• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

The Ghosts of Climates Past and the Specters of Climates Future

2. The Ghosts of Climates Past

From the age of Aristotle until early in this century, most philosophers and scientists reflecting on the progress of nations assumed that climate was among the chief determinants of the differences among nations. This approach was summarized by the controversial Yale geographer, Ellsworth Huntington (1915, p. 4-11), who argued:

The climate of many countries seems to be one of the great reasons why idleness, dishonesty, immorality, stupidity, and weakness of will prevail.

'Formally known as the United Nations Conference on Environment and Development (UNCED), the E a r t h Summit was the culmination of an effort t o reach international agree- ments on climate, forest, biodiversity and biotechnology, as well as t o develop principles for environmentally sound economic development.

Sometime around the middle of this century, climate virtually disap- peared from the economic-development literature - or, more accurately, it was eclipsed by other factors, such as investment, trade policies, educa- tion, and other "modern" factors. In the last few years, however, climate has reemerged as a new concern - as the centerpiece of international envi- ronmental issues in the form of the threat of global warming. Whereas in an earlier era, geographers analyzed the influence of "temperature, humid- ity, wind movements, storminess, variability, and sunlight" on health and economic activity (Huntington, 1915, p. 6.), today geographers and envi- ronmentalists worry about the impacts of droughts, sea-level rise, species depletion, ecosystem health and diversity, and forest migration.

Many writers of earlier periods pointed t o the obvious fact that cli- mate had economic impacts on human civilizations, but the most influential scholar of the modern era was Ellsworth Huntington. His studies ranged widely, but the central hypothesis, the climatic hypothesis of civilization, held that climate ranks "as one of the three great factors in determining the conditions of civilization" (Huntington, 1915, p. 385). His studies were based on international comparisons, on analyses of the rise and fall of civilizations, and on a detailed examination of d a t a relating individual achievement t o weat her conditions.

Huntington's approach is shown in Figure 1, which is reproduced from the original (Huntington, 1915, p. 125). This shows the results of numerous tests and measurements of the effect of outside temperature on physical and mental performance from 1905 t o 1913. T h e top eight curves (A through H) show variations in wages for operatives, where wages reflect physical produc- tivity as the operatives were paid on a piece-rate basis. The bottom curve shows performance on tests in mathematics and English by 1560 students a t the US military academies. From these data, Huntington concludes that maximum productivity for physical effort occurs a t a temperature between 5g°F and 65OF, while "people do their best mental work when the (out- side) temperature ranges from freezing t o about 50

. . . "

(Huntington, 1915, p. 128).

Many other findings spring from Huntington's imaginative interpretation of his and others' data. One entertaining finding concerned the role of sun- light. At that time, an army surgeon, C.W. Woodruff, wrote a tract, The Ef- fect of Tropical Light on White Men, in which Woodruff speculated that the backwardness of tropical countries is due t o excessive sunlight. Woodruff's theory held that sunlight at the blue end of the spectrum would fall upon the human body and overstimulate cell growth - like a fruit exposed t o too much ripening. Huntington examined d a t a on factory operatives and found

lobs

W

M e a n temperature

150 20" ZP JOO SP @ 4S0 50° 5S0 60a bSO 7 Z 750 &

A. BOO Mcn In T w o Connecticut Fnctorlen. 101&15.

U. 1W Girls in One Connecticut Factory. 1911-13.

C One Mnn (P) in Dcntnnrk. JuncDcccn~ber. 19M.

D. One Man (L) in Utnmnrk. Jullr-Dcrrmber. 1 W .

E sAo Cinr-makers in Factory B n t 'rampa. FIR.. 1913.

P. UY) Cicar-mnkcrs in Fnctory A nt Tampa. Fla.. 1913.

G. S Childrrn Typcwritinu ill New York. IW5-6.

H. OW Cianr-makers in Factory B a t Tampn. Fla.. l r l ? .

1. 1580 Students ill M a t l ~ e ~ n a t i c s and El~b-lish a t \Vest I'oint n ~ ~ d Annapolis, 1DOelDLa NOTE. All t h e crlrves except C; a n d I are drnwn an the same wale. The m u i m n m In

every case ia reckallcd u IW.

