• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Consider a very simple model along the lines of Alesina and Rodrik (1994). Population is normalized to one, and aggregate (as well as per capita) output is

y=Akαg1−α (4)

wherekis the aggregate capital stock andg is the amount of public goods provided. The economy consists of one firm operating under perfect competition, takingg as given, so that the wage rate and the rate of return on capital are

w = (1−α)Akαg1−α (5a)

r = αAkα−1g1−α (5b)

The public good is funded by a tax rate of (τ) on the assessed value (a) of the capital stock so that g=τ a. Note that the assessed value will not necessarily be exactly equal to the capital stock.

An individual’s income depends on their wage income, which is identical across all individuals, plus the return to their personal capital, minus the tax on the assessed value of their personal capital,

yi=w+rki−τ ai. (6)

If the assessed value of personal capital is exactly equal toki, then this simply reduces to the model as originally written by Alesina and Rodrik. The net return on capital for an individual is then r−τ, and as this is identical across all individuals, all individuals make the same choice of savings rates, and so there is no change in the distribution of capital across individuals over time.

To introduce redistribution into this analysis, let us assume that the assessed value of capital is related to the actual value of capital in the following manner,

ai=kγ+1i (7)

and the value of γ ∈ (−1,1). The aggregate assessment is simply a = P

iai and the aggregate capital stock isk=P

iki. To see the effect of different values ofγ, consider the assessment rate of capital, orai/ki,

ai

ki =kγi. (8)

As can be seen, ifγ >0 then the assessment rate on personal property is progressive, or increasing in the amount of personal capital. However, ifγ <0, then assessment rates are regressive and an increase in the amount of personal capital results in a lower assessment rate. A value ofγ =−1 implies a simple head tax. In the specific case that γ= 0 then each person has an assessment of ai=ki, as in the original Alesina and Rodrik model.

So what is the optimal tax rate from the perspective of individuali? Let us assume only that the individual is interested in maximizing income. The individual is presumed to be inconsequential enough to ignore the effect of their choice on the level ofkor the assessment ratea/k. Usingg=τ a along with (5a) and (5b) in equation (6) we get

yi = (1−α)Akα(τ a)1−α+αAkα−1(τ a)1−αki−τ kγ+1i . (9) Maximizing overτ yields the following solution for τi, the individual’s optimal tax rate,

τi=

In the median voter model, the tax rate implemented will be equal to the optimal tax rate of the median individual, who holdskm in assets. Assuming that there is some inequality in the distribution of assets, then it must be the case thatkm< k, or the median individual has fewer assets than the average individual. A natural measure of inequality is then the ratio k/km. Increasing values ofk/kmindicate increasing inequality.

The question now is how the optimal tax rate changes with inequality. Holding kconstant, it can be shown that the relationship ofk/kmto the implemented tax rate,τm, depends crucially on regressiveness of the tax itself. Ifγ=−1 then we have a head tax, and τm declines as inequality (k/km) increases. If taxes are regressive and−1< γ < α−1 then taxes will decline with inequality up to a point. As long as k/km < γα/((1−α)(−γ−1)) then taxes fall as inequality increases.

Once inequality is high enough to cross this threshold, then the median voter has so little wealth that the punitive tax rate does not offset the gains they get to wages from voting for more public goods. Finally, ifγ > α−1, then taxes increase with inequality no matter initial inequality.

The important point is that for some combinations of γ and k/km, the relationship between

inequality and taxes is negative, even though there is full voting and the median voter decides the tax rate.

References

[1] Acemoglu, Daron and Maria Angelica Bautista and Pablo Querubin and James A. Robin-son, 2007, ”Economic and Political Inequality in Development: The Case of Cundinamarco, Colombia,” working paper.

[2] Acemoglu, Daron and James A. Robinson, 2000, ”Why Did the West Extend the Franchise?”

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 115, pp. 1167-1199.

[3] Aghion, Phillippe and Patrick Bolton, 1997, ”A Theory of Trickle-Down Growth and Devel-opment,” Review of Economic Studies, 64, pp. 151-172.

[4] Alesina, Alberto and Edward Glaeser and Bruce Sacerdote, 2001, ”Why Doesn’t the U.S. Have a European-style Welfare State?” Brookings Papers on Economic Affairs (2), 187-277.

