• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Optimal Exploitation of Multiple Stocks by a Common Fishery: A New Methodology

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Optimal Exploitation of Multiple Stocks by a Common Fishery: A New Methodology"

Copied!
16
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

OPTIMAL EXPLOITATION OF MULTIPLE STOCKS BY A COMMON FISHERY: A NEW METHODOLOGY

Ray Hilborn August 1975

Research Reports are publications reporting on the work o f the author. Any views or conclusions are those of the author, and d o not necessarily reflect those of IIASA.

(2)
(3)

Optimal Exploitation Of Multiple Stocks By A Colmon Fishery: A New Methodology

Ray Hilborn*

Abstract

Optimal harvest rates for mixed stocks of fish are calculated using stochastic dynamic programming. This technique is shown to be superior to the best methods currently described in the literature. The Ricker stock recruitment curve is assumed for two stocks harvested by the same fishery. The optimal harvest rates are calculated as a function of the size of each stock, for a series of possible parameter values. The dynamic pro- gramming solution is similar to the fixed escapement policy only when the two stocks have similar Ricker pa- rameters, or when the two stocks are of equal size.

Normally, one should harvest harder than calculated from fixed escapement analysis.

Introduction

It is well recognized that many fisheries exploit more than one stock of fish: a stock may consist of separate species at .~arious trophic levels, as in tropical fisheries, or genetically isolated races of the same species, as in Pacific salmon. The problem of optimal harvesting of these mixed fish- eries is interesting because the biological understanding of the stock dynamics is frequently quite advanced relative to the methodological tools to de~ermine the optimal harvest. Paulik et al. [ 7 ] have presented techniques for calculating the optimal harvest rate for fisheries consisting of up to twenty separate stocks. They use the basic Ricker equation of stock dynamics

(Ricker [9] which assumes a deterministic relationship between spawning stock and resultant run. Their solution involves

solving a set of equations iteratively by computer to arrive at the optimal exploitation rate.

*

Institute of Animal Resource Ecology, University of

British Columbia, Nancouver, B.C., Canada, and the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, Laxenburg, Austria.

(4)

There are several weaknesses in their solution, which are due to the analytic intractability of the problem. The authors calculate only the optimal exploitation rate, assuming the

population is at equilibrium. There is incredible variation in the actual stock recruitment relationships for salmon populations, and current management practice uses the concept of fixed

escapement instead of fixed harvest rate. The fixed escape- ment policy recognizes that the long term yield is maximized by allowing a fixed number of adult salmon to reach the spawning grounds, irrespective of the number of salmon in the total run.

When the stock is at high numbers it can be harvested at a higher rate than when it is at low numbers. Ricker [lo] has calculated optimal escapement for several stock recruitment re- lationships using numerical methods. Paulik et al. calculated the total run and optimal exploitation rate of all stocks at equilibrium. To derive the escapement one multiplies total run times the exploitation rate. It is not clear, however, that a fixed escapement policy is optimal for mixed fisheries. It is shown later in this paper that the optimal escapement is not independent of the relative abundances of the different stocks.

Specifically, if the fishery consists of two stocks, deter- mination of the optimal expl::.itation rate, or escapement, will depend on the sizes of the two stocks. This is not just a theoretical possibility; data collection associated with cur- rent management of salmon provides reasonably accurate run estimates of stock sizes so that it is definitely possible to implement these policies.

Methods

Current methods for determination of optimal exploitation rates use simple analytic analysis of very simple stock re- cruitment models to determine optimal exploitation rates at equilibrium. Much more complicated computer simulation models have been used to study fish stock dynamics, (Larkin and

Hourston [5]; Ward and Larkin [15])--but these models have not been used to determine optimal exploitation rates. It is

possible to use more complex models to test very simple control laws; for instance, constant harvest or constant escapement.

You simply have the same harvest taken every year and then calculate the average catch by simulating a large number of years. This method has been used to look at the role of

stochastic variation on simple stock recruitment models

(Ricker [I 01

,

Larkin and Hourston [5] )

.

