandtheFamilyPartyreeived

anequaltotalnumberofapprovalsintheexperiment. ThesameistruefortheNPDand

the`HessianPirates',rankedon11thposition,andCivilLibertiesPartyandPSG,ranked

onplae16in theexperiment'spartyrankingin Messel.

(37)

Party Votes Z-Share Z-Rank O-Share O-Rank

SPD 53.8 23.9 1 38.9 1 -15.0

CDU 44.6 19.8 2 36.0 2 -16.2

Greens 36.1 16.0 3 7.0 4 +9.0

FDP 32.6 14.5 4 9.0 3 +5.5

Left 12.3 5.5 5 4.9 5 +0.6

AnimalProt. Party 9.6 4.3 6 0.8 7 +3.5

The FamilyParty 9.6 4.3 6 0.2 12 +4.1

The Free Voters 7.1 3.1 8 0.5 9 +2.6

Republian Party 3.3 1.5 9 1.0 6 +0.5

The Popular Vote 2.9 1.3 10 0.2 13 +1.1

NPD 2.8 1.2 11 0.8 7 +0.4

The Hessian Pirates 2.8 1.2 11 0.3 10 +0.9

The GreyParty 2.5 1.1 13 0.2 13 +0.9

UB 2.1 0.9 14 0.1 15 +0.8

The VioletParty 1.0 0.5 15 0.3 11 +0.2

PSG 0.9 0.4 16 0.1 15 +0.3

CivilLiberties Party 0.9 0.4 16 0.1 15 +0.3

Total 225.0

The

olumn shows the dierene between Z-share and O-Share of the parties.

All data exept ranks are given in %.

reeived inthe experiment by the perentage of votes reeived inthe oial

eletion.

15

Hene, a party fator above 2.25 in Messel indiates that the

partyatuallybenetedfromthehange toApprovalVoting,andvieversa.

Whilethe fators of the CDU andSPD with 1.24 and 1.38are learly below

the 2.25 average, the fators for the Greens and FDP are 5.18 and 3.62.

Aboveaverage aswellare the fators of the NPD and the RepublianParty

with 3.74 and 3.45. Outstanding, however, with 44.64, 12.75 and 14.66 are

15

Toavoidrounding errors,weomputepartyfatorsusing theexatnumberofvotes

providedinTable1.11intheAppendix.

(38)

the fators of the Family Party, the Animal Protetion Party and the Free

Voters. All threeparties are moderate and issue-foused.

List Vote, Konstanz (Table 1.6). Voters ould hoose one of 17 dier-

ent parties: the CDU, the SPD, the Greens, the FDP, the Left, the NPD,

the Republians, the PBC(struggles for upholdingChristian valuesin mod-

ern soiety), the MLPD (the Marxist-Leninist party of Germany), the Civil

Liberties Party, the Popular Vote Party, the ADM (onservative), the DVU

(extremeright),theVioletParty,the AnimalProtetionParty, theödp (ori-

ented towards environmental issues),and the Pirate Party.

Table 1.6: Konstanz: Approval vs. Plurality Voting, List Vote.

Party Votes Z-Share Z-Rank O-Share O-Rank

Greens 58.1 22.7 1 20.1 3 +2.6

SPD 47.3 18.5 2 21.9 2 -3.4

CDU 41.5 16.2 3 28.6 1 -12.4

FDP 36.3 14.2 4 16.9 4 -2.7

The Pirate Party 20.8 8.1 5 3.7 6 +4.4

Left 18.4 7.2 6 6.2 5 +1.0

AnimalProt. Party 12.2 4.8 7 0.9 7 +3.9

ödp 7.4 2.9 8 0.3 9 +2.6

The Popular Vote 4.9 1.9 9 0.2 10 +1.7

The VioletParty 3.1 1.2 10 0.2 10 +1.0

Republian Party 1.3 0.5 11 0.2 12 +0.3

NPD 1.0 0.4 12 0.4 8 +0.0

MLPD 1.0 0.4 13 0.1 14 +0.3

PBC 1.0 0.4 13 0.2 13 +0.2

CivilLiberties Party 0.7 0.3 15 0.0 16 +0.3

ADM 0.3 0.1 16 0.0 15 +0.1

DVU 0.3 0.1 17 0.0 16 +0.1

Total 255.7

The

olumn shows the dierene between Z-share and O-Share of the parties.

All data exept ranks are given in %.