[5] Alesina, Alberto and Dani Rodrik, 1994, ”Distributive Politics and Economic Growth,” Quar-terly Journal of Economics, 109(2), pp. 465-90.

[6] Baier, Scott and Sean Mulholland and Robert Tamura and Chad Turner, 2007, ”Education and Income of the States of the U.S.: 1840-2000,” Journal of Economic Growth, 12(2), pp.

77-184.

[7] Banerjee, Abhijit and L. Iyer. 2005. ”History, Institutions, and Economic Performance: The Legacy of Colonial Land Tenure Systems in India.”American Economic Review95:1190-1213.

[8] Banerjee, Abhijit and Andrew Newman, 1993, ”Occupational Choice and the Process of De-velopment,” Journal of Political Economy, 101(2), pp. 274-298.

[9] Banerjee, Abhijit and Andrew Newman, 1994, ”Poverty, Incentives, and Development,” Amer-ican Economic Review, 84(2), pp. 211-215.

[10] Benabou, Roland, 2000, ”Unequal Societies: Income Distribution and the Social Contract,”

American Economic Review, 90(1), pp. 96-129.

[11] Benabou, Roland, 2005, ”Inequality, Technology, and the Social Contract,” in Handbook of Economic Growth, P. Aghion and S. N. Durlauf, eds., Amsterdam: Elsevier.

[12] Benson, Sumner, 1965, ”A History of the General Property Tax,” inThe American Property Tax: Its History, Administration, and Economic Impact, ed. Benson, G. C. S., Benson, S., McClelland, H. and Thomson, P., Claremont, CA: Lincoln School of Public Finance.

[13] Binswanger, Hans P. and Klaus Deininger and Gershon Feder, 1995, ”Power, Distortions, Revolt and Reform in Agricultural Land Relations,” inHandbook of Development Economics, Volume III, Jere Behrman and T. N. Srinivasan, eds., Amsterdam: Elsevier.

[14] Birdsall, Nancy and J. L. Londono, (1997), ”Asset Inequality Matters: An Assessment of the World Bank’s Approach to Poverty Reduction,” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, 87(2), pp. 32-37.

[15] Bruhn, Miriam and Francisco Gallego, 2007, ”Good, Bad, and Ugly Colonial Activities: Ex-plaining Development across the Americas,” working paper.

[16] Bourguignon, Francios and Thierry Verdier, 2000, ”Oligarchy, Democracy, Inequality and Growth,” Journal of Development Economics, 62, pp. 285-313.

[17] Burgess, Robin and Nicholas Stern, 1993, ”Taxation and Development,”Journal of Economic Literature, 31, pp. 762-830.

[18] Dasgupta, Partha and Debraj Ray, 1986, ”Inequality as a Determinant of Malnutrition and Unemployment: Theory,” The Economic Journal, 96(384), pp. 1011-1034.

[19] Deininger, Klaus and Lyn Squire, (1998), ”New Ways of Looking at Old Issues: Inequality and Growth,” Journal of Development Economics, 57, 259-287.

[20] Easterly, William, 2001, ”The Middle Class Consensus and Economic Development,”Journal of Economic Growth, 6, pp. 317-35.

[21] Easterly, William, 2007, ”Inequality Does Cause Underdevelopment: Insights from a New Instrument,”Journal of Development Economics, forthcoming.

[22] Engerman, Stanley L. and Kenneth L. Sokoloff, 2002, ”Factor Endowments, Inequality, and Paths of Development Among New World Economies,” Economia, 3, pp. 41-102.

[23] Engerman, Stanley L. and Kenneth L. Sokoloff, 2005, ”The Evolution of Suffrage Institutions in the Americas,” Journal of Economic History, 65.

[24] Figini, Paolo, 1998, ”Inequality and Growth Revisited,” Trinity Economic Paper Series 99/2.

[25] Fisher, Glenn W., 1996,The Worst Tax? A History of the Property Tax in America, Lawrence, KS: University Press of Kansas.

[26] Frankema, Ewout, (2006), ”The Colonial Origins of Inequality: Exploring the Causes and Consequences of Land Distribution,” Groningen Growth and Development Centre, Research Memorandum GD-81.

[27] Galor, Oded and Omer Moav, 2004, ”From Physical the Human Capital Accumulation: In-equality in the Process of Development,”Review of Economic Studies, 71, pp. 1001-1026.

[28] Galor, Oded and Omer Moav and Dietrich Vollrath, 2008, ”Inequality in Land Ownership, the Emergence of Human Capital Promoting Institutions, and the Great Divergence,” Review of Economic Studies, forthcoming.

[29] Galor, Oded and Joseph Zeira, 1993, ”Income Distribution and Macroeconomics,”Review of Economic Studies, 60(1), pp. 35-52.

[30] Gates, Paul Wallace, 1968,History of Public Land Law Development, Washington: GPO.

[31] Goodrich, Carter, 1950, ”The Revulsion Against Internal Improvements,”Journal of Economic History, 10, pp. 145-169.

[32] Gouveia, M. and N. A. Masia, 1998, ”Does the Median Voter Explain the Size of Government?

Evidence fom the States,” Public Choice, 97, pp. 159-77.

[33] Keyssar, Alexander, 2000, The Right to Vote: The Contested History of Democracy in the United States, New York: Basic Books.

[34] Legler, John B. and Richard E. Sylla and John J. Wallis, 1988, ”U.S. City Finances and the Growth of Government, 1850-1902,”Journal of Economic History, 48(2), pp. 347-56.

[35] Leland, Simeon E., 1928,The Classified Property Tax in the United States, Boston: Houghton Mifflin.

[36] Lindert, Peter H., 1996, ”What Limits Social Spending?,”Explorations in Economics, 33, pp.

1-34.

[37] McClelland, Harold, 1965, ”Property Tax Assessment,” in The American Property Tax: Its History, Administration, and Economic Impact, ed. Benson, G. C. S., Benson, S., McClelland, H. and Thomson, P., Claremont, CA: Lincoln School of Public Finance.

[38] McGovney, Dudley O., 1949,The American Suffrage Medley: The Need for a National Uniform Suffrage, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

[39] Naritomi, Joana and Rodrigo Soares and Juliano J. Assuncao. 2007. ”Rent Seeking and the Un-veiling of ’De Facto’ Institutions: Development and Colonial Heritage within Brazil.” Working Paper.

[40] Niemi, Albert W., 1971, ”Inequality in the Distribution of Slave Wealth: The Cotton South and other Southern Agricultural Regions,”Journal of Economic History, 37(3), pp. 747-754.

[41] Olson, R. J. and C. J. Emerson and M. K. Nungesser. 2003. ”GEOECOLOGY: County-level Environmental Data for the United States, 1946-1979.” Oak Ridge National laboratory Dis-tributed Active Archive Center.

[42] Partridge, M., 1997, ”Is Inequality Harmful for Growth? Comment,” American Economic Review, 87, pp. 311-16.

[43] Perotti, Roberto, 1996, ”Growth, Income Distribution and Democracy: What the Data Say,”

Journal of Economic Growth, 1(2), pp. 149-187.

[44] Persson, Torsten and Guido Tabellini, 1994, ”Is Inequality Harmful for Growth?”American Economic Review, 84(3), pp. 600-621.

[45] Pineda, J. and F. Rodriguez, 2006, ”The Political Economy of Investment in Human Capital,”

Economics of Governance, 7, pp. 167-193.

[46] Piketty, Thomas, 1997, ”The Dynamics of the Wealth Distribution and the Interest Rate with Credit Rationing,” Review of Economic Studies, 64, pp. 173-189.

[47] Porter, Kirk H., 1918,A History of Suffrage in the United States, New York: Greenwood Press.

[48] Ramcharan, Rodney, 2007, ”Inequality and Redistribution: Evidence from U.S. Counties and States, 1890-1930,” working paper.

[49] Ratner, Sidney, 1980,Taxation and Democracy in America, New York: Wiley 4th edition.

[50] Rodriguez, Francisco C., 1999, ”Does Distributional Skewness Lead to Redistribution? Evi-dence from the United States,”Economics and Politics, 11(2), pp. 171-199.

[51] Seligman, Edwin R. A., 1969 [1931],Essays in Taxation, New York: Augustus M. Kelley.

[52] Sokoloff, Kenneth L. and Eric M. Zolt, 2005, ”Inequality and the Evolution of Institutions of Taxation: Evidence from the Economic History of the Americas,” working paper.

