• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

2 A Model with a Riskless Capital Market

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "2 A Model with a Riskless Capital Market"

Copied!
12
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Lutz Kruschwitz Freie Universität Berlin

and

Andreas Löffler1 Universität Hannover version from January 23, 2003

1Corresponding author, Königsworther Platz 1, 30167 Hannover, Germany, E–Mail: AL@wacc.de.

(2)

We generalize the classical concept of a certainty equivalent to a model where an investor can trade on a capital market with several future trad- ing dates. We show that if a riskless asset is traded and the investor has a CARA utility then our generalized certainty equivalent can be evaluated using the sum of discounted one–period certainty equivalents. This is not true if the investor has a HARA utility.

keywords: certainty equivalent, CARA JEL class.: D81, D92

(3)

1 Introduction

The concept of expected utility (dating back to Bernoulli (1738)) is used in economics to describe the behavior of an investor choosing between several lotteries or alternatives. Its applications include not only portfo- lio choice but insurance and game theory as well. A certainty equivalent (see Markowitz (1952)) of a risky outcome is a sure–thing lottery which yields the same utility as a random lottery. If the investor is risk–averse the outcome of the certainty equivalent will be less than the expected outcome of the random lottery. A certainty equivalent can be defined in a world where no capital market exists. Our goal is to show how this idea has to be modified if the investor can trade on an incomplete market with several future trading dates. In particular we show that for CARA utility and a capital market with only riskless assets the generalized cer- tainty equivalent can be evaluated using the discounted sum of classical certainty equivalents. The same is not true if the investor has a HARA utility function.

2 A Model with a Riskless Capital Market

To keep our approach as simple as possible we look at three points in time, t = 0 (present) and t = 1,2 (future). The future is uncertain. A project realizes cash–flowsCF0,gCF1 andCFg2. Any investor valuing the projects uses his expected utility functionu(x). We assume that the util- ity function is not time–dependent, although there are discount factors δ1, δ2. Hence, the utility of an investment is given by

u(CF0)+δ1E[u(gCF1)]+δ2E[u(gCF2)].

(4)

We now add a capital market to our model and consider the simplest capital market that is possible: only riskless assets can be traded. Let Xt andYt be the amount the investor can put on or get from a riskless money market account. A first idea to generalize a certainty equivalent would be a definition of the form

u(C0+Y0)+δ1·Eh

u(Y1(1+rf)Y0)i

+δ2·Eh

u(−(1+rf)Y1)i

=Def u(CF0+X0)+δ1·Eh

u(gCF1+X1(1+rf)X0)i

2·Eh

u(gCF2(1+rf)X1)i (1) In the last equation the definition of the certainty equivalent depends on the amountXt andYt which cannot be accepted. A rational investor will optimize her strategy on the capital market: she will chooseXt and Ytsuch that both sides on the equation will be as large as possible. Hence

maxYt

u(C0+Y0)+δ1Eh

u(Y1(1+rf)Y0)i

2Eh

u(−(1+rf)Y1)i

=Def maxXt

u(CF0+X0)+δ1Eh

u(gCF1+X1(1+rf)X0)i

2Eh

u(gCF2(1+rf)X1)i .

(2) This will be our generalization of a certainty equivalent if a capital market

is prevalent.

It is evident that riskless payments have to be valued using the risk- less interest rate. Although this is obvious it has to be proven using our model (2). To this end we assume thatCF0 =0 and show the following result.

Theorem 1 If cash–flows are riskless then

C0= CF1

1+rf + CF2 (1+rf)2.

(5)

Our proof reveals that this result is not restricted to the time horizon we have choosen. For simplicity we restrict ourselves toT = 2. The same will be true if risky assets are traded – if a market price for these risky assets exists our approach will yield the market price.

The utility functions are strictly concave. Hence, Xt and Yt are unique. We know that Y0 and Y1 maximize the left hand side of (2).

Substituting

Yˆ0:= − CF1

1+rfCF2

(1+rf)2 +X0, Yˆ1:= − CF2

1+rf +X1 the right hand side can be written as u CF1

1+rf + CF2

(1+rf)2 +Yˆ0

!

1·Eh u

Yˆ1(1+rf)Yˆ0i

2·Eh u

−(1+rf)Yˆ1i .

SinceCF0 =0 this will be the optimal solution of the right hand side of (2) iff

C0= CF1

1+rf + CF2 (1+rf)2

holds. But the optimization of the left and the right hand side must yield identical values since the utility functions are strictly concave.

