• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Two Scales, One Methodology - Expenditure Based Equivalence Scales for the United States and Germany

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Two Scales, One Methodology - Expenditure Based Equivalence Scales for the United States and Germany"

Copied!
51
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Munich Personal RePEc Archive

Two Scales, One Methodology -

Expenditure Based Equivalence Scales for the United States and Germany

Merz, Joachim and Garner, Thesia and Smeeding, Timothy M. and Faik, Jürgen and Johnson, David

Forschungsinstitut Freie Berufe (FFB)

April 1994

Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/7233/

MPRA Paper No. 7233, posted 18 Feb 2008 14:35 UTC

(2)

FFB Forschungsinstitut Freie Berufe

Fakultät II - Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft

Postanschrift:

Forschungsinstitut Freie Berufe

ffb@uni-lueneburg.de http://ffb.uni- lueneburg.de

Universität

L Ü N E B U R G

Two Scales, One Methodology -

Expenditure Based Equivalence Scales for the United States and Germany

Joachim Merz, Thesia Garner, Timothy M. Smeeding, Jürgen Faik and David Johnson

FFB Discussion Paper No. 8 April 1994

(3)

Two Scales, One Methodology -

Expenditure Based Equivalence Scales for the United States and Germany

Joachim Men, Thesia Gamer, Timothy M. Smeeding, Jürgen Faik

and David Johnson*

Discussion Paper No. 8

April1994 ISSN 0942-2595

This paper evolves out of our current research with the hancial Support of the U.S.

National Institute on Aging, Program Project #I-Pol-Ag09743-01, "The Well-Being of the Elderly in a Comparative Context. It is also available as the Cross-National Studies in Aging Program Project Paper No.8, All-University Gerontology Center, Maxwell School of Citizenship and Public AfFairs, Syracuse University, Syracuse, New York 13244-1090.

*Prof. Dr. Joachim Merz, University of Lüneburg, Department of Econornics and Social Sciences, Director of the Research Institute on Professions (!3orschungsinstitut Freie Berufe), Thesia Garner and David Johnson, U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Prof.

Timothy M. Smeediig, Project Investigator, Syracuse University, Maxwell School of Citizenship and Public AfFairs, Jürgen Faik, University of Franldürt.

(4)

Acknowledgements

The research for this paper is part of an National Institute on Aging Programm Project No. Pol-AG09743 at Syracuse University under the direction of Richard V. Burkhauser and Timothy M. Smeeding. The German CO-partners in this paper are Jürgen Faik, University of Frankfurt, and Joachim Merz, University of Lüneburg. The United States Partners in this paper are Thesia Garner and Pavid Johnson of the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics.

We would like to thank the former Sonderforschungsbereich 3 at the University of Frankfurt, financed by the German National Science Foundation, and the German Federal Statistical Office, Wiesbaden, for the opportunity to use an anonymized and reduced actual sample of the German Income and Consumption Suwey (EVS) as our German microdata base.

The fust dr& of this paper was presented to the Gerontological Society of America in November 1992. We would like to thank Patricia Ruggles and Stephen Jenkins for helpful comments on an earlier dr&. This paper was rewritten to reflect these comments. The manuscnpt was typed by Laura Griffin and Ester Gray of Syracuse University. The findings presented here do not represent the official position of the U.S.

Department of Labor or the Bureau of Labor Statistics. The authors accept responsibility for all errors and omissions.

Forschungsinstitut Freie Berufe (FFB)

Fachbereich Wirtschafts- und Sozialwissenschaften Universität Lüneburg

Schamhorststraße 1, Gebäude 4 21335 Lüneburg

Tel.: +0413 1/78 2051 Fax.: +04131/78 2059

Germany

(5)

Two Scales, One Methodology -

Expenditure Based Equivalence Scales for the United States and Germany Joachim Merz, Thesia Garner, Timothy M. Smeeding,

Jürgen Faik and David Johnson

FFB-Discussion Paper No. 8, May 1994, ISSN 0942-2595

Abstract

Choosing an appropriate equivalence scale is a prerequisite for comparisons of economic well- being income distribution, inequality or poverty. This is true for country specific work or for cross-national comparisons. Researchers generally either use a country specific equivalence scale (social assistance, expert based, or poverty scales), or adopt a single scale for all comparison across countries. Here we follow a different approach. We use microdata to estimate equivalence scales based on a revealed preference consumption approach for West Germany and the United States. We review several approaches and rely on a complete demand system approach, which provides constant utility based equivalence scales using an extended linear expenditure system (ELES). The multiple equation expenditure system takes into account a full market basket with all its interdependencies and relative prices. Our consumption-based equivalence results are compared to alternative consumption based measures, expert based measures, and subjective based measures in use in both countries and to other scales used for cross-national comparisons.

JEL: I30, I32, D30, D31

Keywords: alternative equivalence scale, Germany, USA, distribution of income, inequality, poverty

Zusammenfassung

Die Wahl einer passenden Äquivalenzskala ist Voraussetzung für Vergleiche der Ein- kommensverteilung ökonomischer Wohlfahrt, Ungleichheit und Armut. Dies gilt vor allem für länderspezifische Analysen und/oder für länderübergreifende Vergleiche. Es werden von Forschern entweder eine jeweils landesspezifische Äquivalenzskala (Sozialhilfe, Experten basierte oder Armutsskalen) oder eine einzige Skala für einen mehrere Länder umfassenden Vergleich verwendet. Wir verfolgen hier einen unterschiedlichen Ansatz. Wir verwenden Mikrodaten um Äquivalenzskalen zu schätzen, die auf offenbarten Konsumpräferenzen für die alte Bundesrepublik und die Vereinigten Staaten basieren. Wir überprüfen verschiedene Ansätze und beziehen uns auf einen nachfragetheoretisch fundierten Systemansatz, der konstante nutzenbasierte Äquivalenzskalen über ein erweitertes lineares Ausgabensystem (ELES) liefert.

