• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Technical Notes on (Steady-State) Comparative Statics in Section 3

3 A Fixed Exchange Rate Regime: Argentina After the Stabilization

5.3 Technical Notes on (Steady-State) Comparative Statics in Section 3

It is also useful to notice that

) . Thus, the following must be true:

a) If r(1)(1), then well defined. In addition, as I mentioned before, <0.

b) If r(1)(1), then well defined. Also, notice that, as I mentioned before, >0.

Thus, from (A.33), it follows that

 

5.3 Technical Notes on (Steady-State) Comparative Statics in Section 3

5.3.1 Steady-State Equilibria in a Walrasian Regime

Comparative Statics with respect to the Policy Parameters  and  Differentiating equation (65) with respect to  and , respectively, I obtain

(1 *)( 1)((1 ) )( (11)(1 ) ) *(1 )

2 0,given 1,

In addition, differentiating equation (63) also with respect to  and , respectively, one gets

Finally, differentiating equation (64) with respect to  and , respectively, yields

,

Effects of Increases in *, r, d or f on the capital-labor ratio (kˆ)

Given equation (62), it is obvious that there is a negative relationship between kˆ and .

Then, it will be sufficient to show the effects of *, r, d and f on . Differentiating (56) Differentiating equation (65) with respect to * yields

(1 *)( 1)( (1) (1 ) ) *(1 )

2 0. expression

.

Notice that ( 1)0 for lending to be positive.

Comparative Statics under a Currency Board

In a currency board, the subsidy rate on capital can be written as

(1 *)( (11)( )( )1)((1 ) ) *(1 )

.

Differentiating (A.46) with respect to r, one obtains

(1 *)( (11)( ) () (1 )(1 ) ) *(1 )

2 .

Thus, the subsidy rate on capital  is increasing in r.

On the other hand, differentiating equation (64) with respect to r, we obtain the following expression

. Then, the share of net investment abroad in total savings is increasing in the world interest rate r.

Regarding the effects of changes in domestic reserve requirements, I start with the analysis of increases in d. Differentiating (A.46) with respect to d, one gets

 

.

This condition always holds if

.

Obviously, (A.51) always holds under a currency board and, therefore, 0

 Similarly, differentiating (46) with respect to f yields

 

This condition always holds if

.

Again, it is obvious that (A.55) always holds under a currency board and therefore,

straightforward to show that ˆ is increasing in f: Thus, differentiating (64), one obtains ˆ 0

Comparative Statics under a Pure Fixed Exchange Rate

In a pure fixed exchange rate regime, the subsidy rate on capital can be written as

(1 ) *(1 )

.

By inspection of (A.57), it is obvious that 0

Thus, the share of net investment abroad in total savings is always increasing in r.

Next, differentiate (A.57) with respect to d to obtain

(1 (1 ) )(1*(1 ) )

2 .

In addition, differentiating equation (64) with respect to d, yields

   

Using (A.43), (A.59), and (A.60) I am able to determine that the share of net investment abroad is increasing in d for all but very small values of *.

In similar way, differentiating (A.57) with respect to f I obtain

 

Differentiating equation (64) with respect to f, I obtain

. investment abroad is increasing in f for all but very small values of *.

5.3.2 Steady-State Equilibria in a Credit Rationing Regime

Comparative Statics with respect to the Policy Parameters  and 

Differentiating equation (68) with respect to  and with respect to , and using (A.35) as well as (A.36) I am able to determine, respectively, that

 

 

obtains. 2 and using (A.35), (A.36), (A.63), and (A.64), I am able to determine that

obtains,

Finally, differentiating equation (69) with respect to  and with respect to , and using (A.35), (A.36), (A.63) and (A.64), I am able to determine, respectively, that

 

 

obtains, 2

 

 

obtains. 2

Comparative Statics under a Currency Board

Proof of Proposition 8 In this section I proceed to prove Proposition 8 as well as the corresponding results for a Case 2 economy arises for the case when a currency board is in place.