3 CARA–utility

Assume the investor has a utility function of CARA type

u(t)= −e−at. (3)

LetC1B andC2B be the (classical Bernoulli–)certainty equivalents without a capital market, i.e. riskless payments that yield the same utility as the

(6)

random cash–flows

E[u(gCF1)]=u(C1B), E[u(gCF2)]=u(C2B). (4) We want to clarify the relation between the fair valueC0and theBernoulli–

certainty equivalents. The following theorem holds.

Theorem 2 If the utility function is of CARA type our certainty equivalent is the riskless discounted Bernoulli–certainty equivalent

C0= C1B

1+rf + C2B (1+rf)2.

To prove theorem 2 we denote by Xt and Yt the optimal money market account from (2). We will furthermore make use of the following two well–known properties of CARA utility for any random variablesXe andYe

Eh

u(Xe+Y )e i

=Eh u(X)e i

·Eh u(Y )e i

. (5)

IfCF0=0 equation (2) simplifies to u C0+Y0

+δ1·Eh

u(Y1(1+rf)Y0)i

+δ2·Eh

u(−(1+rf)Y1)i

=u X0

1·Eh

u(gCF1+X1(1+rf)X0)i

2·Eh

u(gCF2(1+rf)X1)i ,

which using (5) can be written as u C0+Y0

+δ1·Eh

u(Y1(1+rf)Y0)i

+δ2·Eh

u(−(1+rf)Y1)i

=u(X0)+δ1·Eh

u(gCF1)i

·Eh

u(X1(1+rf)X0)i +δ2·Eh

u(gCF2)i

·Eh

u(−(1+rf)X1)i .

(7)

With (4) this is equivalent to u C0+Y0

+δ1·u

Y1(1+rf)Y0

+δ2·u

−(1+rf)Y1

=u X0

1·u C1B

·u

X1(1+rf)X0

2·u C2B

·u

−(1+rf)X1 . (6) We now evaluate the optimal valuesXt andYt. We start with Y0. The FOC are

0=u0 C0+Y0

δ1(1+rf) u0

Y1(1+rf)Y0 u0 C0+Y0

=δ1(1+rf) u0

Y1(1+rf)Y0 .

Given our utility functions whereu0= −a uwe get u C0+Y0

=δ1(1+rf) u

Y1(1+rf)Y0

. (7)

Analogously δ1u

Y1(1+rf)Y0

=δ2(1+rf) u

−(1+rf)Y1

. (8) Using a similar approach we arrive at

0=u0 X0

δ1(1+rf)Eh

u0(gCF1+X1(1+rf)X0)i u0 X0

=δ1(1+rf)Eh

u0(gCF1+X1(1+rf)X0)i u X0

=δ1(1+rf)Eh

u(gCF1+X1(1+rf)X0)i u X0

=δ1(1+rf)Eh

u(gCF1)i

·u

X1(1+rf)X0 u X0

=δ1(1+rf) u C1B

·u

X1(1+rf)X0

. (9)

Finally this gives u

C1B

·u

X1(1+rf)X0

=δ2(1+rf) u C2B

·u

−(1+rf)X1 (10)

(8)

We now plug (7) to (10) into (6) such that onlyu(X0) andu(C0+Y0) remain. This gives

1+ 1

1+rf + 1 (1+rf)2

!

u(X0)= 1+ 1

1+rf + 1 (1+rf)2

!

u(C0+Y0),

and hence

u(X0)=u(C0+Y0)

or, since the utility function is strictly monotonous X0 =C0+Y0

X0Y0 =C0. (11) Now using (7) to (10) in (6) such that only the termsu

X1(1+rf)X0 andu

Y1(1+rf)Y0

left gives

1+rf +1+ 1 1+rf

! δ1u

Y1(1+rf) Y0

= 1+rf +1+ 1 1+rf

! δ1u

C1B

·u

X1(1+rf)X0

or (using (5)) u

Y1(1+rf)Y0

=u

C1B +X1(1+rf)X0 .

This is equivalent to

Y1X1

1+rfY0X0

= C1B

1+rf . (12)

We now use (7) to (10) again in (6) such that only the termsu

−(1+rf)X1 undu

−(1+rf)Y1

remain and we get (1+rf)2+1+rf +1

δ2u

−(1+rf) Y1

=

(1+rf)2+1+rf+1 δ2u

C2B

·u

−(1+rf)X1

(9)

or using (5)

u

−(1+rf)Y1

=u

C2B(1+rf)X1 .

Since the utility function is strictly monotonous X1Y1= C2B

1+rf (13)

and (11) to (13) finish our proof. This proof reveals that the restriction toT =2 is not a necessary restriction.

4 HARA–utility

We are convinced that our theorem2is not valid for any utility function.

To this end we use a HARA–utility function

u(t)=ln(t) (14)

and will show that the riskless discountedBernoulli–certainty equivalent is not the certainty equivalent of our theory. We restrict ourselves to T = 1 and only two possible states of nature ω1 and ω2. Both states may occur with the same probability. The equation (2) now for CF0=0 reads

ln(C0+Y0)+δln(−(1+rf)Y0)

=ln(X0)+δ 2

ln(CF11)(1+rf)X0)+ln(CF12)(1+rf)X0) .

The optimal valueY0 can easily be evaluated

0= 1

C0+Y0 + δ

Y0 =⇒ Y0= − C0 1+1δ.

(10)

To getX0 we need the FOC on the right hand side 0= 1

X0 + δ 2

−(1+rf)

CF11)(1+rf)X0 + −(1+rf) CF12)(1+rf)X0

! .

Some algebraic manipulations lead to X0 = 2+δ

4(1+rf)(1+δ) CF11)+CF12)

± s

CF121)+CF122)+2CF11)CF122−4δ−4 δ2+4δ+4

!

Let without loss of generality CF11)CF12). Then, X0 has to be between CF1+r11)

f and CF1+r12)

f . Hence, the solution of the quadratic equation can only be the one with−. Now plugging the optimal values in C0 we get an equation for C0 that was solved numerically. We also evaluated the riskless discountedBernoulli–certainty equivalent

C1B = q

CF11) CF12) .

To show that theorem2with a HARA utility does not hold we consid- ered a numerical example. To this end we have choosenCF11) = 1, rf = 5 % andδ = 0.95. A variation ofCF12)(1,7] yielded several values for the riskless discountedBernoulli–equivalent and C0. The fig- ure1shows a plot of both values. In our plot both values do not coincide, the difference is larger the larger the volatility of the cash–flow is.

5 Conclusion

We generalized the classical concept of a certainty equivalent to a model where aa riskless capital market with several future trading dates exists.

(11)

1.0 1.5 2.0 2.5

1.0 3.0 5.0 7.0

- 6

CF12) CF11)

certainty equivalent

discounted Bernoulli (C1b, C2B)

generalized certainty equivalentC0

..............................................................

.....................................................

Figure 1: riskless discounted Bernoulli–equivalent and depending on volatility (withrf =5 %, δ=0.95)

If the investor has a CARA utility then our generalized certainty equiva- lent can be evaluated using the sum of discounted one–period certainty equivalents. The same is not true with HARA utility.

The authors thank the Verein zur Förderung der Zusammenarbeit zwischen Lehre und Praxis am Finanzplatz Hannover e.V. for financial support and Wolfgang Ballwieser, Wolfgang Kürsten and Jochen Wilhelm for helpful remarks.

References

Bernoulli, D. (1738), ‘Specimen theoriae novae de mensura sortis’,Com- mentarii Academiae Scientiarum Imperialis Petropolitanae,175–192, Louise Sommer: Exposition of a new theory on the measurement of risk,Econometrica, 22, 1954, 23–36).

(12)

Markowitz, H. M. (1952), ‘Portfolio selection’, The Journal of Finance 7, 77–91.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

In particular, we (1) compute the present value borrowing constraint and creditworthiness without and with en- dogenous credit cost, (2) compute thresholds of those types of

En este caso, la demanda de dinero tendr´a efetos indirectos provenientes de la fracci´on de las ganancias que cada empresa genere en su periodo productivo, la remuneraci´on que

The reached level of development of the capital market in Croatia is the result and the consequence of the openness of Croatian economy, but it is also, partly, the result of

Based on this argument it is necessary to allow for asymmetric effects when the issue of financial market integration in investigated empirically in order to figure

If the employer is a managerial hotshot, the team production problem will be solved because he/she is capable of solving it and managerial effort has no cost.. For example,

CAPM is a linear equilibrium model of return on investments that explains expected returns above the risk free rate 1 using covariance of expected returns on individual

We next simulate the benchmark model to quantitatively examine the e¤ects of two factor tax rates ( K and L ) on an array of endogenous variables of interest, including the

In order to achieve a separation of attitudes towards wealth and attitudes towards risk we have proposed the interpretation of acts as a composition of the worst possible outcome