Dieses multiple Ausgabegleichunmgssystem trägt einem vollen Warenkorb mit allen seinen Interdependenzen und relativen Preisen Rechnung. Unsere konsumbasierten Äquivalenzskalen werden mit alternativen Skalen, expertenbasierte und Skalen subjektiver individueller Einschätzung und anderen Skalen verglichen, die in beiden Ländern Verwendung finden und für länderübergreifende Vergleiche benutzt werden.

JEL: I30, I32, D30, D31

Schlagwörter: Alternative Äquivalenzskalen, Deutschland, USA, Einkommensverteilung, Ungleichheit, Armut

(6)

Cross-National Studies in Aging

Staff

Richard

V.

Burkhauser Project DUector Timothy M. Smeeding Project Investigator

Sheng Zhu Project Programmer

Loweii Lutz Project Programmer Detlef Jurkat Project Translator

Affiliated Researchers

Greg Duncan University of Michigan Richard Hauser University of FranldÜrt Joachim Merz University of Lüneburg

Thesia Garner U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics Barbara Boyle Torrey National Academy of Sciences

Research Staff

Deborah Bailey Research Assistant Barbara Bumca Research Assistant

M a r ~ Daly Research Assistant

Jack Lawrence Research Assistant Inge O'Comor Research Assistant J o b G. Poupore Research Assistant Stephen Rhody Research Assistant

Administrative and Support Staff

Margaret Austin Administrator

and

Budget Oficer Maruia W. Bomey Administrative Coordinator

Esther Gray Administrative Secretary

Contact:

All-University Gerontology Center

Maxwell School of Citizenship and Public Affairs 426 Eggers Hall, Syracuse University

Syracuse, New York 13244-1090 United States of Amenca Telephone: (3 15) 443-2703 Internet: mbonney@maxwell.syr.edu

Fax: (315) 443-1081

(7)

TWO SCALES,

ONE

METEIODOLOGY-I3XPENDlTUR.E

BASED

EQWALENCE SCALES

FOR TBE

UNITED STATES

Introduction

Equivaience scaies are used in measuring the economic resources (income, wealth) available to persons in households of different &es and compositions. They are an integd part of most economic weii-being comparisons involving income distribution, inequality and poverty. Buhmann, Rainwater, Schmaus, and Smeediig (1988), has shown that different national equivaience scales and approaches produce differences in the measurement of household needs, and aiso in intergroup and international comparisons of poverty and income position using different equivalence scaies. Hence, the equivalence scaie used can importantly affect the outcome of such studies.

This paper offers an alternative to the current Set of equivalence scaies by using microdata to estimate a Set of equivalence scales based on reveded preference for Wen Germany and the United States, using the Same methodology for each nation. Our paper is part of a joint United States and German research project to compare equivalence scales using consistent methods and similar microdata from the household expenditure s w e y s of both countries.

We review severai approaches to estimating these equivalence scales, but rely on a complete demand system approach as specified by an extended linear expenditure system (ELES) to provide constant utility based equivalence scaies. This multiple equation expenditure system takes into account a fuil market basket with all its interdependencies and relative prices.

(8)

For purposes of international comparison, most analysts rely on one equivaience scaie, testing sensitivity of the basic results to the scaie chosen (e.g., Förster, 1993). When two countries are used, for example the United States and Gemany, anaiysts try to use each nation's own scale and test the sensitivity of the results by substituting one nation's scaie for another's ,and vice versa a (e.g., Bukhauser, Duncan, and Hauser, 1991). We follow a different approach, one which considers both the economic and ktftutional dierences of two nations. Employing one nation's scale on another nations people would ignore differences in the provision of "ment" goods, such as health care and education, across these two nations.

Our one methodology approach explicitly allows for national differences in consumption weights and goods pnces to affect the resultant scaies. Moreover, comparisons of cross- national and intra-national income dismbutions are supported by a consistent methodological basis whereby adjustments for differences in consumption needs are determined by actual consumption Patterns and not by expert judgements or by public opinion. We also compare the equivalence scales enimated here to different scales irnplicit in German and United States social policy toward the aged, in poverty measurement, and in other policy and program issues where household size adjustments are called into play.

Our project began with Merz and Faik's (1992) estimates of several types of consurnption based equivalence scales for Germany. These were the first such scales ever estimated in Germany. A sirnilar research approach was used by Phipps and Garner (1992) to cornpare the United States and Canada. The resulting equivalence scales were

"indistinguishable statistically or practically" (Phipps and Garne:, 1992, p. 18). However, the results of our analysis do produce different equivalence scales for both nations. After additional a d j m e n t s , at the suggestion of the American Partners, we selected a Set of methods, defuiitions and equations which were then re-estimated for both nations.

(9)

The paper is arranged as foiiows: the second section briefiy embeds our approach within the general literature on equivalence scales. We then review revealed preference consumption expenditure-based equivalence scaies and speciSr our Engel single equation expenditure approach and the ELES complete demand System approach. Next we describe the microdata bases,

a

sample of the most recently available West German Income and Consumption Survey (EVS) for 1983 and eventually the

U.S.

Consumer Expenditure Survey (CEX) for 1983. The empirical results are discussed and compared to other scaies in the literature in the last section.

Equivilence Scales for Welfare Comparisons:

Aim, General Approaches, and Issues

Equivaience scales deflate household income according to the household type to

"calculate the relative amounts of money two different types of households require in order to reach the same standard of living" (Muellbauer, 1977, p. 460). Given equal preference or utility levels u for w o households and constant prices @), an equivalcnce scale (e) of a household with composition (U) relative to that of some reference household with composition (Uo) then is defmed as

e = c(u.p,a)Jc(u.p,ao) = Y I Y ~ , (1)

where C(.) is the cost function of reaching utility level u and y is the moncy income of the respective household.

