• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

5 Proofs and technical lemmas

Proof of Lemma 1. The arguments being quite standard, we just give a sketch of proof (see e.g. Theorem 2.4 in Francq and Zakoïan (2010) for a similar result with a more detailed proof). Because all the components of C0t and B0t are non-negative, the components ofYtdefined by (4) are always well defined in[0,+∞]. SinceE|logkB01k|<

∞, by the Cauchy rule, whenγ <0, the components ofYtare shown to be almost surely finite. The process Yt satisfies (3) and, being a measurable function of (ηt,xt), it is also stationary and ergodic under A1. The uniqueness of the stationary solution is shown as in the case π0 = 0. For the converse, note that when a (finite) stationary solution exists for (3), then

Proof of Lemma 2. The result is known whenπ0 = 0 (see Proposition A.1 in HZ). For notational simplicity, we give the proof for general π0 when p = q = 1. If γ < 0, ht is then given by (6). Using the elementary inequality(P

iui)s≤P

iusi for any sequence of positive numbers ui and any s∈(0,1], and the Cauchy-Schwarz inequality, we obtain

Ehst

By Assumption A1, there exists s > 0 such that E̟2st < ∞. Moreover, the fact that γ =Eloga(ηt)<0and that Eart)<∞ for some r >0 entails that there exists s >0 such that Ea2st) <1 (see e.g. Lemma 2.2 in (Francq and Zakoïan, 2010)). It follows

3Panet al. (2008) employed different assumptions, but a careful examination of their proof and of Lemma 3.4 inBougerol and Picard (992a) reveals that the assumption that t) is iid, as well as their regularity conditionA1, are useless for that result.

that Ehst <∞, and thus Ehs/δt <∞ for some s >0. By the Cauchy-Schwarz inequality and A1, we deduce that E|εt|s/2 <∞. ✷ The following lemma is useful to show the identifiability of the parameters under A4.

Lemma 3 Let X be a random variable which takes at least three values and P(X >0)∈ (0,1). If a(X+)δ+b(X)δ=c a.s., with a, b, c∈R, then a=b= 0. X <0which is in contradition with assumption that X has at least three values. ✷ Proof of Theorem 1. The consistency can be shown by establishing the following intermediate results:

The proofs of i), iii) and iv) being essentially the same as when the parameter π is not present, we only give the proof of ii).

Assume that σt(ϑ) = σt0) a.s. By the second part of A5, the polynomials Bϑ(B) constant e and a sequence of vectors (di)such that

X

Since ε+t δ The proof of the asymptotic distribution of the QMLE is split into several technical lemmas.

Lemma 4 Under the assumptions of Theorem 2, (i) E

(ii) J is non-singular and var

∂ℓt0) In Cases A and B (strong model), one can thus prove (i) by showing that

E

and the existence of the first expectation in (i) can be proven by showing that

E

Thanks toA2, the second expectation of (i) is still obtained by showing (30).

The existence of the moments in (29)–(31) is already known when π0 is absent, (ηt) is iid andϑ0 belongs to the interior of Θ (see the proof of (i) and (ii) of Theorem 2.2 in HZ). We now explain the changes in the proof induced by the our particular framework in the case p=q = 1. The proof can be easily extended to the general case.

Since σδt =P

Similar expressions hold for the second order derivatives. Noting also that ω := inf

ϑ∈Θσtδ >0, (32)

under the moment conditions in A11, we have (29) and (30) in Case B, and (30) and (31) in Case D. In Cases A and C, we have

Note that, for any q ≥1, under the moments assumptions in A1 and A6, we have

for sufficiently small s > 0. It follows that (29) and (31), for any ν > 0, hold true when all the components of ϑ0 are non-zero. By the same arguments, we can even show the stronger result that for any s0 >0 there exists a neighborhood V(ϑ0) of ϑ0 included in Θ such that We obtain (30) by similar arguments, which completes the proof of (i) in the two remain-ing cases A and C.

We now turn to the proof of (ii). Note that the second equality in (11) comes from (28) and the fact that E(η2t | Ft1) = 1. Using (27), we also have var(∂ℓt0)/∂ϑ) =I. It remains to show thatJ is invertible. If it is not the case, then there exists c∈Rdsuch that

By the arguments used to prove (ii) of Theorem 1, this is impossible with c 6= 0, which

completes the proof of (ii). ✷

Lemma 5 Under the assumptions of Theorem 2, as n → ∞, we have

Proof of Lemma 5. In this proof, K and ρ denote generic constants whose values can By the arguments used to show (7.60) inFrancq and Zakoïan (2010), we have

UnderA10-A11, we haveEηt4 <∞and (29), and thus the expectation of the right-hand side of the inequality is bounded by Kρt. It follows that

X

has a finite expectation, and thus is finite almost surely, which entails (38). The conver-gence (39) is shown by arguments which follow the scheme of the proof of the last part of (d) on Page 167 in Francq and Zakoïan (2010).

