• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

5 Sensitivity Analysis

5.2 How General a Result is Equilibrium Mismatch?

Our main results illustrate the importance of whether or not mismatch is a feature of the post-liberalization equilibrium for how the labor market adjusts to o¤shoring. Implicit is the fact that in our baseline parameterization both EPS (no mismatch) and CSM (mismatch) equilibrium are feasible. How general a result is the coexistence of both types of equilibria under trade?

Fig. 3 o¤ers some perspective on this. Holding constant all other parameters, the …gure varies the share of o¤shored production in the high-tech good, , along the x-axis and the parameter governing the substitutability of Northern and Southern high-skilled inputs, , along the y-axis. Every point on the grid evaluates the conditions presented in Section 5.2 that tell us whether CSM equilibrium can obtain alongside EPS equilibrium.

part of the parameter space in which both EPS and CSM equilibria coexist. The unshaded (smaller) region to the right denotes that part of the parameter space where mismatch cannot be supported in a trade equilibrium. Finally, the black line denotes that baseline share parameterization of = 0:9: The baseline substitutability parameter has such that Northern and Southern high-skilled inputs are strong complements in the multinational’s production function, putting the baseline model in a part of the parameter space where both equilibria coexist and mismatch is feasible.

What is interesting about Fig. 3 is that an empirically relevant parameterization is one in which the share of o¤shored production is relatively small, so that 0:9 < 1 (see, for instance, Burstein, Kurtz, and Tesar (2008) and Arseneau and Leduc (2012)). Within that range, mismatch only exists as an equilibrium outcome when domestic and foreign high-skilled inputs are su¢ciently complementary. While our parameterization of

satis-…es this criteria, there is considerable uncertainty regarding whether o¤shored production should be viewed as a complement to or a substitute for domestic inputs. Fig. 1 suggests that if one believes the inputs are substitutes (or mild complements with a su¢ciently low share of o¤shore activity), the labor market implications of o¤shoring could be much larger because mismatch will not arise to help cushion the labor market e¤ects following a trade liberalization.

6 Conclusion

We study the role of mismatch in the adjustment of the labor market to a trade liberalization that results in o¤shoring of high-tech production. Our results suggest that mismatch helps to mitigate the negative labor market consequences that arise from o¤shoring. The ability to reallocate domestic high-skilled labor across both high- and low-tech industries dampens the increase in the unemployment rate as well as the decline in wages that result from shifting domestic production abroad. Our analysis also reveals that under our calibration the size of the parameter space over which mismatch can arise as an equilibrium outcome is, in fact, quite limited. Indeed, as long as the share of the o¤shored production is not too large, high-skilled workers will only choose to accept jobs with low-tech …rms if domestic and o¤shore

high-tech production are su¢ciently complementary.

In general, we view the limited subset of the parameters space in which mismatch can arise as an equilibrium outcome as a limitation of the model presented in this paper. in order to bring a calibrated version of the model more in line with observed data, the model needs to be extended in a way that makes mismatch a more attractive proposition to both workers and …rms following trade reform. We pursue two such extensions in companion work. Arse-neau and Epstein (2014b) introduces on-the-job search to the partial equilibrium framework presented here, while Arseneau and Epstein (2014c) extends this modeling framework to a general equilibrium open economy setting with endogenous directed search.

References

[1] Acemoglu, Daron, Gino Gancia, and Fabrizio Zilibotti (2012). “O¤shoring and Directed Technical Change.” No. w18595. National Bureau of Economic Research.

[2] Albrecht, James, and Susan Vroman (2002). “A Matching Model with Endogenous Skill Requirements.” International Economic Review, 43(1), 283-305.

[3] Amiti, Mary and Shang-Jin Wei (2005). “Fear of Services O¤shoring: Is it Justi…ed?”

Economic Policy, 20(42), 208-347.

[4] Arseneau, David M. and Brendan Epstein (2014a). “The Welfare Costs of Skill-Mismatch Employment.”Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2014-42, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

[5] Arseneau, David M. and Brendan Epstein (2014b). “On-the-Job Search and Mismatch in a Model of O¤shoring.” Mimeo, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System [6] Arseneau, David M. and Brendan Epstein (2014c). “O¤shoring and Job Dislocation.”

Mimeo, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

[7] Arseneau, David M. and Sylvain Leduc (2012). “Threatening to O¤shore in a Search Model of the Labor Market.” Mimeo, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

[8] Blinder, Alan (2009). “How Many U.S. Jobs Might be O¤shorable?”World Economics, 10(2), 41-78.

[9] Bosch, Mariano, and William F. Maloney (2007). “Gross Worker Flows in the Presence

[10] Burdett, Kenneth, and Dale T. Mortensen (1998). “Wage Di¤erentials, Employer Size, and Unemployment.” International Economic Review, 39, 257-273.

[11] Burstein, Ariel, Christopher Kurz, and Linda Tesar (2008). “Trade, Production Shar-ing, and the International Transmission of Business Cycles.” Journal of Monetary Economics, 55(4), 775-795.