Economies of scale and differences in individual needs by age suggest that a per capita measure of household income which gives equal weight to each person a crude equivalence scale. Unadjusted household income implicitly contains yet another type of scaie-a zero adjustment for differences in household size and composition. A behavioral based approach to equivalence scales producc results which are more sensitive to such diierences.

(10)

Equivalence approaches can be divided into three general categories: expert, subjective, and consumption based.' Expert b.ased equivalence scales are defined by physiological and socio-cultural basic needs stated by some experts. Examples are "Zentimetergewichte" (height

*

weight) (Engel, 1895), physiological and further basic needs (Rowntree, 1901), or basic food expenditures (Orshansky, 1965). Subjective equivalence scales are based on individual surveys asking either for the minimum income needed by a typical household or for the minimum income for the respondent's own household (Kapteyn and van Praag, 1976; Kapteyn, Kooreman and Willemse, 1988; van Praag et al., 1982; deVos and Gamer, 1991 are examples of these).

Consurnption based equivalence scales rely on revealed preferences measuring actual consumption expendimes of different household types. Single consumption equation methods

f k

dealt with either absolute expenditures with specific adult and children goods (Rothbarth, 1943) or budget shares (Engel, 1557) where the incorne relation y/yo is given by identical relative expenditures. Later, multiple consurnption equation rnethods encornpassing several goods to capture different economies of scale in different goods were developed (Prais and Houthakker, 1955, generalizing the Engel rnodel).'

More recently, the complete dernand systern approach has bein based on cost h c t i o n s defined by rnicroeconornic theory (and its duality assumptions) and incorporaring the household allocation problem for a full rnarket basket of expendimes (Barten, 1964; Gorman, 1976;

van der Gaag; and Smolensky, 1982). Though we ignore the issue here, recent research in this area has also addressed the issue of inua-household allocation of resources via a household production approach (Gronaq 1988).'

. .

(11)

Revealed Preference Consumption Expenditure Based Equivalence Scales: Our Approach and

' Impiicit Choices

In this paper we concenmte on one revealed preference consumption based method-the complete demand system ELES approach. As an expendime based model this approach is behaviordy based and relies on actual expenditures of different household types to estimate an equivaience scale, rather than using physiologicdy based needs (e.g., minimum quantities of minerais or vitamins) or socidy and politicaily determined "needs." We experimented with the Engle (1 975) single equation approach because of its use as a traditionai reference in practice but decided to rely on the rnore general ELES approach as argued by van der Gaag and Smolensky (1982) and Betson (1990).

Tne cornplete dernand systern approach is a rnore general approach than the Engel approach, taking into account the consurnption of a full rnarket bashet satisfying individual needs and preferences in a closed demand systern. Lluchos (1973) Ex~ended Linear Expenditure System (ELES) the dernand system can be derived frorn rnavimization of a lifetime utiliry function under a lifetime wealth constraint (Kakwani, 1980)~ The two period intertemporal utility rnavimization problem which yields the Same results (van der Gaas and Srnolensky, 1982) is

"th

Ci

ßi = 1, v,/mi > g, (goods: i = I ,..., n; periods: t = 1,2), where vti = expendime of good i in period t, 6 = the subjective utility discount factor, T = interest rate, Öi = marginal budget share, g, = subsistenct expenditures, and with m;:

(12)

mi = I +

da

1 (4)

as commodity specific wei$Ihng factos yielding mi = 1 for the reference household with a=O.

Constrained o p h k a t i o n yields the current penod linear expenditure vstem:

0 0

V . I = a . I + ß.- I + uia resp. I

I

(3

vi = gi + u 1 .U + ßip(z

-

x j g j ) (i = 1,

...,

n),

with (z

-

Ejg) as supernumerary income and

0 0

ai = gi

- Pi &.

gj,

Pi

0 = ßip, where p = [(I + 6)/(2 + 6)](2 + x)(1 + X), and

-

0.d.

-

ßiCjg,dik 0 a i ~ - P I rk

as the elernents of the household cornposition coefficients s-vector ai, with goods i, j = I , ..., n and household characterinics k = I, ..., s.

0 0 0

After estimation of a; ,

Pi

and ai with

Ci Pi

=

C.

I ßip = p C . r~

P.

= u the srnicnual

coefficients ßi and ,q. are given by

The dual of the utility rnavimization problern with its Stone-Geary utiliry function yields the following cost function (Dearon and Muellbauer, 1980):

C , ) =

C

gi(i + d a ) + exp

I

u

- C

ßiloeßy +

C

ß)og(i + d a ) ] .

(13)

Finally, the aue, constant util* household equwalence scaie with respect to differentes in household composition is given as in (1) by the hction of both households' cost functions e = c(u,a)/c(u, a d .

The s t r u c d iduence of the household composition, gven by the s-vectos di (i =

I,

..., n), which is important to calculate the utility level, the cost function value, and commodity specific weighting factors, can be derived via equation (6) by solving the linear expenditure systemS

A d = U:, with d k = A(,,,,)cuk, -1

(4 k (k = 1, ...J),

0 I I

with A(ij) = + ( I -

P i )

for i=j and -ßO OJ W . else; d k = (dlk ,..., dnk) and crk = ( a i k

,...,

anJ

.

To caiculate ELES expendinire equivalenct scales, three important questions conctrning the underlying approach need be answered:

Which basker of goods should we utilize?

How should we incorporate household cornposition?

Which resource or budget consaaint rneasure should be used?

Which Good, or \%ich Basket of Goods? Traditionally, food is the central category fulfilling the rnost basic needs. Our food category compnses basic food, seni-luxury food and rneals out of home. klany equivalence scales irnplicitly presented in Social Assisrance stipends and other sirnilar minimurn consumption standards progams are based on a basket of goods. We considered two baskets of goods: food, clothing, and shoes, and housing and energy (goods basket I) and goods basket I plus body and health care (goods basket 11), to describe basic standard of living for expenditures in indusbialized countries. We selected goods basket I1 for our modeling. Food policy and goods basket I results are available from the authors upon request

(14)

How Should We Incorporate Household Composition? In bringing demo~raphics into the ELES model, we follow the Barten (1964) approach using a linear combination of household composition dummies, a procedure which is comparable to the van der Gaag and Smolensky (1982), United States approach.6 Here we can either specify a separate household type and give each a dummy (i.e., two adults, one child household, etc.), or we can combine a more or less homogeneous group (like the number of persons in age groups) to form a polytomeous dummy variable. We follow the second approach in our model.'

Which Resource or Budget Constraint Bleasure Should be Used? As mentioned above, the budget consuaint regressor might be either total expendimes or some measure of household income capturing saving and dissaving processes. Our anaiysis will show the results for both resource measures. T'he question of a permanent income measure to better capture the durable expendime problem nill be discussed within the complete demand System.

Microdata: West German Income and Consumption Survey 1983 and the United States Consumer

Espenditure Survey 1986-87

Two databases were used to estimate our equivalence scales, the West German Income and Consumption Survey (Einkommens- und Verbrauchsstichprobe, EVS) and the Unired Stares Consumer Expendime Survey (CEX). The project staff identified a common Set of variables and aggregation of variables for the purpose of estimating this Set of equivalence scales.

West Germin Incume and Cousumptiou Survey 1983

The most recently available and extensive cross-section microdata base for household economic research in Germany is the Income and Consumption S w e y (1983). Information about this survey of more than 44,000 households (ail persons living together regardless of

(15)

mari-iage or birth Sam), with detailed expenditure and income microdatq is summ-ed in Table 1A. To protect respondents' privacy an anonymized 96 percent random sample of the original EVS (1983) was made avaiiable to us for our analysis, reducing our wnple to 42,752 units. This sampIe, was provided by the Sonderforschungsbereich 3 "Microanalytic Founda- tions of Sociai Policy" at the Universities of Frankfurt and blamheim, financed by the Gernan National Science Foundation.

'

Our sample is restricted to German-headed households of four than seven members.

Household inforrnation consists of household characteristics, income, transfer and tau information of a variety of sources. Consumption expenditures are aggegated into 20 categories. Additionally, socio-demogaphic information about each Person in every household was also used. Variable defuiitions are presented in Table 2.4.

United Ststes Consumer Expenditure Survey

A basic description of rhe u'nired Sutes Consumer Expenditure Survey ( C E 3 dara which underlies this report is contained in Table 1B. This survey is used to compute rhe

United Stares consumer pnce index and to collecr statistics on expenditures by various household units. The sample used for this srudy was resmcted to consumer units participating in four complete interviews (or interviews 2-5) in 1986-87. The sample included 5,073 consumer units. This sample was reduced to 4,972 consumer units when resuicted to units with fewer than seven persons. For the analysis in which income was used as an explanatory variable, the sample was W e r reduced to 4,373 by restricting it in order to calculate the ELES System (see Garner and Blanciforti, 1993, for further information). Variable d e f ~ t i o n s q e given in Table 2B.

(16)

TABLE 1A

WEST C E R i i W ' S iNCOME AND CONSUMFTION SURVEY (EINKOMMENS- UND VERBRAUCHSTICHPROBE, EVS) 1983

Legal basis:

Federal sraristic: Bundessmistik-Gesen (BStatG) I 4 M k 1980: 196263, 1969, 1975, 1975, 1983 (1988).

Sample:

Quota sample with voluntary parricipation (Euler, 1982).

Observations: 0.2 percent of all private households in West Germany (ca 50,000 households

&oss)), 44,507 households fmally to analyze, reduced by 4 percent to 42,752 for our purposes.

Not included: households of foreignen, households in insrinitions, households with a monrhly net household income 2 250,000 DM. Remaining households represent c a 92 percrnt of all West German households.

Number of variables per household: 548.

P- --

Questionnaires/Methods:

First interview (Gmdinrerview) January 1983:

Sociodemo,gaphics, durables available Over the year bookkerping (Haushalrungsb ücher):

Monthly (for 11 months) information (laufende Monaüanschreibungrn): one figure for an enrire respective rnonth (gathered in a four month booklet (Vieneljahresheft)):

all income figures irnporrant expendinires

One month of daily information (Feinanschreibung) by a smtified rotation procedure:

daily information:

detailed smaller private consumption expendinires (open question) food and semi-luxury expendirures (open quenion)

Final interview (Schlußinterview) January 1984: Wealth (selected items) and savings.

Further Information:

Euler, M. 1982. Einkommens- und Verbrauchsstichprobe (EVS) 1985, in: W i c h a f t und Starisrik 611982, pp. 453-57.

Statistisches Bundesamt (1984 and various years), Fachserie 15, Wichaftsrechnungen, E i o m m e n s - und Verbrauchsstichproben, Heft 7. Aufgaben, Methode und Durchfiihtung, Sniugan und Mainz.

Y '

Wirtschaft und Statistik1 (WiSta), various years.

(17)

2

-

TABU 1B

UNITED STATES CONSUMER EXPENDiTTJRE SURVEY INTERVIEW, 1986-87

L q a I Basis and Justifiatioß for the Consumer Expenditure Suwey (Interview and Diary):

To produce weighrs for the Consurner Rice index and to present statistics on the spendiig of connimer unirs.

Suwey Sample:

National probabiliry sample, matified by primary sampling uni8 (PSü's) thar comin of counries (or pam thereof), goups of counties, or independent cities.

The sample of households is desiged to represent the civilian noninstitutional population and a ponion of die instimtional population living 'in gouped quarters, includiig college and univenity housing, living in the four Census regions of the United States.

The sample size is targeted at approximately 5,000 interviews per quarter or every three months.

About 86 percent of the eligible sample unirs participated in an interview during the period for this study.

The d e s i p is such ihat each consumer mit is to be interviewed once per quarter for five consecutive quaners, and zhen rotated out of die sample.

QuestionnaireMethod:

During the initial personal interview, information is collected on demopphic and family chmcterisrics and on the inventory of major durable goods of each consurner unit.

The second thmugh fifh interviews use uniiom questionnaires to collect household and memDer information and expendinire data for die previous three months in general.

Detailed income data such as wage and salary earnings, unemplopent cornpensation, child suppon and alimony. and employent information on each household member, are also obtained in die second and fifth interviews. Asset and liabiliry dara are also collected in the fifth

interview. Ninery to 95 percent of total consumer expenditures are collected using die Interview (USDL, 1990).

Further Information:

Gamet, T. and Blancifoni, L. 1992. "Household Income Repon Completeness: An Analysis of U.S.

Consumer Expenditure Survey Data," ASA Proceedings of the Secrion on Economic und Business Starutics 1991, Atlanra, G.4. Alexandria, VA: American Statistical Association.

U.S. Depamnent of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1990. Comumer Expenditure Swvt"/, 1987, Builetin 2354. Washingon, DC: U.S. Government Pnnting Office, June.

(18)
(19)
(20)

Empirical Results

.

We besjn with basic cornparative statistics describing each sample used in our anaiysis.

Regression and equivalence scaie results foIIow. Findy, our resuits are compared to other commody used equivalence scaies in both nations.

German Microdata Descriptive Measures

Descnptive information based on weighted individual data representing a total population of 23.5 miliion households in West Germany (1983) is given in Table 2A for seven aggegated consumption expenditure categories: food, clothirig and shoes, housing and euer=, transportation and cornrnunication, body and health care, education and entertainment, and personal belongings and other goods and services (our goods basket) period. Table 3A gives figures for these categories plus household net income and a computed remainder (household net income minus private consurnption). As shown in Table 3A, housing and energy (19.6 percent) and food (15.6 percent) amount for the largest shares of income with body and health care (3.6 percent) the smallest share of income. The

variante:

measured by the coeficient of variation, is highest wirhin body and health care, the category with the lowest average expenditures.

It should be noted that Table 3A o d y comprises households with positive values for income. It includes 22 percent (100-33,146147,745) of households with a negative remainder, indicating some dissaving or use of credit. Table 4.4 presents descnptive measures for the household rypes we use in o w regression d y s e s . The breakdowns encompass single persons and rnarried couples with and without children. A distribution of units by household size is also presented.

(21)
(22)

1

TAIILE 38

DESCRII"i'1VE MEASUIIES O P EXPENDI'i'URE ANI) INCOME CATECORIES IN T l l E 1986 UNITED Sl'ATES C0NSl)RlER EXPENDITUltE SURVEY

(iii ilolliirs)

Ex~ieirililiies Pood

Clotliinc aiid slioes Iloiisine. and eiierav

Transporialion aiid coiiiniiinicatioii ßodv and Iieallli care

Ediicatioii aiid eiiteriai~iiiieiit Ollier coods and services

Reiiiaintler Haskel I ßasket II

Iloiiseliold net incoiiie Tolal Expenditures

Reniarks: Only cases wliere coiisiiiiier iiiiit iiel iiicoiiie > 0, expeiiditiires 1-7 > 0. coiisiiiner units are complele incoine reporlers as defined by DLS, and consuiner ui\i(s participaie in ilie survey iiiicrview quarlers 2-5. Meiiii, slaiiilüril deviatioii aiid Sliiiean are based oii weiglited sample. All calegories are based oii loial s ~ n p l e of 4,323 rel,reseiitiiig a pol~olülioii of 69,545,216. I'ercc~il of Iioiiseliolds witli iiegalive or Zero expendiiures giveii in last column.

Legend: Mem = average expeiidiliires; pcrcenl = biidget sliarcs; reiiiiiiiider = Iiouseliold iiet iiicoine nliiiiis all expendiiures vl (i=1,

...,

7).

I'erceiit 15.64 3.69 26.20 19.89 5.61 6.59 11.73 10.65 45.53 51.13 100.00 89.35 Me;iii

3,939.95 930.56 6.601.55 5,012.23

1.412.54 1.66 1.63 2.955.46 2,684.01 11.472.06 12.884.60 15.197.94 22.513.92

Sliiiiil;ird I)cvl;~tioii

2.443.00 1.059.12 4,208.08 5.851.52 1.845.59 2.542.61 3.823.80 19.598.91

6.544.87 7.182.09 25.277.75 14,864.48

Sl;iiid;ir<l

I ) f v i i i l i i ~ i i

1Mc;iii 0.620

1.138 0.637 1.167 1.307 1.530 1.294 7.102 0.571 0.557 1.003 0.660

Mciliiii~

3.564.00 638.65 5.954.45 2.922.00

1,028.40 98 1 .00 1,933.15 692.66 10,496.60 11,908.30 20.283.30 19,572.40

Miii 30.00

0.00 0.00 0.00 -4.313.00

0.00 0.00 -98,490.98

769.00 932.24 50.75 1,721 .OO

Max 28.294.00

11.055.26 73,890.94 44,349.09 45.268.00 72.637.00 96,874.43 794.837.19 88,910.43 92,132.43 897.3 13.00 159,94 1.68