It is theoretically possible and computationally practical to do the same sort of analysis on very complex models (Peterman [81). The main limitation is that the harvest policy must be the same every year. The harvest policy cannot be tied to the size of the various stocks except by fixing a total escapement. If we try to use a simulation approach for every possible combination of harvest rates as a function of stock sizes, the number of compu- tations required rapidly exceeds the ability of modern digital

(5)

computers. It is easy to understand that we wish to harvest harder when a stock is high than when it is low, as the fixed escapement policy automatically does for a single stock. But for a two-stock example, a fixed escapement policy does not differentiate between a case where two stocks are at moderate densities, and a case where one stock is very low and one is very high. The long term harvest can be increased by determin-

ing the harvest rate as a function of the stock sizes of both stocks, when harvesting a mixed stock.

A new methodology has recently been introduced to fisheries management (Walters [I41 which eliminates the computational

constraints and greatly widens the scope of optimization in fisheries. Walters used the technique of stochastic dynamic programing first developed by Bellman. (See Bellman [I];

Bellman and Dreyfus [2]; Bellman and Kalaba [3]. For other applications of dynamic programming to ecological problems, see Shoemaker [I 31

,

and Sancho [ I 1 1

.

) For a good description of stochastic dynamic programming, see Walters [141. Briefly, stochastic dynamic programming allows one to calculate optimal control policies by a procedure that involves the number of

computations increasing linearly, instead of geometrically, with the number of time steps. It requires approximation due to

discretization of the state vari.ables (stock size) and the con- trol policies (harvest rates). Walters used an example of a single salmon stock, discretized into thirty population levels, with thirty discretized exploitation rates and ten discrete

stochastic possibilities. This requires running a simulation of the stock dynamics 9 0 0 0 times per year. Using the simulation approach of following all possible paths into the future, say

2 0

twenty years, this would have required 9 0 0 0 simulations, clearly beyond the scope of current computers. However, using stochastic dynamic programming, only 9 0 0 0 x 2 0 simulations were required. This requires only a few seconds on a modern digital computer.

stochastic dynamic programming has five main advantages over previous analytic techniques. They are:

1) The stock recruitment model can be as complex as desired; the number of parameters in the model does not affect the computation time required or the re- liability of the results.

2) Parameters may be stochastic. However, as the number of stochastic possibilities considered for the param- eter values increase, so does computation time.

3) There may be judgmental uncertainty about parametric values. This is analogous to the stochastic vari- ability of parameters, but conceptually distinct.

4) The objective function (what is maximized) can be as complex as desired. It does not need to be

(6)

" l o n g t e r m c a t c h " ; it c a n b e " d o l l a r v a l u e o f c a t c h , "

" t o t a l employment g e n e r a t e d f r o m t h e f i s h e r y , " o r a n y c o m b i n a t i o n o f f a c t o r s .

5 ) D i s c o u n t i n g r a t e s c a n b e i n t r o d u c e d i n t o t h e model w i t h no p r o b l e m . The t o t a l o b j e c t i v e d o e s n o t need t o b e summed o v e r t i m e [ C ( O i ) ] , b u t may b e m u l t i p l i c a t i v e

[ n u + o i l ] .

A l t h o u g h t h e number o f c o m p u t a t i o n s g o e s u p l i n e a r l y w i t h t h e number o f t i m e i n t e r v a l s , i t g o e s u p g e o m e t r i c a l l y w i t h t h e number o f s t a t e v a r i a b l e s and s t o c h a s t i c p a r a m e t e r s . Thus w e a r e p r a c t i c a l l y r e s t r a i n e d t o o p t i m i z i n g m o d e l s w i t h on t h e o r d e r o f f i v e s t a t e v a r i a b l e s .

I h a v e c h o s e n t o u s e t h e s t a n d a r d R i c k e r s t o c k r e c r u i t m e n t model o f salmon d y n a m i c s ( R i c k e r [ 9 ] ) . Most w i l l remember:

R =

s

e x p ( a ( l

- g ) )

, ( 1

w h e r e

R = t h e t o t a l number o f o f f s p r i n g t h a t w i l l r e t u r n a s a d u l t s , S = t h e number o f s p a w n e r s ,

a = a p a r a m e t e r o f p r o d u c t i v i t y ,

B = t h e number o f s p a w n e r s a t which t h e a v e r a g e number o f r e t u r n i n g f i s h p e r spawner i s o n e .