Figure 1. Weather and economic activity: Performance and weather.

Source: Huntington, 1915, p. 124.

no or a t best only slight effects of light. Huntington was able t o uncover other patterns, however (Huntington, 1915, p. 143).

Taking the year as a whole, uniformity of temperature causes low energy;

a slight rise is beneficial, but a further rise is of no particular value; the beginning of a fall of temperature is harmful, but when the fall becomes a little larger it is much more stimulating than a rise; when it becomes extreme, however, its beneficial qualities begin t o decline.

Having reviewed these results, Huntington turns t o his climatic hypoth- esis of civilization. Three important conclusions emerge here and in his distress, disease, and a high death rate; migration ensues among the more energetic and adventurous people. Perhaps the commonest cause of eco- nomic distress is variations in weather or climate which lead t o bad crops or t o dearth of grass and water for animals. Such economic distress almost inevitably leads t o political disturbances and this again is a potent cause of migrations. T h e people who migrate perforce expose themselves t o hard- ships and their numbers diminish until only a selected group of unusually high quality remains. Such people, either as warlike invaders or in small bands, enter a new country. They may find it well populated and merely impose themselves as a new ruling class, as seems t o have happened several times in India, or they may find it depleted of people as in Attica. When the period of climatic stress is ended and the climate improves, the domi- nant newcomers not only possess an unusually strong inheritance, but are stimulated by unusually good economic conditions and by improved condi- tions of health and energy. Moreover since the population is apt t o remain below the saturation point so long as the climate improves, the standards of living tend t o rise and t o become relatively high. Thus many people are freed from the mere necessity of making a living and have the opportunity t o devote themselves t o the development of new ideas in literature, art, science, politics, and other lines of progress.

We see here the long shadow of Rev. Malthus interacting with crude Darwinism and Huntington's dynamic, climate theory.

Secondly, Huntington sometimes appears t o fall into a kind of climatic fatalism. He worries that in the South of the US "we find less energy, less vitality, less education, and fewer men who rise t o eminence than in the

North, not because southerners are in any way innately inferior t o northern- dinary run of climatic (or other) mechanistic theories and provide a linkage t o modern economic views of climate change. How comes it t o be t h a t Hong Kong or Japan - far down Huntington's scale of climatic potential

- could break free of their climatic chains and prosper close t o or perhaps even beyond the ideal climate of Manchester or Boston? Huntington notes a remarkable article by GilFillan, "The Coldward Course of Progress" which shows how technological change "has enabled mankind t o advance farther and farther into regions of low winter temperature."

Huntington then goes on t o speculate t h a t further progress may change of people may move back and forth among different climates - perhaps every week: "Their work may be arranged so that almost every family can spend week-ends in the highlands and the rest of the time in the lowlands."

While this first proposal seems far from the mark, a second speculation has an uncanny foresight for a book written well before the freon revolution:

In the warmer parts of the earth there is another side to the question. in temperate regions for equipping them with heaters.

He concludes loftily that "if we can conquer climate, the whole world will become stronger and nobler."

Huntington's Climate and Civilization, along with a small library of other scholars a century ago, is a healthy reminder of how our fundamental models of human activity are prisoners of conscious or unconscious models of social systems. In Huntington's case, Malthusianism and Darwinism were mental constraints within which his theory of climate and civilization had to fit. It is surprising that he did not ask whether the climatic effects shown in Figure 1 were de minimis in the light of the economic pace of human invention that he described. The difference in performance of his opera- tives between the 60 "optimal" temperature of New York and an 80 average temperature in a tropical region hardly exceeds 2%. Yet real wages and productivity during this period were routinely growing a t that rate every year. The real but unseen puzzle for a climatic determinist like Huntington was why productivity in the tropics was so much lower than was predicted by his wage-temperature curves. Had he asked that question, he might have become a development economist!