To establish (36), first note that

P sufficiently small, a1 → 0. The ergodic theorem and Lemma 4 imply that a3 → 0 for

any ǫ > 0. To prove that a2 → 0, it suffices to show that, for all ǫ > 0, there exists a neighborhood V(ϑ0)of ϑ0 satisfying

nlim→∞

The result follows from the ergodic theorem, the dominated convergence theorem, the uniform continuity of the second order derivatives of ℓt(ϑ), and by showing that

E sup using A12. In view of (28) and since σt is bounded away from zero, to show (40), it suffices to establish that Now, (10), the second part of A5 and the compactness of Θentail that

∂σtδ

The first moment condition in (41) thus follows from the Hölder inequality and A12.

The second moment condition is obtained by doing similar developments for the second order derivatives. We thus have shown (40) in Cases B and D.

To establish (40) in the two other cases, let us first show that, for any s0 > 0, there exists a neighborhood V(ϑ0)of ϑ0 such thatV(ϑ0)⊂Θand

By the arguments used to show (7.51) in Francq and Zakoïan (2010), for all ξ > 0 and s∈(0,1), there exists a neighborhood V(ϑ0)of ϑ0 such that

Without loss of generality, it can be assumed that2s0/δ≥1. By the Minskowski

Now, in view of (28), A2 and the Hölder inequality entail E sup

Thus, in Cases A and C, (40) comes from (33) and (42), and the analog (33) for second order derivatives.

By (27), Lemma 4 and A2, the last result, (37), is a consequence of the central limit theorem for square integrable martingale difference of Billingsley (1961). ✷ Proof of Theorem 2. A Taylor expansion ofQen(ϑ)around ϑ0 gives

Qen(ϑ)−Qen0) = ∂Qn0)

we obtain the following quadratic approximation of the objective function

where the first inequality comes from the definition of ϑZn, the equality from (45), and the second inequality from the definition of ϑbn. By (46), it follows that

The Minskowski inequality then entails that

It follows that, by the cr-inequality,

We now show that √ Using the characterization (12) of the projection on a convex cone, we have

k√ Using (48), we thus obtain

k√

n(ϑbn−ϑ0)−ZCnk2J ≤ k√

n(ϑbn−ϑ0)−Znk2J − kZCn−Znk2J =oP(1).

The continuous mapping theorem and (37) entail ZCnd ZC, and the conclusion follows.

✷ Proof of Proposition1. We only show (17) because (16) and (18) are obtained directly from arguments used in the proof of Theorem 1. Let

In(ϑ) = 4 use standard arguments to show that

nlim→∞

In(ϑbn)−bIn

= 0 a.s.

The ergodic theorem shows that

nlim→∞kIn0)−Ik= 0 a.s.

Using the strong convergence of ϑbn to ϑ0, it remains to show that, for any ǫ > 0, there exists a neighborhood V(ϑ0)of ϑ0 such that

nlim→∞ sup

ϑ∈V(ϑ0)kIn(ϑ)−In0)k ≤ǫ.

It suffices to show that there exists a neighborhood V(ϑ0) of ϑ0 such that

E sup

ϑ∈V(ϑ0)ΘkSt(ϑ)k<∞, (50) and the result will follow from the ergodic theorem applied to

supϑ∈V(ϑ0)kSt(ϑ)−St0)k t, the dominated convergence theorem, and the uniform continuity of ϑ 7→ St(ϑ) in the neighborhood of ϑ0.

In Cases A and C, (50) follows from A10, (33) and (42). In Cases B and D, (50)

follows from A12 and the Hölder inequality. ✷

References

Andrews, D.W. (1999) Estimation when a parameter is on a boundary. Econometrica 67, 1341–1383.

Andrews, D.W. (2001) Testing when a parameter is on the boundary of the maintained hypothesis. Econometrica 69, 683–734.

Billingsley, P. (1961) The Lindeberg-Levy theorem for martingales. Proceedings of the American Mathematical Society 12, 788–792.