I h a v e c h o s e n t h i s model b e c a u s e it h a s b e e n u s e d by a l m o s t a l l r e c e n t work o n salmon s t o c k d y n a m i c s , and p a r t i c u l a r l y by P a u l i k e t a l . [ 7 ] , and W a l t e r s [ 1 4 ] . his f a c i l i t a t e s com-

p a r i s o n o f r e s u l t s . I u s e d t w e n t y d i s c r e t e l e v e l s f o r e a c h s t o c k o f e i g h t e e n d i s c r e t e h a r v e s t r a t e s , and t e n s t o c h a s t i c o u t -

comes. A l t h o u g h a R i c k e r model was u s e d f o r t h e s t o c k r e c r u i t - ment r e l a t i o n s h i p , o t h e r commonly u s e d m o d e l s o f f i s h s t o c k r e c r u i t m e n t s u c h a s t h e B e v e r t o n - H o l t ( B e v e r t o n and H o l t [ 4 1 ) o r t h e S c h a e f e r model ( S c h a e f e r [ I 2 1 ) c o u l d b e s u b s t i t u t e d .

The s t a t e o f a s i n g l e s t o c k a t a t i m e i n t e r v a l i s d e s c r i b e d by a s i n g l e number, t h e s t o c k s i z e . W e c a n i n t h e o r y d e a l w i t h up t o a b o u t f i v e s e p a r a t e s t o c k s w i t h o u t r u n n i n g i n t o compu- t a t i o n a l p r o b l e m s . However, i t i s d i f f i c u l t t o p r e s e n t and u n d e r s t a n d t h e r e s u l t s o f o p t i m i z a t i o n w i t h f i v e s t a t e v a r i - a b l e s , s o I h a v e c h o s e n t o u s e j u s t two s t o c k s f o r d e m o n s t r a t i o n p u r p o s e s . I f t h i s t e c h n i q u e w e r e u s e d i n a c t u a l management;

it c o u l d e a s i l y b e u s e d on mixed s t o c k s o f f i v e s e p a r a t e s t o c k s .

(7)

R e s u l t s

S i n c e t h e c a l c u l a t i o n of o p t i m a l c o n t r o l p o l i c i e s r e q u i r e s c o m p u t a t i o n s on a computer, no g e n e r a l s o l u t i o n c a n be p r e - s e n t e d . What I w i l l do i s p r e s e n t o p t i m a l c o n t r o l s o l u t i o n s f o r a s e r i e s of p o s s i b l e p a r a m e t e r v a l u e s f o r two s t o c k s , and g e n e r a l i z e from t h e s e r e s u l t s . From e q u a t i o n ( 1 ) we c a n s e e t h a t t h e dynamics o f e a c h s t o c k a r e governed by two p a r a m e t e r s , a and B. For any two s t o c k s , t h e r e a r e f i v e u n i q u e r e l a t i o n - s h i p s between p a r a m e t e r s . They a r e :

1 ) a v a l u e s a r e t h e same and B v a l u e s a r e t h e same;

2 ) o n e s t o c k h a s a h i g h e r a v a l u e , and B v a l u e s a r e t h e same;

3 ) s t o c k 1 h a s a lower a v a l u e , and s t o c k 2 h a s a lower B v a l u e ;

4 ) s t o c k 1 h a s a lower a v a l u e and a lower B v a l u e ;

5 ) t h e a v a l u e s a r e t h e same, b u t one h a s a lower B v a l u e . S t o c h a s t i c dynamic programming c a l c u l a t e s a c o n t r o l law ( h a r v e s t r a t e ) a s a f u n c t i o n of t h e s t a t e v a r i a b l e s ( t h e two r u n s i z e s ) . To p r e s e n t t h e c o n t r o l l a w s g e n e r a t e d by t h e o p t i - m i z a t i o n p r o c e d u r e , I drew h a r v e s t r a t e i s o c l i n e s on a g r i d w i t h t h e r u n s i z e of s t o c k 1 on t h e X-axis and t h e r u n s i z e of s t o c k 2 on t h e Y-axis. F i g u r e 1 p r e s e n t s t h e c o n t r o l l a w s

f o r a c a s e where s t o c k 1 h a s a n a v a l u e of 1.0 and a B v a l u e of 1.0. S t o c k 2 h a s a n a v a l u e of 2.2 and a B v a l u e of 0.4.