[12] Christensen, Bent Jesper, Rasmus Lentz, Dale T. Mortensen, George R. Neumann, and Axel Werwatz (2005). “On-the-Job Search and the Wage Distribution.” Journal of Labor Economics, 23(1), 31-58.

[13] Costinot, Arnaud and Jonathan Vogel (2010). “Matching and Inequality in the World Economy.” Journal of Political Economy, 118(4), 747-786.

[14] Crino, Rosario (2009). “O¤shoring, Multinationals, and Labour Market: A Review of the Empirical Literature.” Journal of Economic Surveys, 23(2), 197-249.

[15] Davidson, Carl and Steven J. Matusz (2009).International Trade with Equilibrium Un-employment. Princeton University Press, Princeton, N.J.

[16] Davidson, Carl, Steven J. Matusz, and Andrei Shevchenko (2008). “Outsourcing Peter to Pay Paul: High-skill Expectations and Low-Skill Wages with Imperfect Labor Markets.” Macroeconomic Dynamics, 12, 463-479.

[17] Diamond, Peter A (1982). “Wage Determination and E¢ciency in Search Equilibrium.”

The Review of Economic Studies, 49(2), 217-227.

[18] Dolado, Juan J., Marcel Jansen, and Juan F. Jimeno (2009). “On-the-job Search in a Matching Model with Heterogeneous Jobs and Workers.” The Economic Journal 119, 200-228.

[19] Ebenstein, Avraham Y., Ann E. Harrison, Margaret S. McMillian, and Shannon Phillips (2011). “Estimating the Impact of Trade and O¤shoring on American Workers Us-ing the Current Population Surveys.” No. w15107. National Bureau of Economic Research.

[20] Elsby, Michael W. L., Ryan Michaels, and Gary Solon (2009). “The Ins and Outs of Cyclical Unemployment.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1(1), 84-110.

[21] Epstein, Brendan (2012). “Heterogeneous Workers, Optimal Job Seeking, and Aggregate Labor Market Dynamics.” International Finance Discussion Papers 1053, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

[22] Feenstra, Robert C. and Gordon H. Hanson (1996). “Globalization, Outsourcing and Wage Inequality.” American Economic Review, 86(2), 240–245.

[23] Feenstra, Robert C. and Gordon H. Hanson (1997). “Foreign Direct Investment and Relative Wages: Evidence from Mexico’s Maquiladoras.” Journal of International Economics, 42(3–4), 371–393.

[24] Feenstra, Robert C. and Gordon H. Hanson (1999). “The Impact of Outsourcing and High-Technology Capital on Wages: Estimates for the United States, 1979–1990.”

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 907–940.

[25] Feenstra, Robert C. and Gordon H. Hanson (2003). “Global Production Sharing and Rising Inequality: A Survey of Trade and Wages.” In K. Choi and J. Harrigan (eds), Handbook of International Trade (pp. 146–185). Oxford: Blackwell.

[26] Gautier, Pieter A (2002). “Unemployment and Search Externalities in a Model with Heterogeneous Jobs and Workers.” Economica, 69(2), 21-40.

[27] Goos, Maarten, Alan Manning, and Anna Salomons (2014). “Explaining Job Polariza-tion: Routine-Biased Technological Change and O¤shoring,” American Economic Review, 104(8), 2509-2526.

[28] Gorg, Holger and Aoife Hansely (2005). “Labour Demand E¤ects of International Out-sourcing: Evidence from Plant-level Data.” International Review of Economics and Finance, 14(3), 365-376.

[29] Grossman, Gene M. and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg (2008). “Trading Tasks: A Simple Theory of O¤shoring.” American Economic Review, 98(5), 1978-1997.

[30] Helpman, Elhanan (2006). “Trade, FDI, and the Organization of Firms.” Journal of Economic Literature, 44(4), 580–630.

[31] Hosios, Arthur J. (1990). “On the E¢ciency of Matching and Related Models of Search and Unemployment.” Review of Economic Studies, 57(2), 279-298.

[32] Hummels, David, Jakob R. Munch, and Chong Xiang (2011). “O¤shoring, Transition, and Training: Evidence from Danish Matched Worker-Firm Data.” American Eco-nomic Review: Papers and Proceedings, 102(3), 424-428.

[33] Jacobson, Louis S., Robert J. Lalonde, and Daniel J. Sullivan (1993). “Earning Losses of Displaced Workers.” American Economic Review, 83(4), 685-709.

[34] Kletzer, Lori (2001). “What Are the Costs of Job Loss from Import-Competing

Indus-[35] Liu, Runjua and Daniel Tre-er (2008). “Much Ado About Nothing: American Jobs and the Rise of Service O¤shoring to China and India.” No. w14061. National Bureau of Economic Research.