Bollerslev, T. (2008) Glossary to ARCH (GARCH).Volatility and Time Series Econo-metrics: Essays in Honor of Robert F. Engle(eds. T. Bollerslev, J. R. Russell and M. Watson), Oxford University Press, Oxford, UK.

Bougerol, P. and N. Picard (1992a) Strict stationarity of generalized autoregressive processes. Annals of Probability20, 1714–1729.

Bougerol, P. and N. Picard (1992b) Stationarity of GARCH processes and of some nonnegative time series. Journal of Econometrics 52, 115–127.

Brandt, A. (1986) The stochastic equation Yn+1 = AnYn+Bn with stationary coeffi-cients. Advance in Applied Probability 18, 221–254.

Ding, Z., Granger, C. and R.F. Engle (1993) A long memory property of stock mar-ket returns and a new model. Journal of Empirical Finance 1, 83–106.

Engle, R.F., Hendry, D.F. and J.F. Richard (1983) Exogeneity. Econometrica51, 277–304.

Engle, R.F. and A.J. Patton (2001) What good is a volatility model. Quantitative finance 1, 237–245.

Escanciano, J.C. (2009) Quasi-maximum likelihood estimation of semi-strong GARCH models. Econometric Theory25, 561–570.

Francq, C. and J-M. Zakoïan (2004) Maximum likelihood estimation of pure GARCH and ARMA-GARCH processes. Bernoulli 10, 605–637.

Francq, C. and J-M. Zakoïan (2010) GARCH Models: Structure, Statistical Infer-ence and Financial Applications. John Wiley.

Francq, C. and J-M. Zakoïan (2007) Quasi-Maximum Likelihood Estimation in GARCH Processes when some coefficients are equal to zero. Stochastic Processes and their Applications 117, 1265–1284.

Francq, C. and J-M. Zakoian (2009) Testing the nullity of GARCH coefficients: cor-rection of the standard tests and relative efficiency comparisons. Journal of the American Statistical Association 104, 313–324.

Fuertes, A.M., Izzeldin, M. and E. Kalotychou (2009) On forecasting daily stock volatility: the role of intraday information and market conditions. International Journal of Forecasting 25, 259–281.

Glosten, L.R., Jaganathan, R. and D. Runkle (1993) On the relation between the expected values and the volatility of the nominal excess return on stocks. Journal of Finance 48, 1779–1801.

Hamadeh, T. and J-M. Zakoïan (2011) Asymptotic properties of LS and QML esti-mators for a class of nonlinear GARCH processes. Journal of Statistical Planning and Inference 141, 488–507.

Han, H. (2013) Asymptotic Properties of GARCH-X Processes. Journal of Financial Econometrics Forthcoming.

Han, H. and D. Kristensen (2014) Asymptotic Theory for the QMLE in GARCH-X Models With Stationary and Nonstationary Covariates. Journal of Business &

Economic Statistics 32, 416–429.

Han, H. and J.Y. Park (2012) ARCH/GARCH with persistent covariates: Asymp-totic theory of MLE. Journal of Econometrics 167, 95–112.

Han, H. and J.Y. Park (2014) GARCH with omitted persistent covariate. Economics Letters 124, 248–254.

Hansen, P.R. and A. Lunde (2005) A forecast comparison of volatility models: does anything beat a GARCH(1,1)? Journal of applied econometrics20, 873–889.

Laurent, S., Lecourt, C. and F.C. Palm (2014) Testing for jumps in conditionally Gaussian ARMA-GARCH models, a robust approach. Computational Statistics &

Data Analysis. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.csda.2014.05.015

Nelson, D. B. (1991) Conditional heteroskedasticity in asset returns: A new approach.

Econometrica 59, 347–370.

Nijman, T. and E. Sentana (1996) Marginalization and contemporaneous aggrega-tion in multivariate GARCH processes. Journal of Econometrics 71, 71–87.

Pan, J., Wang, H. and H. Tong (2008) Estimation and tests for power-transformed and threshold GARCH models. Journal of Econometrics 142, 352–378.

Sucarrat, G. and A. Escribano (2010) The Power Log-GARCH Model. Working doc-ument, Economic Series 10-13, University Carlos III, Madrid.

Taylor, S.J. (1986) Modelling Financial Time Series, New-York : Wiley.

Wintenberger, O. (2013) Continuous invertibility and stable QML estimation of the EGARCH(1,1) model. Scandinavian Journal of Statistics 40, 846–867.

Zakoïan, J-M. (1994) Threshold heteroskedastic models. Journal of Economic Dynam-ics and Control 18, 931–955.