• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

A Proofs and Supplementary Explanations

A.5 Numerical Results

Figure A.1 reports the numerical results for 25 sample countries, including Australia, Austria, Chile, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Italy, Japan, Lithuania, Luxemburg, the Netherlands, Norway, Poland, Portu-gal, Republic of Latvia, Slovenia, Spain, Sweden, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom.

The ratio of capital income tax revenue to GDP shows a U-shaped pattern for Australia, Chile, Estonia, Japan, Latvia, Lithuania, and Switzerland whereas it is monotonically increasing in ω for other countries.

[Figure A.1.]

References

[1] Andersen, T.M., 2019. Intergenerational conflict and public sector size and structure: A rationale for debt limits? European Journal of Political Economy 57, 70–88.

[2] Arai, R., Naito, K., and Ono, T., 2018. Intergenerational policies, public debt, and economic growth: A politico-economic analysis.Journal of Public Economics 166, 39–52.

[3] Arawatari, R., and Ono, T., 2017. Inequality and public debt: A positive analysis. Review of International Economics 25, 1155–1173.

[4] Arcalean, C., 2018. Dynamic fiscal competition: A political economy theory. Journal of Public Economics 164, 211–224.

[5] Bassetto, M., 2008. Political economy of taxation in an overlapping-generations economy.

Review of Economic Dynamics 11, 18–43.

[6] Beauchemin, K., 1998. Intergenerational politics, fiscal policy and productivity. Review of Economic Dynamics 1, 835–858,

[7] Bishnu, M., and Wang, M., 2017. The political intergenerational welfare state. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 77, 93–110.

[8] Boldrin, M., and Rustichini, A., 2000. Political equilibria with social security. Review of Economic Dynamics 3, 41–78.

[9] Cukierman, A., and Meltzer, A.H., 1989. A political theory of government debt and deficits in a neo-Ricardian framework.American Economic Review 79, 713–732.

[10] de la Croix, D., and Doepke, M., 2002. Inequality and growth: Why differential fertility matters.American Economic Review 93, 1091–1113.

[11] Forni, L., 2005. Social security as Markov equilibrium in OLG models. Review of Economic Dynamics 8, 178–194.

[12] Gonzalez-Eiras, M., and Niepelt, D., 2008. The future of social security.Journal of Monetary Economics 55, 197–218.

[13] Gonzalez-Eiras, M., and Niepelt, D., 2012. Ageing, government budgets, retirement, and growth.European Economic Review 56, 97–115.

[14] Greenwood, J., Hercowitz, Z., Huffman, G.W., 1988. “Investment, capacity utilization, and the real business cycle.American Economic Review 78, 402–417.

[15] Kydland, F.E., and Prescott, E.C., 1982. Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econo-metrica 50, 1345–1370.

[16] Lancia, F., and Russo, A., 2016. Public education and pensions in democracy: A political economy theory.Journal of the European Economic Association 14, 1038–1073.

[17] Lindbeck, A.J., and Weibull, W., 1987. Balanced-budget redistribution as the outcome of political competition.Public Choice 52, 273–297.

[18] Mateos-Planas, X., 2010. Demographics and the politics of capital taxation in a life-cycle economy.American Economic Review 100, 337–363.

[19] M¨uller, A., Storesletten, K., and Zilibotti, F., 2016. The political color of fiscal responsibil-ity.Journal of the European Economic Association 14, 252–302.

[20] Ono, T., and Uchida, Y., 2016. Pensions, education, and growth: A positive analysis.

Journal of Macroeconomics 48, 127–143.

[21] Ono, T., and Uchida, Y., 2018. Human capital, public debt, and economic growth: A political economy analysis.Journal of Macroeconomics 57, 1–14.

[22] Persson, T., and Tabellini, G., 2000. Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy.

MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.

[23] Razin, A., and Sadka, E., 2007. Aging population: The complex effect of fiscal leakages on the politico-economic equilibrium.European Journal of Political Economy 23, 564–575.

[24] Razin, A., Sadka, E., and Swagel, P., 2004. Capital income taxation under majority voting with aging population.Review of World Economics 140, 476–495.

[25] Renstr¨om, T.I., 1996. Endogenous taxation: An overlapping generations approach. Eco-nomic Journal 106, 471–482.

