• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

A multi-input multi-output yak production function is developed in the livestock husbandry sector in order to measure the production performance of yak production and to examine the impact of renting-in grassland on yak production and technical inefficiency. The livestock grazing system on the Qinghai-Tibetan Plateau is extensive, suggesting that we should rely on an approach which does not require behavioral assumptions. We adopt the stochastic distance

function approach instead of a deterministic approach in order to simultaneously accommodate random noise and systematic differences in technical efficiency.

2.3.1 Conceptual framework

The output distance function introduced by Shephard (1970) treats the inputs as given and looks at the potential proportional expansion of outputs, as long as the outputs are technologically feasible. Denoting a vector of inputs by π‘₯ = (π‘₯1, β‹― , π‘₯𝐾) ∈ β„œπΎ+ and a vector of outputs by 𝑦 = (𝑦1, β‹― , 𝑦𝑀) ∈ β„œπ‘€+, a feasible multi-input multi-output production technology can be defined using the output possibility set P(x), which can be produced using the input vector x: 𝑃(π‘₯) = {𝑦: π‘₯ can produce 𝑦}. This is assumed to satisfy the set of axioms depicted in FΓ€re and Primont (1996). The output distance function is defined as: 𝐷𝑂(π‘₯, 𝑦) = min {πœ‡: 𝑦/πœ‡ ∈ 𝑃(π‘₯)}.

Since an output distance function Do (x,y) is defined in terms of the output set 𝑃(π‘₯), satisfying certain properties, the output distance function is required to satisfy analogous conditions. As noted by Lovell et al. (1994), 𝐷𝑂(π‘₯, 𝑦) is non-decreasing, positively linearly homogeneous, convex in y, and decreasing in x. It should be clear from the definition and figures that 𝑃(π‘₯) = {𝑦: π‘₯ can produce 𝑦} and that on the iso-quant, 𝑃(π‘₯) = {𝑦: 𝐷𝑂(π‘₯, 𝑦) = 1} . If 𝐷𝑂(π‘₯, 𝑦) < 1, then (x, y) belongs to the production set 𝑃(π‘₯), 𝐷𝑂(π‘₯, 𝑦) < 1 if y is located on the outer boundary of the output possibility set (Kumbhakar and Lovell, 2000).

In order to estimate the distance function in a parametric setting, a translog functional form is assumed. According to Coelli and Perelman (2000), the translog output distance function for the case of k inputs and m outputs is specified as:

π‘™π‘›π·π‘œπ‘–(π‘₯, 𝑦) = 𝛼0+ βˆ‘ π›Όπ‘šπ‘™π‘›π‘¦π‘šπ‘–+

21

where i denotes the ith household in the sample and T is the sample size. The restrictions required for linear homogeneity in outputs are:

βˆ‘π‘€π‘š=1π›Όπ‘š = 1, π‘š = 1,2, β‹― , 𝑀, βˆ‘π‘€π‘š=1π›Όπ‘šπ‘› = 0, π‘š, 𝑛 = 1,2, β‹― , 𝑀, βˆ‘π‘€π‘š=1π›Ώπ‘˜π‘š = 0, π‘˜ = 1,2, β‹― , 𝐾 and those required for symmetry are:

π›Όπ‘šπ‘› = π›Όπ‘šπ‘›, π‘š, 𝑛 = 1,2, β‹― , 𝑀, π›½π‘˜π‘™ = π›½π‘™π‘˜, π‘˜, 𝑙 = 1,2, β‹― , 𝐾.

According to Lovell et al. (1994), the homogeneity implies that 𝐷𝑂(π‘₯, ϑ𝑦) = πœ—π·π‘‚(π‘₯, 𝑦), for any πœ— > 0. Hence, if we arbitrarily choose one of the outputs as the dominated output 𝑦𝐷, and set πœ— = 1/𝑦𝐷, we obtain 𝐷𝑂(π‘₯, 𝑦/𝑦𝐷) = 𝐷𝑂(π‘₯, 𝑦)/𝑦𝐷 . For the translog form, this provides: should be assumed to be exogenous. Similar arguments are confirmed in page 95 of the book Stochastic Frontier Analysis (Kumbhakar and Lovell 2000).

According to Aigner, Lovell and Schmidt (1977), the stochastic frontier model is obtained by adding a term 𝑣𝑖 to capture noise. Thus the stochastic output distance function is:

βˆ’ln(𝑦𝐷𝑖) = 𝑇𝐿(π‘₯𝑖, π‘¦π‘šπ‘–β„π‘¦π·π‘–, 𝛼, 𝛽, 𝛿) + 𝑣𝑖 βˆ’ 𝑒𝑖 (2-4)

As usual, the 𝑣𝑖 term is assumed to be a two-sided random disturbance and is distributed as i.i.d. 𝑁(0, πœŽπ‘£2). 𝑒𝑖 is a random negative term derived from an independent distribution 𝑁(πœ‡π‘–, πœŽπ‘’2), truncated above zero of the normal distribution with mean πœ‡π‘– and variance πœŽπ‘’2 (Battese and Coelli, 1988; 1995; 1996; Coelli, 1995; Coelli and Battese, 1996). The mean πœ‡π‘– is defined as:

πœ‡π‘– = 𝑍𝑖 βˆ— 𝜏 (2-5)

where 𝑍𝑖 is a vector of explanatory variables associated with the technical inefficiency effects which could include socioeconomic and farm management characteristics. 𝜏 is a vector of unknown parameter to be estimated. MLE could be used to estimate the parameters of the stochastic output distance function given appropriate distributional assumptions for 𝑣𝑖 and 𝑒𝑖 (Aigner, Lovell and Schmidt, 1977).

The production frontier is specified as follows:

y𝑖 = 𝑓(π‘₯𝑖, 𝛽). exp (𝑣𝑖 βˆ’ 𝑒𝑖) (2-6)

where, for all households indexed with a subscript i, the measure of technical efficiency of the ith farm denoted by TEi is defined as the ratio of the observed output to the corresponding potential output, written as:

𝑇𝐸𝑖 =𝑓(𝑋𝑖, 𝛽). exp (π‘£π‘–βˆ’ 𝑒𝑖)

𝑓(𝑋𝑖, 𝛽). exp (𝑣𝑖) = exp(βˆ’π‘’π‘–) = π·π‘œπ‘–(π‘₯, 𝑦) (2-7)

The predicted value of the output distance π·π‘œπ‘–(π‘₯, 𝑦) is not directly observable because 𝑒𝑖 only appears as part of the composed error term πœ€π‘– = 𝑣𝑖 + 𝑒𝑖. It may be obtained using the conditional expectation

23

π·π‘œπ‘– = 𝐸(exp(βˆ’π‘’π‘–) |πœ€π‘–) =1 βˆ’Ξ¦(πœŽπ΄βˆ’ π›Ύπœ€π‘–β„ )𝜎𝐴

1 βˆ’Ξ¦(π›Ύπœ€π‘–β„ )𝜎𝐴 exp(π›Ύπœ€π‘– + 𝜎𝐴2⁄ ) 2 (2-8)

where 𝜎𝐴 = βˆšπ›Ύ(1 βˆ’ 𝛾)𝜎2, 𝜎2 = πœŽπ‘£2+ πœŽπ‘’2, 𝛾 = πœŽπ‘’2/𝜎2, and Ξ¦(βˆ™) represents the distribution function of a standard normal random variable. Once the parameters of model (2-1) are estimated, it is both interesting and easy to calculate the meaningful elasticity.

2.3.2 Empirical specification

In agricultural economics literature, output is frequently treated as a stochastic variable because of weather conditions, diseases, and other exogenous random forces. We assume that the decision variables are fixed in the short term and that the production level follows common and reasonable assumptions when estimating production relationships in agriculture.

We therefore build the production frontier and auxiliary technical inefficiency model with a one-step approach.

y𝑖 = 𝑓(π‘₯𝑖, 𝛽). exp (𝑣𝑖 βˆ’ 𝑒𝑖) (2-9)

where yi denotes the vector of outputs. The first output describes the output of yak production, denoted by the amount of yak meat produced in the year. The second output denotes the revenue of the other outputs, including the revenue of Tibetan sheep, milk, yak hide, Tibetan sheep wool, and so on. T describes the sample size, which is equal to 197 households in this study.

π‘₯𝑖 is a vector of inputs of grassland area, labor, household capital, and initial yak.

𝛽 are technological parameters to be estimated for π‘₯𝑖.

𝑣𝑖 is a random error term, independently and identically distributed as 𝑁(0, πœŽπ‘£2). It is intended to capture events beyond the control of the herdsman.

𝑒𝑖 is a non-negative random error term, independently and identically distributed as 𝑁(πœ‡, πœŽπ‘’2), truncated above zero and intended to capture technical inefficiency in production. This is measured as the ratio of observed outputs to maximum feasible output.

According to the conceptual framework described above, the translog functional form for the parametric distance function of yak production for the two outputs and four inputs is written as follows:

βˆ’ln(𝑦1𝑖) = 𝛼0+ 𝛼1ln(𝑦2𝑖⁄ ) +𝑦1𝑖 1

2𝛼11ln(𝑦2𝑖⁄ ) ln(𝑦𝑦1𝑖 2𝑖⁄ ) + βˆ‘ 𝛽𝑦1𝑖 π‘˜π‘™π‘›π‘₯π‘˜π‘–

4

π‘˜=1

+1

2βˆ‘ βˆ‘ π›½π‘˜π‘™

4

𝑙=1

𝑙𝑛π‘₯π‘˜π‘–π‘™π‘›π‘₯𝑙𝑖+ βˆ‘ π›Ώπ‘˜1𝑙𝑛π‘₯π‘˜π‘–ln (𝑦2𝑖⁄ )𝑦1𝑖

4

π‘˜=1 4

π‘˜=1

+ 𝑣𝑖 βˆ’ 𝑒𝑖

(2-10)

the empirical technical inefficiency model, as described in equation (2-7), is written in equation (2-11),

πœ‡π‘– = 𝑧𝑖 βˆ— 𝜏 = 𝜏0+ βˆ‘ πœβ„Žπ‘§β„Žπ‘–

9

β„Ž=1

(2-11)

where 𝑧𝑖 is a vector of explanatory variables associated with the technical inefficiency effects, including household size, variables relating to livestock intensity and variables relating to grassland property rights of renting-in grassland. These variables are described in more detail in the following section. We used the maximum likelihood estimation method to estimate the

β€œone-step” model, which specifies both the stochastic frontier and technical inefficiency model.