These p a r a m e t e r s c o r r e s p o n d t o c a s e 3 above.

The i s o c l i n e s f o r h a r v e s t r a t e s of 0 , 0.3, 0.5, and 0.7 a r e drawn. S i n c e s t o c k 2 , on t h e Y-axis, i s more p r o d u c t i v e , t h e r e i s a h i g h e r h a r v e s t r a t e f o r Low v a l u e s o f s t o c k 2 t h a n t h e r e i s f o r low v a l u e s of s t o c k 1 . I n o r d e r t o compare

t h e s e r e s u l t s w i t h a c o n s t a n t escapement p o l i c y , we must u t i l - i z e some s i m p l e r e l a t i o n s h i p s . We know t h a t :

Escapement = (Run of s t o c k 1

+

Run o f s t o c k 2 ) ( 2 )

*

( H a r v e s t r a t e )

.

From t h i s we c a n c a l c u l a t e t h a t

Run of s t o c k 2 = Escapement

-

Run o f s t o c k 1

.

( 3 )

H a r v e s t R a t e

T h i s e q u a t i o n e n a b l e s u s t o p l o t t h e h a r v e s t r a t e i s o c l i n e s on t h e s t o c k 1 , s t o c k 2 s u r f a c e . I t i s a l s o e v i d e n t t h a t a l l

(8)

S T O C K 1

F i g u r e 1 . H a r v e s t r a t e i s o c l i n e s d e r i v e d f r o m d y n a m i c p r o g r a m m i n g ( t h i c k s o l i d l i n e ) a n d f i x e d e s c a p e m e n t

( d a s h e d l i n e ) . a a n d B v a l u e s a r e 1 . 0 a n d 1 . 0 f o r s t o c k 1 , a n d 2 . 2 arid 1 . 0 f o r s t o c k 2 .

(9)

i s o c l i n e s w i l l h a v e a s l o p e of -1. T h i s means t h a t u s i n g a c o n s t a n t e s c a p e m e n t p o l i c y , t h e o p t i m a l h a r v e s t r a t e l i n e s w i l l a l w a y s b e t h e same s h a p e , i n d e p e n d e n t of t h e p a r a m e t e r s a and B. The h a r v e s t r a t e i s o c l i n e s u n d e r a f i x e d e s c a p e m e n t p o l i c y h a v e b e e n drawn a s d a ~ h e d l i n e s i n F i g . 1 . I t i s o b v i o u s t h a t t h e o p t i m a l s o l u t i o n from t h e dynamic programming a l g o r i t h m i s q u i t e d i f f e r e n t from t h e f i x e d e s c a p e m e n t law d e r i v e d from P a u l i k e t a l . [ 7 ] . F i g . ~ ~ r e s 2 and 5 p r e s e n t s i m i l a r p l o t s f o r c a s e s 1 , 2 , 4 and 5.

D i s c u s s i o n

From t h e r e s u l t s i n F i g u r e s 1

-

5, i t i s c l e a r t h a t f i x e d e s c a p e m e n t i s t h e o p t i m a l p o l i c y o n l y when t h e two s t o c k s

h a v e t h e same a and B v a l u e s ( c a s e 1 ) . Thus, a f i x e d e s c a p e - ment p o l i c y f o r managing mixed s t o c k s of salmon i s o p t i m a l

o n l y u n d e r v e r y r e s t r i c t i v e c i r c u m s t a n c e s . The r e s u l t s o b t a i n e d a b o v e s u g g e s t t h a t i n g e n e r a l o n e s h o u l d h a r v e s t a mixed s t o c k h a r d e r when t h e r a t i o o f t h e two s t o c k s s t r a y s away from 1 : l .

T h i s s u g g e s t s t h a t a s o n e s t o c k becomes much more s i g n i - f i c a n t t h a n t h e o t h e r , t h e management s h o u l d p r o c e e d a s i f i t w e r e t h e o n l y s t o c k . I t a p p e a r s t h a t t h e e x p e c t e d b e n e f i t s

from r e d u c i n g t h e h a r v e s t r a t e s when o n e s t o c k becomes low a r e o u t w e i g h e d by t h e l o s s o f c a t c h from t h e r e d u c e d h a r v e s t . I t must b e s t r e s s e d however, t h a t t h e s e c o n c l u s i o n s a p p l y o n l y f o r t h e o b j e c t i v e f u n c t i o n maximized: e x p e c t e d a n n u a l a v e r a g e y i e l d . I f o t h e r f a c t o r s s u c h a s s t o c k d i v e r s i t y w e r e t o be i n c l u d e d i n t h e o b j e c t i v e f u n c t i o n , t h e o p t i m a l c o n t r o l l a w s would u n d o u b t e d l y c h a n g e .

S t o c h a s t i c dynamic programminq a p p e a r s t o be t h e b e s t c u r r e n t method f o r p r o d u c i n g c o n t r o l l a w s f o r mixed s t o c k s o f f i s h e s . The f a c t t h a t t h e a b o v e examples w e r e worked f o r P a c i f i c salmon s h o u l d n o t c a u s e o n e t o f o r g e t t h a t t h e t e c h - n i q u e s u s e d a r e c o m p l e t e l y g e n e r a l i z a b l e t o a v e r y l a r g e c l a s s o f f i s h e r i e s and o t h e r e c o l o g i c a l p r o b l e m s . The p r i m a r y l i m i - t a t i o n i s i n t h e number o f s t a t e v a r i a b l e s , b u t f o r any re- newable r e s o u r c e where some a n a l o g o f a s t o c k r e c r u i t m e n t c u r v e c a n b e c o n s t r u c t e d , t h e n a s i n g i e v a r i a b l e , t h e s t o c k , i s s u f - f i c i e n t t o d e s c r i b e t h e p o p u l a t i o n , and s t o c h a s t i c dynamic programming c a n be u s e d . The n a i n l i m i t a t i o n s o c c u r when a g e / c l a s s phenomena become i m p o r t a n t , s o t h a t s e v e r a l numbers a r e r e q u i r e d t o d e s c r i b e a p o p u l a t i o n . However, f o r a l m o s t a l l f i s h e r i e s p r o b l e m s , a s t o c k - r e c r u i t m e n t r e l a t i o n s h i p i s t h e b a s i s o f p r e s e n t management, s o u s i n g dynamic programming a s a n o p t i m i z a t i o n t e c h n i q u e would s e e m t o be most a p p r o p r i a t e . ( S e e P a r r i s h [ 6 ]

.

)

(10)

F i g u r e 2 . H a r v e s t r a t e i s o c l i n e s f o r c a s e 1 i n t e x t . S o l u t i o n f r o m

dynamic programming a n d f i x e d e s c a p e m e n t a r e i d e n t i c a l . a a n d B v a l u e s f o r b o t h s t o c k s a r e 1 . 8 and 1 . O .

(11)

STOCK 1

F i g u r e 3 . H a r v e s t r a t e i s o c l i n e s d e r i v e d from dynamic programming ( t h i c k s o l i d l i n e s ) a n d f i x e d e s c a p e - ment ( d a s h e d l i n e s ) . a and B v a l u e s a r e 1.0 and 1.0 f o r s t o c k

1 , and 2 . 2 and 1 . 0 f o r s t o c k 2 .

(12)

STOCK 1

F i g u r e 4 . H a r v e s t r a t e i s o c l i n e s d e r i v e d f r o m d y n a m i c programming ( t h i c k s o l i d l i n e s ) a n d f i x e d e s c a p e - ment ( d a s h e d l i n e s )

.

a a n d B v a l u e s a r e 1 . 0 a n d . 4 f o r s t o c k

1 , a n d 2 . 2 a n d 1 . 0 f o r s t o c k 2 .

(13)

F i g u r e 5. H a r v e s t r a t e i s o c l i n e s d e r i v e d f r o m d y n a m i c programming ( t h i c k s o l i d l i n e s ) a n d f i x e d e s c a p e - ment ( d a s h e d l i n e s )

.

a a n d El

v a l u e s a r e 1 . 8 a n d . 4 f o r s t o c k 1 , a n d 1 . 8 and 1 . 0 f o r s t o c k 2 .

(14)

T a b l e 1. a and B v a l u e s u s e d i n o p t i m i z a t i o n s .

C a s e No. S t o c k 1 S t o c k 2

a B a B

1 1.8 1 .O 1.8 1 .O

2 1.0 1 . 0 2.2 1.0

3 1 . O 1 .O 2.2 0.4

4 1.0 0.4 2.2 1 .O

5 1.8 0.4 1.8 1 .O

(15)

References

Bellman, R. Adaptive Control Processes: A Guided Tour.

Princeton, N.J., Princeton university Press, 1961.

Bellman, R. and Dreyfus, S. Applied ~ y n a m i c programming.

Princeton, N.J., Princeton university Press, 1962.

Bellman, R. and Kalaba, R. Dynamic programming and

Modern Control Theory. ~ s s 1965. ,

Beverton, R.J.H. and Holt, S.J. "On the Dynamics of Exploited Fish Populations." Fishery Invest. Lond.,

19, 2 (1957). 1-533.

Larkin, P.A. and Hourston, A.S. "A Model for Simulation of the Population Biology of Pacific Salmon."

J. Fish. Res. Bd. Canada, - 21, 5 (1964), 1245-1265.

Parrish, B.C., ed. "Fish Stocks and Recruitment."

Rapports et Proces-verbaux des Reunions." Vol. 164.

Conseil International pour lTExploration de la Mer, 1973.

Paulik, G.J., Hourston, A.S., and ark in, P.A. "~xploi- tation of Multiple Stocks by a Common Fishery."

J. Fish. Res. Bd. Canada, 24, 12 (1967), 2527-2537. - - Peterman, R.M. "New Techniques for Policy Evaluation in

Complex Systems: A Case Study of Pacific Salmon Fisheries. I. Methodology." J. Fish. Res. Bd.

Canada, forthcoming, (1 975)

.

Ricker, W.E. "Stock and Recruitment." J. ~ i s h . Res. ~ d . Canada, 11, 5 (1954), 559-623. -

Ricker, W.E. "Maximum Sustained Yields from Fluctuatinq

~nvironments and Mixed Stocks." J. Fish. Res. ~ d . -

Canada, 15, 5 (1958), 991-1006.

-

Sancho, N.G.F. "Optimal Policies in Ecology and Resource Management.

"

Plathematical Biosciences, - 17, ( 197 3)

,

35-41.

Schaefer, M.B. "Methods of Estimating Effects of Fishing on ~ ~ Populations." Trans. s h Am. Fish. Soc., - 97,

(1968), 231-241.

Shoemaker, C. "Optimization of Agricultural Pest Manage- ment, 111: Results and Extensions of a Model."

Mathematical Biosciences, - 18, (1 9731, 1-22.

(16)

[14] W a l t e r s , C . J . "Optimal H a r v e s t S t r a t e g i e s f o r Salmon i n R e l a t i o n t o E n v i r o n m e n t a l V a r i a b i l i t y and Uncer- t a i n t y a b o u t P r o d u c t i o n P a r a m e t e r s . " J. F i s h . Res.

Bd. Canada, f o r t h c o m i n g , ( 1 9 7 5 ) .

11 51 Ward, F. J. and L a r k i n , P.A. " C y c l i c Dominance i n Adams R i v e r Sockeye Salmon." I n t e r n a t i o n a l P a c i f i c

Salmon F i s h . Commission. P r o g r e s s R e p o r t No. 1 1 , 1964.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

In this work, we have analyzed and compared the complexity of three gradient based methods for the numerical solution of a risk-averse optimal control problem involving an elliptic

Summarizing all in one, the main result that follows from current analysis is that the microstructure theories can be to a certain extent successfully tested and different

In the paper we also provide modeling results for optimal (energy-efficient) running over 100 m: calculation of the minimum energy and trajectories of acceleration, velocity

Comparing rates of contemporary evolution in life-history traits for exploited fish stocks..

An evolutionary perspective will, therefore, i support the ecosystem approach to fisheries management 10–13 by considering how evolution alters ecological relations and

The purpose of this seminar is to provide a comprehensive introduction to the theory of Soergel bimodules, in particular, using diagrammatic methods.. Indeed, it is not an

The solution to dynamic linear programming problems usually seeks an optimal control for the entire planning horizon, [O,T].. This solution can, however, usually be altered after

I. Research Memoranda are interim reports on research being conducted by the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis, and as such receive only limited scientific