• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

On the uniqueness of macroeconomic equilibria with quantity rationing

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "On the uniqueness of macroeconomic equilibria with quantity rationing"

Copied!
6
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

North-Holland Publishing Company

ON THE UNIQUENESS OF MACROECONOMIC EQUILIBRIA WITH QUANTITY RATIONING

Volker BOHM

Unioersrty of Mannheim, D-6800 Mannheim, West Germany Received 29 April 1982

This note provides an elementary proof of uniqueness of macroeconomic equilibria with rationing for economics with two traded commodities and fixed prices.

1. Introduction

In two independent contributions by Muellbauer and Portes (1978) and in the habilitation monograph by the author submitted in 1977 and published in 1980, a macroeconomic model with quantity rationing was described which allows producers to hold inventories as well as money balances. In both papers the discussion of comparative statics properties depends crucially on an asserted uniqueness result which is not proved in either publication. This note gives an elementary uniqueness proof. The general case with an arbitrary number of commodities is treated in Kosch (1981).

2. The model

Given the data of the economy, the consumption sector including government purchases can be described by the effective commodity demand function

x=

C,(L)

01651765/82/0000-0000/$02.75 0 1982 North-Holland

(2)

44 V. Bijhm / Uniqueness of macroeconomic equilibria

and by the effective labor supply function L=A,(X)

satisfying for some L* > 0 and X* > 0 (i) X* = C,(L) VL2 L*,

(ii) L* =A,(X) VX>X*.

(X*, L*) is the pair of unconstrained decisions (i.e., the notional demand and supply) of the consumption sector. Similarly, the production sector is given by a pair of effective demand and supply functions, relating sales Y to labor demand 2,

Y= G,(Z),

Z=H,(Y)

satisfying for some Z* > 0 and Y* > 0 (iii) Y* = G,(Z) VZ>Z*,

(iv) Z* =H,(Y) WY2 Y*.

(Y*, Z*) is the pair of notional supply and demand of the production sector. All variables and functions are assumed to be non-negative.

Let

c= {(x,L)IC,(L)~X,A,(X)>L}, and P= {(r,z)(H,(Y)~Z, G=(Z)> y}.

Then, the set of feasible states is C n P.

Definition. A feasible state (X, L) of the exonomy of aggregate employ- ment L and aggregate sales X is a Keynesian unemployment situation if it is a solution for

C,(L) =x,

xc y*,

f$(X)=L

L<L*. (K)

Definition. A feasible state (X, L) is a repressed inflation situation if

(3)

Fig. I.

(X, L) is a solution for

A,(X) =

L, L<z*,

G,(L) =X, xcx*. (1)

Definition. A feasible state (X, L) is a classical unemployment situation denoted C if

L=z*, x= y*,

C,(L) >X, A,(X)>L. ((3

Definition. A feasible state (X, L) is a situation of underconsumption if L= L*, x=x*,

G,(L)>X, H,(X)>L. (U)

A geometrical presentation of a typical disequilibrium situation is given in fig. 1, which depicts a situation where a repressed inflation state is _- obtained. (L, X) are the associated employment and sales levels. From the behavioral assumptions underlying the aggregate functions it follows that all acceptable states of a sector lie ‘inside’ the set formed by the wedge of the two functions. The acceptable sets are bounded and they

(4)

46 V. Bijhm / Uniqueness of macroeconomic equilibria

are closed if the functions are continuous. Therefore, any disequilibrium state lies in the intersection of the two sets which is always non-empty since the origin belongs to both sets. Moreover, it is easy to see that at least one of the disequilibrium states will occur.

Theorem. Assume that the following conditions hold:

(C.1) C,(O)

0, A,(O)

0,

(C.2) CL ==o, A;>O, C;A;< 1, (P.1) H,(O) ‘0, G,(O) ’ 0,

(P.2) H;>O, G;>O, H;G;< 1, (A) C;H;c 1, A;G; -=I 1.

Then, there exists at most one disequilibrium situation which has positive employment and positive sales.

Assumptions (C.l), (C.2), (P.l) and (P.2) are natural in the aggregate context here and they prevent boundary solutions. Assumption (A) was used in Biihm (1980) and Muellbauer and Portes (1978). It guarantees normal supply and demand multipliers. (A) can be weakened to piece- wise differentiable functions which would be the more natural frame- work, since the aggregate effective supply and demand functions will typically be non-differentiable at a point where an individual agent changes from a situation of rationing to non-rationing.