(39)

UnderApproval Voting, the pitureissimilartothe one skethed for the

Constitueny Vote. The lear winner is the Green Party, with an absolute

majority of approvals(58.1%). Thewinner ofthe oialeletion,the CDU,

drops to the 3rd position. The marginal Pirate Party, whih reeived only

3.7% of the votes inthe oialeletion,is approved of by astunning 20.8%

of the eletorate and is ranked even beforethe Left. The AnimalProtetion

Party and the green-oriented ödp alsoexperienelarge inreases, from0.9%

resp. 0.3%shares inthe oialeletionto12.2% and7.4% approvalrates in

the experiment.

1.3.3 General Disussion

Several desirableproperties of the Approval Voting methodan befound in

the literature whih are highlighted in our data or beame lear during the

experiments. It has been argued (e.g. Brams and Fishburn, 2005) that the

methodredues strategionsiderationsasthewastedvote eet,bywhih

voters do not reveal the parties they favor most and bet on popular alter-

natives instead. Under Approval Voting, individualsan ast votes for their

preferredminorityalternativesandthemostpopularones. Thus,themethod

enourages sinerevoting(see alsoBramsand Fishburn,1978and Wolitzky,

2009) and provides voters with more options to represent their preferenes.

Minority andidates reeive their true level of support, so that the outome

under Approval Voting should be a better reetion of the aeptability of

all andidates amongthe eletorate.

It is alsooften laimed (e.g. Brams and Fishburn, 1978), that ompared

tomoreompliatedrankingmethods, itiseasyforvoterstounderstandthe

Approval Voting method. It provides a simple way for voters to express a

larger part of the informationontained intheir preferenes withoutforing

them todevelop full andidate/party rankings. Hene,it isaognitiveom-

promisebetween deidingonlyabest andidateand generatingaomplete

ranking.

Finally, the method is supposed to redue inentives for negative am-

paigning, sine lose andidates need no longer ompete against eah other

(40)

for the vote of the eletor. They an share a ommon base. As a onse-

quene, by a simple politial proximity argument, we an expet a larger

inrease in the base shared by entrist andidates than in that shared by

extremist andidates. Hene, Approval Voting strengthens the position of

moderate, entrist andidates, withoutatthe same timedenyingvoters the

opportunity toexpress their support for moreextremist andidates (Brams

and Fishburn, 1978, p. 831).

Qualitative Lessons from the Data

Letusbrieydisusshowtheseinsightstranslateintoour experimentaldata.

The typial image of the German party system at the time we ran our ex-

periments was haraterized by two big enter, ath-all-parties, the CDU

and the SPD who, with a broad support inthe population, struggleagainst

eah other for the rst position in the party ranking. Parties like the FDP,

the Greens and the Left were only of interest when partners for forming a

rulingoalitionwereneeded. In theontextoftheexperiments'outome,we

dare speulatethatthis viewmightatually beanadho artifatreated by

the prevailing voting method, rather than an aurate image of the voters'

preferenes.

The Approval Voting system used in our experiments fundamentally al-

tered the pereption of the party landsape,showing instead fourmain par-

ties, eah of them with a signiant proportion of the vote (see Tables 1.5

and1.6). TheallegedlysmallerGreenPartyandtheliberalFDP,whihuntil

the date of writing are universally viewed as oalition partners but not as

andidatesforwinninganeletion,anbeseen tohavealevelofsupportnot

far behind that of the two main parties. That is, the omparison between

our experimentaldataand thedata ofthe oialeletionsisonsistentwith

the view that, when voters are asked to hoose only one of the available

alternatives, the wasted vote argument plays a more than signiant role.

It beomes less attrative to vote for smaller parties whih are pereived as

not having the option for winning the eletion or entering the parliament,

althoughthey mightatbest represent the voter's opinion. Eletorstrade-o

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

In this analysis, we use a county-level variable -- mail-in census response rates -- to measure the strength of civic norms in counties represented in the 1992 American National

To sum up our hypotheses, we expect a lower propensity to turn out if voting is voluntary to be associated with a lower level of political sophistica- tion, a

(1) according to the Messel Parliament, the majority of the seats would have been given to four different parties, the CDU, the SPD, the FDP and the Greens; (2) three small

Why one would accept Voting Theory for Democracy and reject the Penrose. Square

&gt;f simple games, indices of relative decisiveness are single valued solution concepts )n pivota l entities. If member states hav e different votin g weights unde r majority

in: Power Indices and Coalition Formation

the impact on Iran, Asad’s closest strategic partner; the perception of the power of the United States and its allies; the stability of neighbor- ing states; and the impact

The case of Luxembourg is the textbook example for illustrating the concept of a null player (which is often confused with that of a dummy player). As shown above this is