• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

The CEEC10's Real Convergence Prospects

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2021

Aktie "The CEEC10's Real Convergence Prospects"

Copied!
53
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

The CEEC10's Real Convergence Prospects

Martin Wagner, Jaroslava Hlouskova

20 Reihe Transformationsökonomie Transition Economics Series

(2)

The CEEC10's Real Convergence Prospects

Martin Wagner, Jaroslava Hlouskova April 2001

20 Reihe Transformationsökonomie Transition Economics Series

Institut für Höhere Studien (IHS), Wien

(3)

Contact:

Martin Wagner

Department of Economics University of Bern Gesellschaftsstrasse 49 CH-3012 Bern

(: +41/31/631 47 78 fax: +41/31/631 39 92

email: martin.wagner@vwi.unibe.ch Jaroslava Hlouskova

(: +43/1/599 91-142 fax: +43/1/599 91-163 email: hlouskov@ihs.ac.at

Founded in 1963 by two prominent Austrians living in exile – the sociologist Paul F. Lazarsfeld and the economist Oskar Morgenstern – with the financial support from the Ford Foundation, the Austrian Federal Ministry of Education and the City of Vienna, the Institute for Advanced Studies (IHS) is the first institution for postgraduate education and research in economics and the social sciences in Austria. The Transition Economics Series presents research done at the Department of Transition Economics and aims to share “work in progress” in a timely way before formal publication. As usual, authors bear full responsibility for the content of their contributions.

Das Institut für Höhere Studien (IHS) wurde im Jahr 1963 von zwei prominenten Exilösterreichern – dem Soziologen Paul F. Lazarsfeld und dem Ökonomen Oskar Morgenstern – mit Hilfe der Ford- Stiftung, des Österreichischen Bundesministeriums für Unterricht und der Stadt Wien gegründet und ist somit die erste nachuniversitäre Lehr- und Forschungsstätte für die Sozial- und Wirtschafts- wissenschaften in Österreich. Die Reihe Transformationsökonomie bietet Einblick in die Forschungsarbeit der Abteilung für Transformationsökonomie und verfolgt das Ziel, abteilungsinterne Diskussionsbeiträge einer breiteren fachinternen Öffentlichkeit zugänglich zu machen. Die inhaltliche Verantwortung für die veröffentlichten Beiträge liegt bei den Autoren und Autorinnen.

(4)

Abstract

The Central and Eastern European countries' prospects of becoming EU members depend heavily on, among other things, their per capita GDP levels. The growth prospects of these economies cannot be directly assessed, as the economic growth process in the transition countries is shown to not yet be described adequately by neoclassical growth theory. Thus, an indirect approach is taken, which maps the Western European growth experience on 10 Central and Eastern European countries (CEEC10). This indirect approach is used to project growth rates of the CEEC10 and the time required to close the income gaps to the European Union (EU). The sensitivity of the results is analyzed by presenting a wide variety of economically meaningful scenarios. Finally, possible beneficial effects of EU membership or pre-accession aids are studied. The effects on the reduction of the times to converge are computed.

Keywords

Transition economies, growth and convergence, EU accession

JEL Classifications

F02, F43, O11, O19

(5)

Comments

Financial support from the Austrian Ministry of Economic Affairs is gratefully acknowledged by the authors. The authors would furthermore like to thank H. Hutter and B. Meininger for their help with TeX and data issues and A. Wörgötter for valuable comments.

Preliminary Version: Please do not quote without permission.

(6)

Contents

1 Introduction 1

2 The Structural Stock of Transition 5

3 An Indirect Approach to Assess Convergence Prospects 18

4 Conclusions 31

5 Appendix 33

References 43

(7)

Sincethe collapseofthe SovietUnion andtheinduced majorsystemictrans-

formation from centrally planned to market based economies, for nearly all

the Central and Eastern European countries membership within the Euro-

pean Union is one, if not the, primary goal. However, the prospects of be-

coming a member of the EU depend strongly on the economic performance

of the respective applicantcountry. 1

Thus, anassessment ofpossibletiming

of EUmembershipof theindividualcountriesrequires anassessmentoftheir

economic development. One primary indicator of economic development is

(the evolution of) real per capita GDP. Of course also other economic and

politicalcriteria have to be fullled beforemembership can beachieved. As

all potential entrants, also the Eastern European applicant countries have

to meet legal standards and have to achieve satisfactory levels of political

developments. Criteriahave been formulatedat the Copenhagen summit.

In this paper we solelyfocus oneconomic growth and onrelative percapita

GDP levels of the Eastern European countries relative to the European

Union, which is a very important economic criterion for the timing of po-

tential entrance in the EU. The group of countries we investigate consits of

Bulgaria (BGR), Czech Republic (CZE), Estonia (EST), Hungary (HUN),

Latvia(LVA),Lithuania(LTU),Poland(POL),Romania(ROM),SlovakRe-

public (SVK) and Slovenia (SVN). This group of countries is, as indicated

above, labeled CEEC10 throughout the paper. Compared to many other

quantitative studies on transitioncountries, we restrict our attention to the

smaller group of countries that have expressed their willingness to join the

EU. Several studies include up to 26 countries, where usually also the non-

Baltic republicsof the former SovietUnion are included, sometimes alsothe

People'sRepublicofChinaand Vietnam(seee.g. deMeloetal,1997 orBerg

et al,1999).

ForalltheseEasternEuropeancountrieslistedabovetheroughpictureofthe

last decade is the following: The initialperiod of transitionis characterized

by drastic falls in output, high ination and rising unemployment (see e.g.

Kornai, 1994, Fischer, Sahay and Vegh, 1998a, Berg et al., 1999 or Fischer

and Sahay,2000). The most drasticexample is areal GDP growth of about

-40 % in Latvia in 1992. For most countries in the sample, with the excep-

tion ofBulgariaandRomania,outputstartedtogrowsustainedlyin1994 or

1995. Ination rates also soared up and some countries experienced hyper-

1

At the time being there are 13 applicant countries: The ten Central and Eastern

Europeancountries analyzedin thiscontribution,listedbelow,and additionallyCyprus,

MaltaandTurkey.

(8)

inations. Again with the exception of Bulgaria and Romania, by the end

of the 1990ies inationhas been brought down toone-digitor low two-digit

numbers. Thus, amongthese countries stabilization policy has been, grosso

modo, successfuland growth isnow experienced widely.

Economic growth in these countries depends on two sets of factors, see e.g.

Fischer et al. (1998b): On factors in relation totransition, which again can

be separated in initial conditions and reform policy, on the one hand, and

on the determinants of long-rungrowth as described by neoclassical growth

theory on the other hand. DeMelo et al. (1997) nd that initialconditions

do matter, but that the adverse eect of unfavorable initial conditions can

beovercome by strict commitmentto reform policy.

The further along acountryis onitstransitionprocess, the more important

will the standard neoclassical determinants of economic growth become. If

the growth process isdescribed adequatelyby the neoclassicaldeterminants

of growth (along the lines of Ramsey, 1928, Solow, 1956 or Cass, 1965),

then some clear predictions concerning the long-runco-movement of macro-

economicaggregatesfollow,likee.g. apositivecorrelationbetweentheinvest-

ment share and output growth. An assessment of possible ways to project

the future evolution of GDP growth in this countries requires rst an un-

derstanding of the experience so far. In section 2 we therefore investigate

the relationships between some macro-economic variables like GDP, invest-

ment and government consumption, which gure (of course) prominently

in the growth literature. The possible emergence of the standard correla-

tions between these variables,likee.g. the already abovementionedpositive

correlation between the investmentshare and growth, ora negative correla-

tion between initialGDP and subsequent growth, willindicate whether the

standard neoclassicalgrowth modelcan directly be appliedtoassess growth

prospects.

3

It turnsout, not too unexpected, that especiallyduringthe rst

part ofthe transitionperiodthese standardcorrelations cannotbeobserved.

I.e. during this period,the systemic collapseputs these countries toofar o

froma(balanced)neoclassicalgrowthpath,astoobservestandardbehavior.

During the later years of the sample, some emergence of expected relation-

ships, for instance a positive correlation between the investment share and

growth, can be observed. For both cases, whether the sample is split after

1993orforthefullsample,surprisinglyalwaysapositivecorrelationbetween

initialGDPandtheaverageGDPgrowthrateisobserved. Thus, upto1998,

2

Thedetailednumbersaregivenintable1insection2.

3

This negativecorrelationbetweeninitial GDPand average growthis usuallylabeled

unconditional-convergenceinthegrowthliterature. Ifitapplies,oneobservesatendency

ofnarrowingincomedierencesbetweenthecountries. Foramoredetaileddiscussionsee

thefollowingsections.

(9)

To gain further understanding about the evolution of the incomes 4

of the

CEEC10 since the beginning of transition we also apply simple methods of

distribution dynamics.

5

The positive correlation between GDP in1993 and

the average growth rate since then indicates that countries in a favorable

position in1993 have been able to take advantage of this. This may be the

case becauseof earlyreformthat putsthe respective countries inafavorable

situation or it could also be due to a longer lasting eect of positive initial

conditions.

An implication of the above observation is that growth projections cannot

be based directly on estimated growth equations for the CEEC10 group, as

applying theseequationswould implyto projectdivergentbehaviorbetween

the countries.

6

Thishowever, isnot the mostlikelyscenariotooccur: Given

that allthesecountries arepreparingthemselvesforEUmembership,similar

experiences with previous enlargements lead us to conclude that it is very

likely to observe a narrowing of income gaps, both between these countries

and with respect tothe European Union. Ben-David (1996) shows that al-

ready the prospect of EU membership has a positive eect onthe potential

entrants'economic performance. Given the currentexperienceof the macro-

economic evolution inthe CEEC10, an alternative approachto base growth

projections upon has to be found. The approach followed in this paper, is

to generate growth projections forthe CEEC10 onthe historically observed

growth process in the current EU member states since 1960. This means

that in a rst step, growth or convergence equations are estimated for the

European Union. Theseequationsare then used tocompute impliedgrowth

rates for the Central and Eastern European countries by insertingvalues of

the variables as observed in the CEEC countries oras specied in scenarios

to be described later.

Section3thereforestartswithaninvestigationofthegrowthandconvergence

behaviorobserved intheEuropean Union. A varietyofspecications ofcon-

vergence equations isestimated forthe EU14countries (by which wedenote

the EU15 excluding Luxemburg), which then serve as the basis for project-

ing the income prospects of the CEEC10. This approach has initiallybeen

4

ThetermincomeisusedassloppynotationforrealpercapitaGDP.

5

Wefollowtheline ofargumentdevelopedbyQuahinaseriesofpapersto assessthe

distributiondynamics,i.e. theevolutionofthejointdistributionofGDPsovertime. Due

tothesmallamountofobservationsweareconnedtoestimatetransitionprobabilitiesof

discretestateMarkovchains,seesection2.

6

Anextensivesummaryofempirical,regressionbasedgrowthliteratureiscontainedin

BarroandSala-i-Martin(1995)andinBarro(1997). Amethodologicallybroadersummary

isgivenin DurlaufandQuah(1998).

(10)

and Vegh(1998b)ourpaperrests onamoresophisticatedeconometricinves-

tigation,with a variety ofequations estimated by panel methods(compared

to pure cross-section regressions in Fischer et al., 1998a). The variety of

specications allows ustoassess therobustness of the results. Notethat the

equationsare estimatedfortheEU only,not foralargersampleofcountries,

and growth projections are only based on this approach for countries that

are applying forEU membership. Webelievethat forthe group ofcountries

investigated, this approach constitutes a feasible computationalexercise, as

already the lastdecade has witnessed a substantialamountof economic and

systemic convergence of the Eastern European transition countries to the

EU. Reforms in the CEEC10 are undertaken with reference to the institu-

tionalarrangementswithintheEU.The EUisthe mainforeigninvestor and

tradingpartnerofthesecountries. Thesestrengthened linkagesimplyloosely

speaking convergence inthe economic structure of the countries involved.

Based on the array of growth projections, derived from the dierent equa-

tionsandscenarios(seesection3),thenumbersofyearsittakesthecountries

of theCEEC10grouptoreachacertainlevelofaverage EUincomearecom-

puted.

7

Computing convergence times is of course more illustrative than

just presenting growth rate projections. All convergence time computations

are based on an assumed real per capita GDP growth in the EU15 of 2 %

per year. It turns out that, with the exceptions of Slovenia and the Czech

Republic, most of the countries still have more than 20 or 30 years to go,

depending on the scenario assumed, until they reach the specied relative

levelsof average European Union real per capita GDP.

Theorganizationofthepaperisasfollows: Insection2theexperienceinthe

CEEC10between1989 and1998 issummarizedand someinvestigationsinto

the distributionofpercapitaGDPsare presented. Insection3theequations

estimated for the EU are presented and discussed.

8

In this section also the

scenarios and the results basedon these scenarios are reported. In section4

some conclusions are drawn. In the appendix some additional gures and

tables related tosection 3are collected.

7

An exampleis70 %of theEU25averagerealpercapitaGDP,where withEU25we

denote all15 currentEU memberstatesandthe CEEC10investigatedtogether. This is

aninterestingrelativelevel,asthisisthepercentagethatPortugalandSpainhad,relative

to theEU12,whentheyenteredtheEUconsistingof10countriesbeforein1986.

8

Inaseparateappendix,availablefromtheauthorsuponrequest,someinvestigations

concerningthedynamicsofthedistributionofincomesintheEU15andforall25countries

togetherarecollected.

(11)

BGR 26.2 238.5 59.6 51.1 72.8 62.7 121.0 949.0 22.2

CZE 9.2 46.2 16.8 17.9 10.9 9.8 9.6 6.5 11.0

EST 304.0 954.0 36.0 42.0 29.0 14.6 12.5 4.4

HUN 25.7 25.4 21.6 21.3 19.5 25.5 21.2 18.5 13.4

LTU 383.0 1163.0 189.0 45.1 35.7 13.1 8.4 2.4

LVA 262.0 959.0 35.0 26.3 23.1 13.1 7.0 2.8

POL 480.1 55.3 38.5 30.5 28.4 27.9 18.7 14.0 12.0

ROM 13.6 195.0 200.1 227.4 138.9 35.2 45.3 147.0 45.9

SVK 6.6 34.6 11.2 15.4 13.8 9.7 4.5 6.6 5.1

SVN 490.8 94.9 208.2 37.1 22.6 15.2 11.1 8.8 7.3

Table 1: Annual inationrate inthe CEEC10. Source: WIIW, OECD.

2 The Structural Shock of Transition

In gures1 and 2the growth ratesof real percapitaGDP are displayed for

theCEEC10forallyearswheredatafortherespectivecountryareavailable.

9

These guresforcefully show the dramaticimpactof the breakdown of com-

munism and central planning. The most dramatic picture is, as mentioned

already intheintroduction,the onefor Latvia,withthe dramaticfallof real

percapitaGDPbyabout40%from1991to1992. Concerningthetworeform

laggards, Romania and Bulgaria, one sees that the limited amount of eco-

nomic reform in these countries has not been suÆcient toachieve sustained

growth. On the contrarythe Baltic republics,severelyhitby the disintegra-

tionoftheSovietUnion,havebeenabletoachievesustainedgrowthsincethe

mid1990ies. Thus, thesepictures conrmthe wellknown factthatthe tran-

sition phase can be split in an early phase of contraction and a subsequent

phase of stabilization and eventual growth.

In the early phase of transition ination rates soared up, see table 1.

Since themid1990iesinationhas been undercontrol,withthe exceptionof

Bulgaria and Romania. Many countries have achieved single-digit ination

rates in the mean time.

For an assessment of the growth prospects of the CEEC10 it is interesting

toanalyze thegrowth experienceup tonow. As pointed oute.g. byFischer,

Sahay and Vegh (1998a, 1998b)growth in transitiondepends ontwo sets of

factors. The rst set consists of the eects of the transition process itself.

This includes initialconditions and reform policy. Consensus in the litera-

9

The longest series are available for the Czech Republic and Romania back to 1961.

All seriesusedinthis paperend in1998.

(12)

Per Capita GDP Growth Rate for Bulgaria

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996

Per Capita GDP Growth Rate for Czech Republic

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

1961 1965 1969 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1997

Per Capita GDP Growth Rate for Estonia

-30%

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998

Per Capita GDP Growth Rate for Hungary

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

1961 1965 1969 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1997

Per Capita GDP Growth Rate for Latvia

-50%

-40%

-30%

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

1966 1969 1972 1975 1978 1981 1984 1987 1990 1993 1996

Per Capita GDP Growth Rate for Lithuania

-30%

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998

Figure 1: Growth rates of real percapita GDP for BGR, CZE, EST, HUN,

LVA and LTU; for all years when data are available. Source: World Bank,

own calculations.

(13)

Per Capita GDP Growth Rate for Poland

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

1971 1974 1977 1980 1983 1986 1989 1992 1995 1998

Per Capita GDP Growth Rate for Romania

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

1961 1965 1969 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1997

Per Capita GDP Growth Rate for Slovak Republic

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997

Per Capita GDP Growth Rate for Slovenia

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998

Figure2: Continuation: GrowthratesofrealpercapitaGDPforPOL,ROM,

SVK and SVN; for all years when data are available. Source: World Bank,

own calculations.

(14)

transition, but that theirimportanceis decliningrapidly (see e.g. deMelo et

al., 1997, Havrylyshyn, Ivorski and van Rooden, 1998 or Berg etal., 1999).

Especiallyitisfoundthatcountrieswithadverseinitialconditionscannever-

theless achieve a positive outcome by strong commitmentto -and therefore

a large extent of - reform. The second set of factors relevant for growth

prospects of transition economies are the standard forces driving long-run

economic growth asdescribed by the (one-sector)neoclassicalgrowth model

dating back to Ramsey (1928), Solow (1956) and Cass (1965). The further

time proceeds, the more relevant will the neoclassical growth determinants

be. Thus,unless agreat backlashisobservedinthesecountries,mediumrun

growth projectionsmaybebased aroundthe neoclassical growth framework

(with possibly allowing fortransitional eects).

Empirical research on economic growth has witnessed an enormous amount

of interestduringthelast10to15years. Oneofthe reasonsforthisrenewed

interest is the general current interest of the profession on growth theory,

another reason is the formulation and empirical investigation of dierent

notions of convergence within this framework. In essence, the neoclassical

growth modelin itsstandard formulation impliesthat alleconomies charac-

terized by the same underlying parameters (concerning e.g. the production

function) end up in the same steady state, regardless of the initialposition.

It furthermore implies a negative correlation between initial GDP and the

average growth rate. This phenomenon is usually labeled as -convergence,

ithasinitiallybeendened inSala-i-Martin(1990)andhasbeenpopularized

by a series of papers by Barro (1991) and Barro and Sala-i-Martin(1992a,

1992b).

10

For economies described by dierent parameters,the steady state

values may dier. This leads to the concept of conditional -convergence,

where a negative cross-section correlation between GDP growth and initial

GDPisobserved aftercontrollingforcrosscountrydierencesinparameters.

Thus, convergence implies,conditional orunconditional,atendency fornar-

rowing income gaps within agroup of countries.

Ingures3and4the(unconditional)correlationbetweentheaveragegrowth

rate of real percapita GDPand (the logof) initialreal percapita GDP, the

averageshareofinvestmentofGDPandtheaverageshareofpublicconsump-

tion of GDP are shown. In gure 3 this is done for the whole period 1989

to 1998 and in gure 4 the correlations are displayed over the sub-periods

1989 to 1993 and 1994 to 1998.

11

Growth theory predicts a positive corre-

10

AlreadyBaumol(1986)andDeLong(1988)investigatelong-runconvergencebetween

incomesofdierentcountries.

11

The timing convention in this paper is thefollowing: The initial year is alwaysthe

year prior to the period overwhich averages are computed, e.g. for the period 1994 to

Abbildung

Table 1: Annual ination rate in the CEEC10. Source: WIIW, OECD.
Figure 1: Growth rates of real per capita GDP for BGR, CZE, EST, HUN,
Figure 2: Continuation: Growth rates of real per capita GDP for POL, ROM,
Figure 3: This graph shows in clockwise order the correlation between the
+7

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

The hypothesis of positive influence of FDI on economic growth will be tested in this paper on the basis of World Bank data on influx of FDI in the region of Southeastern Europe,

This paper suggests an empirical procedure to further extend the neoclassical growth model to distinguish between the growth and level effects of shift variables like the

In this section the outcomes of both short and long run linear Granger causality tests as well as the results of the analysis of nonlinear Granger causal links are presented.. This

t ui npm aecm ai hkvw^xm i faesybz ped {ahd e|am a{cbad gc} }~i hbchcgm ani ghej gmd `aracm ekvvl €wbpa d gf`chnaei hm ani ghc}f} ceei j i fcd i gh. q ‚gpm fagjƒcei

Comparing the result for each country from the group of ETE we may summarize our findings as follows: (1) Especially countries with lower GDP per capita seem to benefit from

While the overall benefits from the cross- border capital movements significantly contributed to the high rates of real output growth in ETE (most of the countries from this

De cet objectif principal, on dérive deux objectifs spécifiques : (i) réexaminer le processus de convergence réelle au sein de l’UEMOA ; (ii) analyser l’effet du pacte sur

6 例如: Ehrlich and Lui (1991), Blackburn and Cipriani (2002), Boldrin and Jones (2002), Kalemli- Ozcan (2003), Doepke (2004), Zhang and Zhang (2005), and Soares (2006)。. 7