[36] Mitra, Divashish and Priya Ranjan (2010). “O¤shoring and Unemployment: The Role of Search Frictions and Labor Mobility.”Journal of International Economics, 81(2), 219-229.

[37] Mortensen, Dale T. (1982). “Property Rights in Mating, Racing, and Related Games.”

American Economic Review 72(5), 968-79.

[38] Mortensen, Dale T. and Christopher A. Pissarides (1994). “Job Creation and Job De-struction in the Theory of Unemployment.”The Review of Economic Studies, 61(3), 397-415.

[39] Mortensen, Dale T. and Christopher A. Pissarides (1999). “Unemployment Responses to

‘Skill-Biased’ Technology Shocks: The Role of Labour Market Policy.”The Economic Journal, 109(455), 242-265.

[40] Mortensen, Dale T. (2005). “Wage Dispersion: Why are Similar Workers Paid Di¤er-ently?” Cambridge MA: MIT Press.

[41] Oldenski, Lindsay (2014). “O¤shoring and the Polarization of the U.S. Labor Market.”

Industrial and Labor Relations Review, 67, Supplement.

[42] Petrongolo, Barbara, and Christopher A. Pissarides (2001). “Looking into the Black Box: A Survey of the Matching Function.” Journal of Economic Literature, 39(2), 390-431.

[43] Ranjan, Priya (2013). “O¤shoring, Unemployment, and Wages: The Role of Labor Market Institutions.” Journal of International Economics, 89(1), 172-186.

[44] Shimer, Robert (2005). “The Cyclical Behavior of Equilibrium Unemployment and Va-cancies.” American Economic Review, 95(1), 25-49.

[45] Shimer, Robert (2012). “Reassessing the Ins and Outs of Unemployment.” Review of Economic Dynamics, 15(2), 127-148.

[46] Sicherman, Nachum (1991). “Overeducation in the Labor Market.” Journal of Labor Economics, 9, 101-112.

Table 1Baseline Calibration at Monthly Frequency

North South

Production Parameters

2.45 Multinational technology parameter: ZH -0.99 Multinational share of domestic input: --41.75 Multinational substitutability parameter: -1.60 Low-tech …nal goods technology: ZL,ZL 0.60 1.00 High-tech intermediate production technology: zL, zL 1.00 1.00 Low-tech intermediate production technology: zL,zL 1.00 1.05 Mismatch intermediate production technology: zM

-Labor-Market, Population Parameters, and Other

0.004 Interest rater, r 0.004

0.50 Share of low skill individuals: , 0.80

0.50 Worker bargaining power: , 0.50

0.36 Flow unemployment bene…ts: b, b 0.03

0.73 Vacancy and job maintenance ‡ow cost: c, c 0.47

0.03 Job destruction rate: , 0.01

0.50 Elasticity of matches with respect to vacancies: , 0.50

0.87 Matching e¢ciency: A, A 0.44

Table 2Baseline Comparisons of Autarky and Trade

World Economic Environment A. Autarky B. Trade C. Trade

Benchmark Benchmark Alternative

Country North South North South North South

Equilibrium Con…guration EPS CSM CSM EPS EPS EPS

1 Price of intermediate high-tech (pH, pO) 2.445 - 1.800 0.652 1.119 1.362 2 Price of intermediate low-tech (pL, pL) 1.600 0.600 1.600 0.600 1.600 0.600

3 Aggregate vacancies (v, v ) 0.077 0.012 0.039 0.020 0.036 0.036

4 Aggregate unemployment rate (u,u ) 0.079 0.058 0.058 0.100 0.364 0.095

5 High-tech vacancies (vH, vO) 0.049 0.000 0.014 0.007 0.003 0.022

6 Low-tech vacancies (vL,vL) 0.028 0.012 0.025 0.013 0.033 0.014

7 High-skill unemp. rate (uH=(1 ),uH=(1 )) 0.059 0.058 0.046 0.150 0.606 0.070 8 High-skill mismatch rate (eM=(1 uH), eM=(1 uH)) 0.000 1.000 0.634 0.000 0.000 0.000 9 Low-skill unemp. rate (uL= , uL= ) 0.099 0.058 0.070 0.087 0.121 0.101 10 Wage: high-skill in high-tech (wH,wH) 1.636 - 1.007 0.161 0.381 0.825

11 Wage: mismatch (wM,wM) - 0.144 0.950 - -

-12 Average wage of high-skill (wH, wH) 1.636 0.144 0.971 0.161 0.381 0.825 13 Wage: low-skill in low-tech (wL, wL) 0.824 0.127 0.837 0.123 0.814 0.122

14 Aggregate wage (W, W ) 1.238 0.130 0.905 0.130 0.680 0.266

33

Fig. 1 Sensitivity of labor market outcomes to share of o¤shoring in multinational produc-tion funcproduc-tion

Fig. 2Sensitivity of labor market outcomes to input substitutability parameter in multina-tional production function

Fig. 3 Existence of CSM and EPS equilibria (substitutability and share of o¤shoring)