• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Behavioral experiments reveal how risk perception and worldviews impact common-good governance

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Behavioral experiments reveal how risk perception and worldviews impact common-good governance"

Copied!
1
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Behavioral E xperiments R eveal H ow R isk P erception and W orldviews I mpact C ommon- G ood G overnance

Peter Bednarik(Evolution and Ecology & Risk and Resilience Programs, IIASA; University of Vienna, Austria) Ulf Dieckmann(Evolution and Ecology Program, IIASA)

Joanne Linnerooth-Bayer(Risk and Resilience Program, IIASA) Piotr Magnuszewski(Risk and Resilience & Water Programs, IIASA) Karl Sigmund(Evolution and Ecology Program, IIASA; University of Vienna, Austria)

Michael Thompson(Risk and Resilience Program, IIASA; University of Oxford, UK)

Groups are better at preserving the forest when it provides flood protection as an additional ecosystem service, as shown in the figure on the left. From the viewpoint of game theory, this finding is surprising, as the profit losses from floods do not outweigh those from foregone harvesting. Yet, the result matches expectations from bounded rationality, as loss aversion stimulated by the stochastically occurring floods promotes cautious harvesting.

Flood risk reduces over-harvesting

Common resources are often threatened by over-exploitation. Such situations (tragedy of the commons) have been in the focus of researchers for several decades. We extend on existing research by investigating how (i) risk perception of external hazards and (ii) worldviews affect cooperative behavior. To this end we designed a stylized computer game:

Participants in groups of five recurrently decide, in each of altogether 20 rounds, how many trees to harvest from a forest of 80 trees that provides two or three ecosystem services: (i) a provisioning service (harvested trees increases a participant’s profit), (ii) a supporting service (the forest’s regeneration rate linearly increases with the number of remaining trees), and optionally, (iii) a regulating service (the risk of losing trees to randomly occurring rainfall-induced floods decreases with the number of remaining trees).

Forest Game

Communication plays a vital role in managing common goods. We implemented versions of the game in which players could either freely communicate via a chat box or were precluded from communicating. Groups that could communicate on average managed to maintain the forest in much better condition.

Fairness pays

We find differential correlations between the average forest condition resulting from a group’s harvesting and the group’s average cultural-theory scores, as shown in the figure on the left. This is in line with expectations from cultural theory: in the absence of harvest limits and private property, egalitarian affinities improve a group’s ability to preserve the forest (positive correlation), whereas individualistic affinities have the opposite effect (negative correlations).

Worldviews matter

A second forest game will focus on probing and quantifying the expectation, central to cultural theory, that the satisfaction of participants increases when governance policies accord with their worldviews. For this, we will consider policies that are narrowly focused on only one of the worldviews recognized by cultural theory, such as harvest limits (hierarchical), private property (individualistic), or income redistribution (egalitarian). Policies of this kind, called ‘corner solutions’ in cultural theory, have already been trialed with YSSP 2016 participants.

A third forest game will examine dynamic patterns of policy change collectively enacted by participants and how these are associated with a group’s composition in terms of cultural-theory scores. In particular, we will explore whether the aforementioned satisfaction effects can lead to the successive establishment and destabilization of corner solutions.

Outlook

No cooperation without communication

We tested how individual harvest rates relate to payoffs. Interestingly, individuals who harvest more than their fair share are likely to be the ones earning less. We conclude that selfish inidviduals are likely to cause the breakdown of the common resource, causing all participants to earn less.

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

1 6 11 16

Fraction of remaining trees (%)

Rounds With floods and communication

With floods, without communication Without floods, with communication

Without floods, without communication

-5 0 5 10 15 20 25

0% 20% 40% 60% 80%

Individuialprofit

Individual relative harvest rate (% of group’s harvest)

0 10 20 30 40 50

0 2 4 6 8 10

Fraction of remaining trees (%)

Score in cultural-theory questionnaire Individualistic

Fatalistic

Egalitarian

Hierarchical

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

[r]

It aimed (1) to quantify the photosynthetic capacity of adult tropical trees along the elevational transect by means of gas exchange measurements and to analyse

At 70 min in Model 1, the greater generation rates of saturated zones were simulated downslope of trees (Fig. 4a), indicating slope failure.. At this time, Model 2 showed

M 6 Writing your own letter of complaint / eine Beschwerde eigenständig verfassen M 7 Checklist for your letter / den Brief anhand von Kriterien korrigieren und

Mean annual stem growth was normalized for diameter at breast height (dbh) (GRO n ) for Norway spruce (Picea abies), European beech (Fa- gus sylvatica), silver fir (Abies alba) and

Our  last  topic  addresses  the  potential  impact  of  a  “taxpayer  advocacy  bias”  on  tax  professional  recommendation  decisions  concerning  an  appeal 

These disturbances affect the capacity of forests to provide essential ecosystem services, such as protection from natural hazards, wood production, and carbon sequestration,

We provide a logical basis for dynamical evaluation: algebraic closure may fail to exist effectively, but it is possible to build effectively a Beth model of the theory of