Skewiiess 1.719 3.282 3.242 2.189 9.042 7.490 6.186 14.924 2.1 19 2.014 10.447

1.976

Kurlosis 7.297 17.891 28.709 5.659 159.849 129.725 93.075 505.420 11.154 9.749 280.222 7.781

Noii- posillvc (pereenl)

0.00 3.28 0.07 0.30 1.02 1.71 0.62 46.43 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00

(23)

TAIILE 4A

DESClllPTlVE MEASURES OF 1IOUSEIIOI.D COMPOSITION IN TIlE 1983 CERMAN CONSUMPTION SURVEY

Ilouseliold Type Shigles

I. all

2. siales, agcd 18 to 64 3. feiiiales, aged 65 or over Sliigle Purc~it, agetl 18 to 64 4. and 1 cliild

5. aiid I cliild, aged 0 to 6 6. aiid I cliild, aged 7 10 17 7. und 2 cliildren

Murrled coulilcs

8. bolli aged 18 to 65 or ovcr 9. botli agcd 18 to 64

10. botli aged 65 or over 11. oiie aged I8 to 64 1

one aged 65 or ovcr 12. aiid I cliild

13. aiid 1 cliild, aged 0 to 6 14. aiid I cliild. agetl 7 lo 17 15. and 2 cliildreii

16. aiid 3 cliildreii 17. aiid 4 cliildreii

Niiiiihcr of Iloiisclioltls

7,574 4,702 2.872

497 112 385 183

10.419 6,421 2,382 1,613

5,53 1 2.653 2,878 .

5,876 1,329 202

Nuiiiber 01 Iloiiseliolds

7.4 1594e6 3.86477e6 3.55 114e6

309,630 80,583 229,047

99.65 1

5.97656~6 3.48383e6

1.60179e6 89 1,026

1.33976~6 1.12886e6 1.2 10We6 1.90751e6 448,031

73.619 Suiiilile

Perceiit of I'ersoiis

17.72 1 1 .OO

6.72

1.16 0.26 0.90 0.43

24.37 15.03 5.57 3.77

12.94 6.2 1 6.73 13.74 3.1 1

, 0.47

Pcrceiit of Iloiiseliolds

99.66 6 1.87 37.79

3.97 0.89 3.07 1.96

83.16 5 1.27 19.0 1 12.87

59.22 28.40 30.81 6138 43.59 26.79

Poliiilatioii Percent of

Persoiis

3 1.59 16.47 15.13

1.32 0.34 0.98 0.42

25.46 14.84 6.82 3.80

9.97 4.81 5.16 8.13 1.91 0.31

Percent 01 llouseholds

99.64 51.93 . 47.7 1

4.31 1.12 3.19 2.40

83.24 48.52 22.3 1 12.41

56.4 1 27.22 29.20 58.60 39.40 23.78

(24)
(25)

1'AnLE 411

I>ESCItII'TIVE MEASURES OF IIOUSEIIO1.I) COMI'OSITION IN TIIE 1986 UNITED STATES CONSUMER EXPEN1)ITURE SURVEY

Ilouseliold Tylie Sliigles

I. all

2. males, aged 18 to 64 3. feniales, aged 65 or over S l n ~ l e Pareiii, ngcd 18 to 64 4. aiid I cliild

5. aiid I cliild, aged 0 io 6 6. and I cliilil, aged 7 io 17 7. aiid 2 cliildren

Married coiiples

8. boili aged I8 io 65 or ovcr 9. boili agcd 18 io 64

10. i~oili aged 65 or ovcr I I. oiie agcd 18 io 64 1

one aged 65 or over 12. md 1 cliild

13. and I cliild, aged 0 to 6 14. and 1 cliild. aged 7 io 17

15. and 2 cliildt'eii 16. aiid 3 cliildreii 17. arid 4 cliildreii

Niiiiilier of Iloiisrliulils

1,07 1 615 456

97 26 7 1 82

96 1 573 276 112

334 1 69 165 399 195 44

Niiiiiber o l Ho~iseliolds

17,367,574 9,613,607 7,753,968

1,626,684 475,543 1,151,141 1,425,646

16,34 1,054 9,610,367 4,785,127 2,625,739

5,426,280 2,808,559 2,617,720 6,240,610 2,877,207 612,879 Saniple

I'ercciit 01 l'ersoiis

24.77 14.23 10.55

2.24 0.60 1.64 1.90

22.23 13.25 6.38 2.59

7.73 3.91 3.82 9.23 4.5 1 1.02

Percciit oT Iloiiseliolds

100.00 57.42 12.58

7.51 2.02 5.52 10.59

74.67 44.52 21.45 8.70

43.15 21.83 21.32 56.60 54.30 33.59

Fopulalloii Percenl of

Fersons

24.97 13.82 11.15

2.34 0.68 1.66 2.05

23.50 13.86 6.88 3.78

7.80 4.04 3.76 8.97 4.14 0.88

Fercenl o l Houseliolds

100.00 55.35 44.65

7.46 2.04 5.28 11.58

74.99 44.24 2 1.96

12.05

44.09 22.82 21.27 56.69 54.13 34.92

(26)
(27)

United States Mcrodata Descnptive Measures

Information presented here is based on approximately 69.55 miIlion United Stares connimer units in 1986-1987 with four i n t e ~ e w s in Tables 3B and 4B closely paraiiering the German descriptions in Tables 3A and 4A. The Same seven aggregate data categones available for Germany have been replicated in the United States by aggregation of the more detailed United States expenditure categories (See Table 2B). Weighted mean totd consumption expenditures in the United States in 1986-87 e q d %23,301. Consumer unit weighted mean net income (icome before taxes minus income and all property taxes and payrnents for Social Security and Railroad Retirement) is $26,180 (Table 3B). Housing and energy account for the largest percentage of income share (23.78 percent). Transportation and communication follow with 20 percent. Food cornes in third at 15.5 percent. The mailest income share is ailocated to clothing and shoes (3.75 percent) (Table 3B).