[26] R¨ohrs, S., 2016. Public debt in a political economy. Macroeconomic Dynamics 20, 1282–

1312.

[27] Song, Z., Storesletten, K., and Zilibotti, F., 2012. Rotten parents and disciplined children:

A politico-economic theory of public expenditure and debt.Econometrica 80, 2785–2803.

[28] Trabandt, M., and Uhlig, H., 2011. The Laffer curve revisited. Journal of Monetary Eco-nomics 58, 305–327.

[29] Uchida, Y., and Ono, T., 2020. Political economy of taxation, debt ceilings, and growth.

https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/99455/1/MPRA paper 99455.pdf

AUS

Labor income tax revenue (% of GDP, ave 95-16)

Popula!on ages 65 and above (% of total, ave 95-16)

(a)

AUSCAN AUT BEL

CZE

Capital income tax revenue (% of GDP, ave 95-16)

Popula!on ages 65 and above (% of total, ave 95-16)

(b)

Government decit (% of GDP, ave 95-16)

Popula"on ages 65 and above (% of total, ave 95-16)

(c)

Figure 1: Each panel plots the data for OECD countries during 1995–2016. The vertical axis takes the average share of population aged 65 years and over. The horizontal axis takes the average ratio of labor income tax revenue to GDP (Panel (a)), the average ratio of capital income tax revenue to GDP (Panel (b)), and average ratio of deficit to GDP (Panel (c)). In Panel (c), the budget deficit is taken as an approximate variable for the public debt.

Source: OECD.Stat (https://stats.oecd.org/) (accessed on September 25, 2019).

0 10 20 30 40 50 60

Chile Korea Switzerland Australia Latvia Ireland Estonia Lithuania United States Japan United Kingdom Luxembourg Spain Czech Republic Slovak Republic Iceland Poland Netherlands Israel Norway Portugal Germany Slovenia Italy Greece Hungary Austria Finland Sweden Denmark France

Government expenditure (% of GDP, ave 95-16)

Figure 2: Average ratios of government expenditure to GDP for OECD countries during 1995–2016. Belgium, Canada, Mexico, Turkey, and New Zealand are not included in the figure because of missing data. The same applies to Table 1.

Source: OECD.Stat (https://stats.oecd.org/) (accessed on September 25, 2019).

AUS AUT CZE DNK FIN FRA DEU GRC HUN ISL IRL n 0.511 0.147 0.0326 0.139 0.11 0.181 0.0174 0.0251 -0.07 0.375 0.491

θ 1.78 18.8 3.64 61.5 26.7 77.1 5.5 8.36 8.84 3.89 2.28

ITA JPN KOR LUX NLD NOR POL PRT SVK ESP SWE

n 0.0957 0.0178 0.2 0.661 0.147 0.298 -0.0239 0.0428 0.0178 0.25 0.179

θ 8.1 2.38 1.14 3.33 4.68 5.01 4.24 5.22 3.67 3.37 32.8

CHE GBR USA CHL EST ISR SVN LVA LTU

n 0.281 0.193 0.318 0.38 -0.117 0.855 0.0543 -0.287 -0.284

θ 1.62 2.85 2.31 0.812 2.15 5.38 6.17 2.04 2.1

Table 1: The average population growth rate for OECD countries during 1995–2016 and the associated estimation of θ.

Source: OECD.Stat (https://stats.oecd.org/) (accessed on September 25, 2019).

Figure 3: Predicted ratios of government debt, capital income tax revenue, and labor income tax revenue to GDP for Iceland, Ireland, Israel, Korea, Slovakia, and the United States.

Figure 4: Numerical illustration of the effects of ωon ¯TK, ¯T, ¯G, ¯B, and ¯TK+ (1−α) ¯T−1 for the two cases of Korea: v = 0 and v = 1.5.

Figure 5: Numerical illustration of the effects ofω onbt/kttK, andτtKRtst−1Nt−1/Yt for the cases of Korea (upper panels) and Iceland (lower panels). The results for the cases of v = 0 and 1.5 are plotted by dotted and solid curves, respectively.

Figure A.1: Predicted ratios of government debt, capital income tax revenue, and labor income tax revenue to GDP for 25 sample countries.

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE