• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

We consider a general-equilibrium monetary model with monopolistic distortions and staggered prices. The model is closely related to Dixit and Lambertini (2003b) and Benigno (2004). The economy is inhabited by a continuum of individual monopo-listic producers. On the one hand, each producer uses his own labor to produce a single differentiated good. On the other hand, each producer, henceforth referred to as “producer-consumer”, derives utility from consuming a bundle of goods and from holding real money balances. There exists a continuum of consumption goods over the unit interval which are imperfect substitutes. There are two regionsAandB, with the population on the segment [0,n) belonging to region Aand the remaining population belonging to regionB, with 0≤n≤1.3

3The two-country setting is taken from Benigno (2004). Other related models are Lombardo and Sutherland (2004), Ferrero (2005), and Galí and Monacelli (2005b). In general, our model can be traced back to the seminal work of Blanchard and Kiyotaki (1987) and Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996, Chapter 10).

2.2.1 The Problem of a Producer-Consumer

A producer-consumerj in regioni∈{A,B} derives utility from aggregate consumption Cj, real money balancesMij/Pi and laborNij according to the following function:

Uij= Labor contributes negatively to the utility of agentj, withβ−1 being the elasticity of marginal disutility of labor. Individual production is assumed to be a function of labor and stochastic productivity,

Yij=AiNij. (2.2)

Using the production function to replace labor in the utility function, one obtains

Uij=

whereξi = A−βi captures the fluctuations in region-specific total factor productivity.

Changes in this variable may be interpreted as changes in (regional) technology. The total consumption of agent j – who for reasons of exposition is assumed to live in re-gionA– is given by4

Cj≡ (CAj)νA(CBj)1−νA

(νA)νA(1−νA)1−νA, (2.4) whereνA is a preference shifter of at least the relative size of region a, given by the fixed parametern: nνA≤1. Hence,νA>ncaptures a bias in consumption towards domestic goods .

Consumption of goods from each region is given by

CAj =

wherea is a generic good produced in regionA,ba generic good produced in region B, andθ>1 the elasticity of substitution between different goods in the same region.5

4For an agentjliving in regionB, total consumption is given byCj (C

j

B)νB(CAj)1−νB

(νB)νB(1−νB)1−νB for allj[n, 1].

5The weights (1/n)(1/θ)and (1/(1n))(1/θ)are a “normalization with the implication that an increase in the number of products does not affect marginal utility after optimization". See Blanchard and Kiy-otaki (1987, p. 649)

The elasticity of substitution of the home and foreign bundles of goods equals one. The corresponding consumer price indices – with subscripts denoting the place of produc-tion and superscripts denoting variables specific to agentj or regioni – are

PA≡(PAA)ν(PBA)1−ν and PB≡(PBB)ν(PBA)1−ν, (2.6) where the respective elements are given by

PAi

·1 n

Z n

0

pi(a)1−θd a

¸1−θ1

and PBi

· 1 1−n

Z 1

n

pi(b)1−θd b

¸1−θ1

(2.7) and denote the market-price indices of goods consumed in regioni and produced in regionAandB, respectively. The small letter pricesp(a) andp(b) denote the price set by a generic producer-consumer in regionAandB, respectively. These prices are cho-sen as to maximize the indirect utility function. When setting her price, the producer-consumer is faced a certain type of price rigidity, such that only a fraction of prices can be adjusted after shocks hit the economy. Details of price setting are presented in appendix Section 5.1.2.

The price indexPi is defined as the minimum expenditure necessary for purchasing goods leading to a consumption indexCj of size one, and the price indexes PiA and PBi are defined as the minimum expenditure required to purchase goods resulting in consumption indexesCAj andCBj, which equal one.

We assume goods-market arbitrage leads to identical prices across borders such that PAA=PBA=PAandPBA=PBB=PB. This implies that thei superscripts on each left hand side of Equation (2.7) can be dropped, and the incentive to set different prices across regions because of the home bias in consumption bears no consequences.6 So the price level of goods consumed in regioni ∈{A,B} – regioni’s consumer price level – given in Equation (2.6) simplifies to

Pi =(Pi)ν(P−i)1−ν, (2.8) where−i denotes the opposite region thani. Again, a superscript refers to the place of consumption and a subscript to the place of production. So Equation (2.8) states that regioni’s CPI is a combination of the indexes of goods produced in regioniand in region−i. Denoting the output of producer-consumer j in regioni byYij, the budget

6In our model, inflation differentials occur due to the home-bias effect, as the composition of the consumption bundles differ in both regions. This assumption is somewhat critical when referring to the Euro-zone, where significant price differences for the same product in different countries exist even for tradeable goods.

constraint for this agent is Z n

0

pi(a)cj(a)d a+ Z 1

n

pi(b)cj(b)d b+Mij =pi(j)Yij(1−τi)−PiTi+M¯ijIij. (2.9) The budget constraint guarantees that the sum of consumption expenditures plus money demand equals nominal net incomeIij, which is the sum of sale revenues from the good produced and beginning-of-period money holdings minus net tax payments.

Macroeconomic policy consists of three elements. A common central bank chooses the nominal money supply and in each of the two regions, a fiscal authority uses its tax rateτi proportional to sales to subsidize production.7 The government is not allowed to be indebted; its budget is balanced by lump-sum taxes Ti. For the two regional government budget constraints we have

Z n 0

pA(j)y(j)τAd j+nPATA=0 Z 1

n

pB(j)y(j)τBd j+(1−n)PBTB=0 (2.10)

2.2.2 Terms of Trade and Equilibrium

As set out before, the law of one price holds in the economy considered, i.e. pA(a)= pB(a) and pA(b)=pB(b). Nonetheless, agents appreciate consumption of domesti-cally produced goods more. Hence, the (consumer) price index in region A, PA in-cludes a larger share of domestic goods than the (consumer) price index in regionB, PB. This has implications for the terms of trade, which we define as follows.

Definition 1. The terms of trade for region i , Si, are given by the price of imports relative to the price of exports. Using “i ” to denote “not i ”,

SiP−ii

Pi−i. (2.11)

Here,Pii is the price level of goods produced in region−i and consumed in regioni, i.e. imports, whereasPii is the price level of goods produced in regioniand consumed in region−i, i.e. exports. E. g., region A’s terms of trade are given by the price levels

7This assumption for fiscal policy is typically used in New Keynesian Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium (DSGE) models.

of goods produced in regionBand consumed in regionA, divided by the price level of goods produced in regionAand consumed in regionB.8The following lemma applies.

Lemma 1. The terms of trade are equal to the ratio of producer price indices.

Si =P−i

Pi . (2.12)

Proof. The equality holds as the rate of substitution between goods of region i is con-stant in both economies, so that the basket of domestically produced goods has the same composition in both economies, though not the same relative size. Therefore, a change in the price index of goods produced in region i has the same impact on e.g. Pii, the price index of region i produced goods consumed in region−i , and on Pii, and we can drop the superscript.

Using the definitions of the consumer price indices given in equation (2.8), we can relate the terms of trade to the consumer price indicesPA andPB and to the price indices of goods produced in each region,PAandPBas follows:

PA

PA =(SA)1−ν, PA PB = 1

(SA)ν, PB

PA =(SA)ν and PB

PB = 1

(SA)1−ν. (2.13) In the case of an identical home bias in both regions, which we are assuming here, the ratios of the two measures of inflation are inversely related to each other:9Si =1/S−i. Movements in the terms of trade imply movements in relative prices and, therefore, shift demand across the border.

Definition 2. Given policy decisions for M andτi, an equilibrium is an allocation {C, (Ci)i∈{A,B}, (Cij)j∈[0,1],Y, (Yi)i∈{A,B}, (Yij)j∈[0,1]}and a price system

{P, (Pi)i∈{A,B}, (Pi)i∈{A,B}, (pij)j∈[0,1]}, such that

1. the allocation maximizes the utility of the producer-consumer, 2. markets clear,

3. the policies are consistent with allocation and prices.

The equilibrium of the model is derived in the appendix, in Sections 5.1.1 to 5.1.3. To-gether with the decisions of monetary and fiscal policies, it can be represented in two

8It follows that the terms of trade for regionB,SB=PBA/PBAare the inverse ofSA. Note that the usual definition, see e. g. Obstfeld and Rogoff (1996, p. 242), is in line with ours from the viewpoint of region B.

9See Galí and Monacelli (2002) for a similar treatment in a small open economy setting.

equations, an equation relating output to real money holdings,10 YA=γM¯

P

γ

1−γ[ν+(1−ν)1−nn SA] and YB=γM¯ P

1

1−γ[ν+(1−ν)1−nnSB], (2.14) and a price rule for an individual producer-consumer,11

µp(a) PA

=

µ θξA

(θ−1)(1−τA)YAβ−1

1+θ(1β−1) and

µp(b) PB

=

µ θξB

(θ−1)(1−τB)YBβ−1

1+θ(1β−1) . (2.15) The variable ¯M/P denotes aggregate beginning-of-period real money holdings which are assumed to be identical across agents and regions. For detailed derivations of both equations the reader is referred to the appendix.

2.2.3 Analysis

So far, the model’s time dimension is fairly simple. At the beginning of the period, shocks did not yet occur and the economy is at its steady state. Then, the shocks oc-cur and all adjustments take place. As we are interested in exactly these deviations from steady state, we approximate our solution of the model around a steady state with identical price levels. We denote the percentage deviation of a price level from its steady state as inflation rate and use the small lettersy ands to denote the percent-age deviation of output and terms of trade from its respective steady state. A log-linear approximation to the model equilibrium is given by the following two propositions.

Proposition 1. In equilibrium, inflation of region i is related to the change in money supply and the deviations of the domestic and the foreign tax rate from their respective steady states. It is also related to private expectations about the model variables and to actual and expected stochastic technology, all subsumed in the variableψi:

πi=dimˆ+ciτˆi+ciτˆi+ψi, i∈{A,B}. (2.16) Proof. See Section 5.1.5 in the appendix.

The formulation used here shows how all three policy authorities affect a regional inflation rate. The central bank influences the policy variable ˆm, the change in the beginning-of-period real money holdings. As one would expect, an expansionary

mon-10This is Equation (5.29) in the appendix.

11This is Equation (5.18) in the appendix, using Equation (5.26) to plug in regional output.

etary policy, i.e., an increase in the real money supply ceteris paribus increases infla-tion. In our calibration, the parameterdi is of positive sign.

The parameterci refers to the influence of national fiscal policies on inflation, andci measures the spill-over effect from foreign fiscal policy on regioni’s inflation. Both pa-rameters are complex combinations of the model’s structural papa-rameters and steady state values, so we abstain from stating them here and refer the reader to Section 5.1.5 in the appendix. Bothci andci have typically negative signs: Dixit and Lambertini (2003a) indicate that the sign of the parameters may become negative when tax cuts and subsidies raise the supply of goods. The absolute value ofci is higher than that of c−i, i. e., direct effects from fiscal policies are stronger than the resulting spill-over ef-fects to the other region. The implied values for our benchmark structural parameters are presented in Table 2.1.

Proposition 2. The deviation of region i ’s output from its steady state is related to changes in the domestic as well as in the foreign tax rate, to domestic surprise inflation, to the terms of trade and to changes in the productivity differential between the domestic and the foreign region. It is given by

yi=aiτˆi+ai,iτˆi+biiπei)+κisi+φi, (2.17) where ai ≡³

2[1+θ(β−1)]1−θ2(β−1)1 ´

τ¯i captures the effect of the home country’s fiscal policy instrument and ai,−i≡ −

³ 1−θ

2[1(β−1)]+2(β−11)

´

τ¯−i the effect of foreign fiscal policy on do-mestic output.

Proof. See Section 5.1.6 in the appendix.

Assuming that fiscal policies choose the steady-state level of taxes ¯τi optimal in order to offset the monopolistic distortion, ¯τi will be negative. Therefore, an expansionary fiscal policy is given ifτi <τ¯i, i.e., if ˆτi=τiτ¯iτ¯i >0. It is important to keep this in mind to follow the fiscal policy description in Section 2.3. Additionally, fiscal policies have positive spill-over effects onto the other region. Therefore, both ai and ai,−i have a positive sign.

The effect of domestic surprise inflation on output is captured bybi(β−1)(1−ρ)2βρ , where the parameterρ∈{0, 1} determines the degree of price stickiness, from flexible prices (ρ =0) of all goods to fixed prices of all goods forρ =1. In line with the landmark papers by Kydland and Prescott (1977) and Barro and Gordon (1983), surprise inflation generates an increase in the national output level, asbi has a positive sign. The private

sector has rational expectations about inflation, i. e. the following condition holds:

πei =E(πi). (2.18)

The terms of trade effect on regional output is captured byκi(β−1)(1−ρ)βρ >0. Region i’s terms of tradesi are given by the log-linear approximation of Equation (2.12):

si=(πiπi) . (2.19)

We know from empirical studies that the terms of trade effect also depends on the re-gion’s size. This means that a smaller region typically has a higherκi, implying that inflation differentials have a greater effect on output, something that is missing here.12 A higher inflation rate in region−i than in regioni corresponds to a real depreciation of regioni and thus increases its net exports. This shift of consumption from foreign goods (region−i) to domestic goods (regioni) increases domestic income. As for the inflation equation, Table 2.1 shows the implied values for our benchmark structural parameters.

Finally, a random shockφi enters the output equation, which is an i.i.d. shock with zero mean and a varianceσ2φi. In the appendix we show that this shock is the weighted difference of the deviations of the two regional (stationary) productivity processes from their respective steady states, as given by

φi=

µ 1−θ

2[1+θ(β−1)]− 1 2(β−1)

ξˆi

µ 1−θ

2[1+θ(β−1)]+ 1 2(β−1)

ξˆi.

Henceforth,φi is denoted as the “region-specific” output shock. In the following sec-tion we will focus attensec-tion on the equasec-tions given in Proposisec-tion 1 and 2, which sum-marize the microeconomic model.