The weighted sample is cornposed rnostiy of rnarried couple consurner units (60.7 percent) while singles represent 23.3 percent of the total sarnple. Elderly single persons represent 9.34 percent, while married couples, with both persons aged 65 or older, represent 7.8 percent. Married couples, with both persons aged 18 to 64 years with one to four children represent approximately 31 percent of the sample (Table 4B).

ELES Complete Demand System Approach

Tne fuil market basket in our ELES estimates encompasses seven expendihire categories: food, clothing and shoes, housing and energy, transportation and communication, body and Iiraith care, education arid entertainment, and personal belongings and other goods and services. By the Statisticai Office's definition in Germany, these expenditures describe private consumption; cimilar c o m c t i o n was rnade for the United States.

(28)

In the theoreticai approach with equation

(3,

the income measure is intertemporal wealth, z, hcorporating saving and dissaving processes. Our proxy, household net income (rather than total expenditures = personal consumption) is incorporated in the estimates which follow.

The ELES complete demand vstem reduced form coefficients, as in equations (3) through

(7,

were estimated equation by equation ushg OLS following the Zeiher (1962) seemingiy unrelated regression approacbg These results are shown in Tables 5A and 5B and 6A and 6B. The goodness-of-fit measured by the adjusted R~ shows a range from 8 percent (body and health care) to housing and enera (46 percent), which is quite good for a Cross section analysis. The seven categories encompass private consumption expenditures with a total marginal propensity to consumer

Ci

b i = 0.46 indicating a high remainder marginal propensity to consume. Since the remainder captures-besides saving and dissaving-a variety of other e ~ ~ e n d i n i r e s ' ~ and the so-cdled "natistical diierence" (survey errors concernhg total expenditure minus income), a relatively high remainder value is plausible.

The ELES equivalence scales depend on a selected income level of the reference household type [z -> v i -> u -> C()]." It is an empirical question whether the scale is positively or negatively correlated with the income level because the ELES full market basket approach includes both basic goods (with an income elasucity normdly < 1) which have an opposite effect. Thus, the empirical results in Tables 7A and 7B contain differential effects accordhg to different income Ievels.

Despite wide income ranges used, from subsistence to 1.5 times the median, the corresponding equivalence scales do not vary greatly by income level. This result corresponds with the findings of van der Gaag and Smolensiq (1982) based on the U.S. Consurner Expenditure Survey 1972173 and with the United States results given in Table 7B. Dierences

(29)

TAnLE 5A

CEIlRlANY E1,ES: REGRESSION 1IESUI;I'S ACCORI>INC T 0 SOCIODEMOCRAPIIIC VARIAULES

Expeiidilure Ciitcgory Food

Cloiliing aiid slioes Iloiising nnd energy

Traiisporlatioii aiid coiiiiiiiiiiicnlio~i Dody aiid healili care

Ediicaiion and eiiieriainiiie~il Ollier goods nnd services

Reiiiarks: (I) t nol sig~iilicn~il al IIic 0.1 percciil Icvel; * iioi sigiiificniil iil ilie I perceiit level; iill ollier paraiiielers are sigiiificanl al llie 0.1 perceiil Ievel.

(2) süniple size: ii = 42,745 (iiel incoiiie > 0; cxl>eiiililiircs 1101 rcslricled).

Legend:. a = coiisiaiii; I> = iiei iiicoiiie; iiiiiiiber of persoiis iii nge classes: C , (aged 0-6). c2 (aged 7-17), C, (aged 18-64), c4 (aged 65t); cS = funlly staius of lioiisehold Iieiid (> 18 yenrs; iiinrried = I, i~oiininrried = 0).

11' 0.386 0.285 0.455 0.160 0.076 0.196 0.200 OLS l'iiriiiiielcrs

11

1.874.126 528.963 3.163.374 797.649 281.848 1,000.9 14 1,210.206

11 0.052 0.042 0.08 1 0.093 0.034 0.059 0.IOI

C,

36.406' -163.700

73 1.327 -78.658' 262.974

153.282 -52 1.295

c2 95 1.087 214.425 771.158 -221.692 -43.807.

274.5 12 -339.497

C,

1,489.878 202.843 577.949 572.515

-

174.425

-80.440' -461.801

c4 1,160.554

-77.277' 724.564 -785.277 93.548' -490.151 -47 1.898

c5 1,020.596

167.526 . 37.043' 413.006 2 18.454 -63.089' 643.002

(30)

1'Alll.E 511

UNITEI) STATES ELES: ItliCltESSION ItESULTS ACCC~RDINC T 0 S0CIOL)EMOCItAI'IIIC VARIAULES

Expeiiditure Calegory Food

Cloiliing and slioes liousing and energy Traiisportaiion and coniinunicaiion ßody and Iiealth care Educaiion and enlertairiineiii Oiher goods and services

Reniarks: (I)

+

nol sigiiiiicaiil ai ilie 0.1 perceili level; ++sigiiificaiii at .05 ievei; . t t + sigiiilicanl ai .I0 level; all oilier parainelers sigiiiticant a1 .001 level. (2) saiiiple size: ii = 4,323 (iiet iiicoiiie > 0; exlieiitliiiires iioi resiricied).

Legend: a = coiistaiii; b = nei iiicoine; iiiiiiiber of Iiersoiis iii age cl;isses: cl (agetl 0-6). cz (aged 7-17). C, (aged 18-64), c4 (aged 65.1.); = fanlily siaius of hoiiseliold Iiead (Z 18 years; iiiarried = I, iioiiiiiarried = 0).