I start with the analysis of the effects of increases in * on the capital-labor ratio k~ . Differentiating equation (68) with respect to * one obtains

   

In addition, using equations (A.58) and (A.65), gives

     

Obviously, under a currency board =1 and [0,(1-d-f)), and therefore (A.70) becomes

 

Notice that the first term in the numerator of (A.71) is positive if ).

In addition, recall that 0(1-d-f) by assumption. Thus, (1-) is unambiguously increasing in * r in situations where [c,(1d f)) holds and a currency board is in place. As a consequence, k~ is decreasing (increasing) in * if Case 1 (Case 2) obtains or, equivalently if r(1)(1)().

On the other hand, notice that if (0,c), the first term in the numerator of (A.71) is negative and, obviously,

 

*

 is decreasing in r. Also, while the denominator in (A.71) is always positive, we can rewrite the numerator as

( )( )

,

) 1

)(

(d f d f  rd  d fd  (A.73) and, therefore

 

parameter values similar to the ones found in Latin American countries and, therefore, it seems that r<rc always holds. Therefore, under plausible conditions, (1-) is also an determine that

 

Using (A.41) and (A.44), (A.75) can be rewritten as

Obviously, under a currency board =1 and [0,(1-d-f)), and therefore (A.76) can be rewritten as

 

obtains

if ,

while when Case 2 obtains

if . respectively.

Notice that, under a currency board

). Also notice that if Case 1 (Case 2) obtains

) case, it is straightforward to show that

 

Notice that when Case 1 obtains

) . increasing function of *. On the other hand, notice that when Case 2 obtains and when both [0,c) and r<rc hold, on the case where r<rc. It is straightforward to show that

) , accordingly. On the other hand, using also (A.81) and (A.85), it is possible to determine that x>xc when Case 2 obtains and both [c,(1d f)) and r<rc hold. Thus, under these circumstances, ~ is always increasing in *. Q.E.D.

Effects of Increases in r on k~

and ~ I start with the analysis of the effects of increases in r on k~

. Differentiating equation (68) with respect to r, I obtain

   

Using (A.42) and (A.47) I obtain

 

r , unambiguously. If )

r , then (1-) is always increasing in r. I next proceed

to analyze when the last condition holds.

 

) . 1

(

) (

) 1

( r

1

) 1

(

) 1

)(

1 1 (

1

 



 



 



 

 

f d

f d f

d d

f d

d f

d

r

(A.88)

Obviously, if [c,(1d f)), the right-hand-side of the second inequality in (A.88) is negative, and the inequality always holds, resulting in (1-) being always increasing in r. On the other hand, if [0,c), the right-hand-side of the second inequality is positive. In this case, it is helpful to rewrite the second inequality in (A.88) as

d(1 (1d f ) (d) f)

.

f

r d

  (A.89)

Notice that, given that both r>1 and

d(1(1df)(d)f)

1

f

d , (A.89) might

hold (or not), especially if  is very close to c. Thus, when [0,c), (1-) is increasing in r for all values of * but maybe those arbitrarily close to 

 

 1 1

r . I can then say that (1-) is typically increasing in r, [0,(1d f)),





 

 

 

* 1 1 , *

Max r .

Now, I return to the analysis of equation (A.86). When Case 1 (Case 2) obtains, both r(1)(1)() and

(1)x(1)

()0 hold, and, therefore, k~

is decreasing (increasing) in r, given that, as we have previously proved, (1-) is typically increasing in r.

Next, I analyze the effects of increases in r on the share of net investment abroad in total savings. Differentiating equation (69) with respect to r, I obtain

) . obtains and a currency board is in place, 0

~ 

r

 . However, when Case 2 obtains and a

currency board is in place, both k~ and  are increasing in r, resulting in two forces that act in opposite directions. In this case, it is helpful to rewrite (A.90) as