[53] Soltow, Lee, 1971, ”Economic Inequality in the United States in the Period from 1790 to 1860,”

Journal of Economic History, 31(4), pp. 822-839.

[54] Tanzi, Vito, 1987, ”Quantitative Characteristics of the Tax Systems in Developing Countries,”

in The Theory of Taxation for Developing Countries, David Newberry and Nicholas Stern, eds., New York: Oxford University Press.

[55] Tomich, Thomas P. and Peter Kilby and Bruce F. Johnston, 1995, Transforming Agrarian Economies, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

[56] U.S. Department of the Interior, 1866, Statistics of the United States in 1860, Washington:

GPO.

[57] U.S. Department of the Interior, 1872,The Statistics of the Wealth and Industry of the United States, Washington: GPO.

[58] U.S. Department of the Interior, Census Office, 1884,Valuation, Taxation, and Public Indebt-edness in the United States: 1880, Washington: GPO.

[59] U.S. Department of the Interior, Census Office, 1895,Report on Wealth, Debt, and Taxation, Part II, Valuation and Taxation, Washington: GPO.

[60] U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, 1907,Wealth, Debt, and Taxation: 1902, Washington: GPO.

[61] U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, 1915,Wealth, Debt, and Taxation: 1913 Vol I and II, Washington: GPO.

[62] U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census, 1924,Wealth, Debt, and Taxation: 1922, Vol I, II, and III, Washington: GPO.

[63] Vollrath, Dietrich, 2007, ”Geographic Determinants of Wealth Distribution: Evidence from the United States,” University of Houston working paper.

[64] Wallis, John J., 1999, ”State Constitutional Reform and the Structure of Government Finance in the Nineteenth Century,” inPublic Choice Interpretations of American Economic History, Heckelman, Jac and John Moorhouse and Robert Whaples, eds., Boston: Kluwer.

[65] Wallis, John J., 2000, ”American Government Finance in the Long Run: 1790 to 1990,”The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(1), pp. 61-82.

[66] Wallis, John J., 2001, ”A History of the Property Tax in America,” inProperty Taxation and municipal Government Finance: Essays in Honor of C. Lowell Harris, ed. Wallace E. Oates, Cambridge: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.

[67] Wallis, John J., 2003, ”The Property Tax as a Coordinating Device: Financing Indiana’s Mammoth System of Internal Improvements, 1835-1842,” Explorations in Economic History, 40(3), pp. 223-250.

[68] Williamson, Chilton, 1960, American Suffrage: From Property to Democracy, Princeton:

Princeton University Press.

[69] Wong, Wei-Kang, 2007, ”Economic Growth: A Channel Decomposition Exercise,”B.E. Jour-nal of Macroeconomics, 7(1), Topics.

[70] Wright, Gavin, 1970, ”Economic Democracy and the Concentration of Agricultural Wealth,”

in The Structure of the Cotton Economy of the Antebellum South, ed. William N. Parker, Washington D.C.: Agricultural History Society.

Figure 1: Property Tax Rates, by Level of Government, 1860-1930

Figure 2: Real and Assessed Property Values, 1860-1920

Figure 3: Assessment Rates as a Function of Estate Size

Table 1: County Level Summary Statistics, 1890

Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min Max

Property tax and wealth data:

Total taxes per capita ($) 5.900 4.782 0.441 73.203 All school taxes per capita ($) 1.942 1.577 0.102 16.068 Local school taxes per capita ($) 1.628 1.465 0.002 10.885 Other taxes per capita ($) 3.957 3.529 0.059 57.135

Total tax rate 0.013 0.006 0.001 0.093

School tax rate 0.004 0.003 0.000 0.040

Local school tax rate 0.003 0.003 0.000 0.037

Other tax rate 0.008 0.004 0.000 0.086

Total wealth per capita ($) 501.199 489.242 61.627 9182.882 Inequality and other control data:

Farm Gini 0.529 0.147 0.033 0.926

Log output per capita 4.455 0.648 2.220 6.986

Proportion black 0.118 0.199 0.000 0.940

Proportion urban 0.134 0.211 0.000 1.000

Proportion children 0.379 0.044 0.209 0.466

Log of total population 9.706 0.927 4.890 14.231

Geographic controls:

Avg. annual temperature (C) 12.150 3.982 3.000 23.800 Total annual rainfall (cm) 98.140 24.842 19.100 175.100 Length growing period (days) 180.426 39.808 81.000 345.000

Latitude (degrees) 38.929 4.200 25.535 48.794

Notes:All variables have 1966 observations. Property tax and wealth data is from the U.S. CensusReport on Wealth, Debt, and Taxation, U.S. Department of the Interior (1895). Total taxes per capita are the total of all ad valorem taxes collected within a county, by any level of government, divided by county population. School taxes are the subset of taxes collected explicitly to fund education. Local school taxes are a subset of school taxes collected only by municipal or school district authorities. The other taxes are simply total taxes minus school taxes. Tax rates are calculated as the total tax revenue in the county divided by total wealth. The farm Gini is calculated from farm size information in the U.S. Census of 1890. Output per capita is the sum of manufacturing output and agricultural output, as reported in the U.S. Census of 1890. Demographic variables are from the U.S. Census. Geographic variables are obtained from the GEOECOLOGY database of Olson et al (2003). See the appendix for more detail on the construction of all variables.

Table 2: OLS Regressions for County Property Taxes on Inequality, 1890

Dependent Variables:

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)

lnT /L lnT /V lnV /L lnT /L lnT /V lnV /L

(Taxes p.c.) (Tax rate) (Wealth p.c.) (Taxes p.c.) (Tax rate) (Wealth p.c.)

= (2)+(3) = (5)+(6)

Panel A: T = Total Property Tax Revenue

Farm Gini 0.274 -0.337** 0.611 0.284 -0.634*** 0.918***

(0.440) (0.159) (0.374) (0.278) (0.125) (0.256)

R-squared 0.634 0.348 0.529 0.810 0.390 0.718

Panel B: T = All School Property Tax Revenue

Farm Gini -0.138 -0.749*** 0.611 0.072 -0.846*** 0.918***

(0.442) (0.221) (0.374) (0.315) (0.224) (0.256)

R-squared 0.734 0.539 0.529 0.830 0.552 0.718

Panel C: T = Local School Property Tax Revenue

Farm Gini -0.078 -0.689*** 0.611 0.027 -0.891*** 0.918***

(0.461) (0.246) (0.374) (0.321) (0.244) (0.256)

R-squared 0.753 0.661 0.529 0.816 0.665 0.718

Panel D: T = Other Property Tax Revenue

Farm Gini 0.460 -0.151 0.611 0.401 -0.517*** 0.918***

(0.441) (0.156) (0.374) (0.278) (0.122) (0.256)

R-squared 0.550 0.266 0.529 0.747 0.323 0.718

Controls No No No Yes Yes Yes

Notes: All regressions have 1966 observations and include state fixed effects. Standard errors, clustered at the state level, are reported in parentheses. * denotes significance at 10%, ** denotes 5%, and *** denotes 1%. The panels vary on the measure of property tax revenue used, and the categories are discussed in the text. Note that results for wealth per capita (V /L) do not vary by panel as the wealth is not contingent on the type of tax collected. Tax and wealth data are from U.S. Census special reports, and the Farm Gini is calculated from U.S. Census data on farm sizes (see text). The final three columns include additional control variables: the log of output per capita, the percent urban, the percent black, the percent of children, and the log of total population. See the appendix for the sources of these variables.

Table 3: Instrumental Variable Regressions for Log Property Tax Rates on Inequality, 1890 Dependent Variable is the log of the tax rate: lnT /V

(1) (2) (3) (4)

All taxes All School Local School Other Taxes

Taxes Taxes

Panel A: No additional controls

Farm Gini -0.524 -1.013** -0.948* -0.240

(0.437) (0.507) (0.542) (0.438)

Hansen J-stat 0.408 1.822 2.315 0.157

Hansen p-value 0.939 0.610 0.510 0.984

First stage F-stat 27.146 27.146 27.146 27.146 First stage p-value <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 Panel B: All additional controls

Farm Gini -1.178** -1.540** -1.446** -0.871

(0.509) (0.628) (0.655) (0.538)

Hansen J-stat 0.526 2.222 2.687 0.671

Hansen p-value 0.913 0.528 0.442 0.880

First stage F-stat 12.863 12.863 12.863 12.863 First stage p-value <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001

Notes: Standard errors, clustered at the state level, are reported in parentheses. * denotes significance at 10%,

** denotes 5%, and *** denotes 1%. All regressions have 1966 observations and include state fixed effects. The excluded instruments in each regression are the log annual rainfall, the log of annual temperature, the log of the growing period, and latitude, all obtained from the GEOECOLOGY database of Olson et al (2003). Panel B includes log output per capita, the percent urban, the percent black, the percent children, and the log of total population as additional controls. See the appendix for the source of these control variables. The dependent variable in each column is the effective tax rate,T /V, whereT is the total amount of tax collected, andV is total wealth. T varies over the columns based on which taxes are used in the calculation. Tax and wealth data are from special U.S. Census reports, see the text for details. For both panels, the Hansen J statistic is distributedχ2(3) and the first stage F statistic is distributedF(4,35).

Table 4: Instrumental Variable Regressions for Property Tax Rates on Inequality, Expanded Sample, 1890

Dependent Variable is the level of the tax rate: T /V

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

All School All School All School Local School Other Taxes

Taxes Taxes Taxes Taxes

Panel A: No additional controls

Farm Gini -0.0057** 0.0018 -0.0079*** -0.0063*** -0.0008

(0.0025) (0.0013) (0.0025) (0.0023) (0.0052)

Hansen J-stat 2.754 0.692 2.072 2.390 1.232

Hansen p-value 0.431 0.874 0.557 0.495 0.745

First stage F-stat 21.724 40.800 27.145 21.724 21.724

First stage p-value <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 Panel B: All additional controls

Farm Gini -0.0115*** -0.0029** -0.0103*** -0.0127*** -0.0088 (0.0040) (0.0012) (0.0031) (0.0040) (0.0075)

Hansen J-stat 1.923 3.642 2.313 1.672 3.730

Hansen p-value 0.588 0.302 0.509 0.643 0.292

First stage F-stat 5.253 12.576 12.862 5.253 5.253

First stage p-value 0.002 0.001 <0.001 0.002 0.002

Sample Information

Included counties All Local school Local school All All

taxes = 0 taxes>0

N 2303 337 1966 2303 2303

Notes: Standard errors, clustered at the state level, are reported in parentheses. * denotes significance at 10%,

** denotes 5%, and *** denotes 1%. All regressions include state fixed effects. The excluded instruments in each regression are the log annual rainfall, the log of annual temperature, the log of the growing period, and latitude, all obtained from the GEOECOLOGY database of Olson et al (2003). Panel B includes log output per capita, the percent urban, the percent black, the percent children, and the log of total population as additional controls. See the appendix for the source of these control variables. The dependent variable in each column is the effective tax rate, T /V, whereT is the total amount of tax collected, andV is total wealth.T varies over the columns based on which taxes are used in the calculation. Tax and wealth data are from special U.S. Census reports, see the text for details.

For all regressions, the Hansen J statistic is distributedχ2(3). The first stage F statistic is distributedF(4,35) in columns (1),(3)-(5), andF(4,9) in column (2).

Table 5: Regressions for Assessment Rate, 1890

Dep. Variable is log of the assessed prop. val.:

(1) (2) (3) (4)

Log true prop. value (β) 0.894*** 0.891*** 0.596*** 0.599***

(0.021) (0.020) (0.049) (0.050)

Farm Gini 0.066 -0.075

(0.154) (0.198)

Additional controls? No No Yes Yes

F-test stat forβ= 1 25.18 30.34 66.78 64.91 F-test p-value <0.001 <0.001 <0.001 <0.001

Notes: Standard errors, clustered at the state level, are reported in parentheses. * denotes significance at 10%, **

denotes 5%, and *** denotes 1%. All regressions are estimated using OLS, have 1966 observations and include state fixed effects. Additional controls are log output per capita, the percent urban, the percent black, the percent children, and the log of total population as additional controls. See the appendix for the source of these control variables. The dependent variable is the log of total assessed property value, while the “true” value is the reported market value of property. Assessment and wealth data are from special U.S. Census reports, see the text for details. The F-test tests the hypothesis that the coefficient on the log of true value,β, is equal to one. The statistic is distributedF(1,35).