Adj. 1t2 .449 .275 ,288 ,203

.097 .I99 .252 0I.S Pnrnaielers

n 1,154.49

184.84 3.509.39 852.77

409.76 308.75 833.53

Ii

0.035 0.017 0.074 0.055

0.010 0.036 0.070

ci -53.36'

9.09'

- 133.87' -377.66'

- 4 4 . 3 ~ ' ~ 49.76' -15.46'

e2

520.5 1 157.62 155.49'"

1 12.90'

29.34' 190.13 -77.45'

C,

766.76 152.27 405.32 1,362.33

164.65 148.33''

41.12'

c4 385.98

-36.65' 539.71 45.01'

747.20 -250.89'' 77.8 1'

C,

680.14 64.95ttC 827.84 1,179.20

345.76 454.02 508.74

(31)

'VAIl1.E 6A

CEIlhIANY ELES: ItECllESSION I1ESUI.TS ACCOllDlNC T 0 IlOUSEllOLD SlZE

Expeiiillliire Ciilceory Food

Clotliing antl slioes Iloiisiiig aiiil energy

Trniisporluiion piid co~iiiiiiiiiicülioii nody aiid Iiealili eure

Ediicnlion aiid eniertaiiiiiieiit Otlitr gootls and services

~ ~ ~ ( I ) ~i. 1101 ~ sig~iificiiiit ~ k s iit :tlie 0.1 Iicrcciii level; * iioi sig~iiii~iiiii iil IIie I perceiit level; iill ollier paraineters are significanl al Ilie 0.1 ~~erceiit Ievel. (2) siiiiiplc sk~c: 11

-

42,745 (iict iiicoiiic > 0; exlieiiililiires iioi rcsiricled).

I.egeiiJ: a = coiistaiil; b

-

iiel iiicoiiie; niiiiilier of persons iii age classes: C,, ..., c5: 2,

...,

6 persons (as 011 diiinmies).

.

1t2 0.365 0.275 0.454 0.149 0.069 OLS I';iraiiieters

P

2,1195,300 549.4115 3.759.605 536.352 286.838 723.237 616.185

I) 0.050 0.044 0.079 ~ 0.099 0.032 0.058 0.101

C I

2,370..102 268.335 732.628 826.912

-114.635' 182.398 409.590 453.955 306.345 -213.830' -555.749 -961.142

c2 3,473.498

505.348 1,534.393 1,525.575

270.713' 0.189' -1,545.565 0.200

58.259' -16.408'

P-

C)

4,221.367 7 17.076 2,095.531

1,478.343

-322.157'

--

c4 5,162.813

716.480 2,710.411 1,398.042

c5

5,937.595 573.637 3,285.845 1,109.1 14

(32)

TAIILE 61)

UNlTED STATES ELES: ItECRESSION RESULTS ACCORDINC T 0 IIOUSEHOLD SIZE

Expeiitliture Cniegory Food

Clotliing aiid slioes Housing md energy

Transporiatioo and communicaiioii Dody and Iiealih care

Education and entertainnient Oilier goods and sewices

Remarks: (I)

+

1101 sigiiificaiii ni tlie 0.1 I~erCeiit Ievel;++Sigiiificiili( n1 .05 Icvei;.kl-i. sigiiilicalii al .I0 level; all otlier paraineters sigiiificaiil at ,001 level.

(2) saiiiple size: ii = 4,323 (iiel incoiiie > 0; expeii~liliires iiol resiricietl).

Legeiid: a = coiisiaiit; L> = nel iiicoiiie; ii~iiiiber of licrsoiis iii nge classes: c l (aged 0-6). c2 (aged 7-17), C, (aged 18-64), cq (aged 65-1.); cS = faiiiily siatus of liouseliold Iiead (> 18 years; iiiarried = I, ooiininrrietl = 0).

Adj. li2 0.410 0.263 0.280 0.168 0.038 0.191 0249 OLS I'nrnnieiers

n 1,7 16.890

262.3 16 3,881.633 1,550.050 848.838 3 15.460 891.964

Ii 0.0'IO 0.0 18 0.077 0.066 0.010 0.038 0.072

C!

1,033.552 96.075'

'

1,063.808 1,500.583 475.737

172.379++*

290.279"

c2 1,702.495

307.270 1,148.046 2,76 1.367 3 13.509 705.790 490.853''

C,

2,206.106 506.446 1,463.440 3,254.873 345.532 933.714 396.2 17"

c4 2,594.1 10

610.111 1,370.837 3,014.674

423.165 1,107.180 254.020t

c5 3,014.980

55 1.756 1.3 13.250 3,472.505

335.442"

596.053"

123.552'

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

Each panel shows the evolution of ARP rates for a given household type based on different thresholds for poverty or poverty risks (50% and 60% of median equivalent income) and

Recent OECD publications (e.g. OECD 2011, OECD 2008) comparing income inequality and poverty across countries use a scale which divides household income by the square root

It is easy to see that classical propositional logic L PL has the intersection property simply by definition: the standard model semantics is typically firstly defined for single

Strong Equivalence for Argumentation Semantics Based on Conflict-Free Sets.. Sarah

Together with the results from [12], we now know how to characterize strong equivalence for the following semantics of abstract argumentation: admissible, preferred, complete,

In contrast, we have shown that colorectal adenocarcinoma tissues with high C3 expression have a higher proportion of resting mast cells and a lower proportion of activated

In summary, these large observational studies of this thesis analysed ex- isting hypotheses and contributed to the evidence of different risk factors for gout such as diuretic

The present study addresses this question by investigating the distributional behaviour of the additive scalar particle even relative to scales whose focus alternatives