Proof. Define _X= min{Y*,X*} and 6 = min{Z*, L*}. (X, L) is a Walrasian state if and only if _X= Y* = X* and L = Z* = L*. All other

- feasible states are such that (X, L) G (_X, L).

Let A; ’ denote the inverse of A, and HJ ’ the inverse of H,, both being defined on their appropriate domaines. Consider the four functions

U(L)=C,(L)-A,‘(L) definedon [A,(O),&], C(L)=G,(L)-H;‘(L) definedon [H~(o),L], K(L)=C,(L)-H;‘(L) definedon[~,(O),&], I(L)=G,(L)-AA,‘(L) defined on [A,(O), 61.

It is easy to see from the assumptions of the theorem, that each of these

(5)

functions is strictly decreasing and positive at the left end of its domain.

Moreover, a feasible state of underconsumption, of classical unemploy- ment, of Keynesian unemployment or of repressed inflation defines a zero of U, C, K or Z respectively. It remains to be shown that, except for boundary cases, no two functions have a zero simultaneously for feasible pairs(X,L)EcnP.

Suppose there exists a Keynesian state (X,,

Lk).

Then

L, -c L

such that K(

Lk)= C,,(L,)-Hy'(L,)=O, U(L,)>O

and C(

L,)>

O.-More- over

Z(k) = G,(L) -A,‘(L,)

=

G,(L) --A,‘(L,) + Cu(L,) -H;‘(k)

=u(L,)+c(L,)>o.

Since Z(L) is strictly decreasing, Z(L)

> 0

for all

L < L,. L > L,

repre- sent infeasible states. Therefore, if a Keynesian solution exists, all the other three are excluded.

Suppose there exists an inflationary state (X,,

L,).

Then

L, < L

such thatZ(L,)=G,(L,)-AA,‘(L,)=O. Since

U(L,)>O

and

C(L,)>%,

one obtains

6%) = Cub%) -H,-‘(h)

=

Cu(L,) - H,-‘(L,) + Gz(L,) -A,‘tL,)

=U(L,)-tC(L,)>O.

Monotonicity implies again that there is no other solution for

L < L,.

Suppose (T,

L*)

is an underconsumption state, i.e., X* = C,(

L*), U( L*) = 0

and

L* <Z*.

Since (X*,

L*) E P,

one must have

C,(L*)<G,(L*)

and

C,(L*)rH;'(L*).

Therefore

Z(L*)=G,(L*)-AA,'(L*)>C,(L*)-AA,'(L*)=O,

and

K(L*)= C,(L*)-H;'(L*)>O.

(6)

48 V. Bihm / Uniqueness of macroeconomic equilibria

Hence, monotonicity of Z and K imply that there exists no other feasible solution. In a similar fashion one shows that, if (Y*, Z*) is a classical state, there exists no other feasible solution. Q.E.D.

References

Bohm, V., 1978, Disequilibrium dynamics in a simple macroeconomic model, Journal of Economic Theory 17, 179- 199.

Bohm, V., 1980, Preise, Lohne und Beschlftigung, Beitrag zur Theorie der mikrookonomischen Grundlagen der Makrookonomik [J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck) Tiibingen].

Kosch, B., 1981, On the global uniqueness of fix-price-equilibria, Discussion paper no.

184-81 (Institut ftir VWL und Statistik der Universitat Mannheim, Mannheim).

Muellbauer, J. and R.D. Portes, 1978, Macroeconomic models with quantity rationing, Economic Journal 88, no. 4, 788-821.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

Znhl im Hauran gefunden sind , nicht hloss weil in ihnen manche. .Andeutungen Uher Landescultur, Götterdienste und

We provide a simple necessary and su¢cient condition for when a multiproduct demand system can be generated from a discrete choice model with unit demands1. Keywords: Discrete

Unlike previous studies, it is found that changes in the output level are mainly driven by aggregate demand shocks, whereas supply shocks are playing the dominant role

The operator makes note of the start point corresponding to that tuple and continues to scan the stream as long as the encountered tuples meet the

We show that arrow cichlids (Amphilophus za/iosus) adjusted their territorial aggression regarding the status ofheterospecific intruders: breeding individuals of Amphilophus

8 Moreover, developing countries insisted on excluding the so-called “Singapore issues” from the negotiations. These issues, identified during the WTO First

this was reflected in the European Commission Communication in 2008, which called for the creation of a southern gas corridor in order to reach the Middle Eastern and

Entry (exit) occurs, or in our aggregative model investment adjusts, until the point where * just covers fixed costs and the zero profit condition is satisfied. Only in