• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Estimation under limited availability of the survey nowcasts

Conditional on Λ, ∆Λ, and Σ,equation (3.28) is a multivariate linear regression of yd on Zd,such that the posterior distribution is obtained from standard SUR results as

p(Ψ|YT,Σ,Λ,∆Λ)∼N( ¯Ψ,V¯Ψ), (3.29) where V¯Ψ = V−1Ψ +Zd0(IT ⊗Σ−1)Zd−1

and Ψ = ¯¯ VΨ V−1Ψ Ψ +Zd0(IT ⊗Σ−1)yd .

To obtain draws from the posterior distribution, Villani (2009) suggests using a three-block Gibbs sampler that iterates between (3.24), (3.25) and (3.29).

Appendix 3.D Estimation under limited availability of the survey nowcasts

Below, we outline the Bayesian estimation of the augmented VAR when survey nowcasts are available only for a subset of the variables in yt and when the time series foryt starts earlier than the nowcasts. We distinguish the cases of section 3.2.2 and 3.2.3 respectively.

3.D.1 Model without Wright’s democratic steady-state prior (sec-tion 3.2.2)

In what follows, we derive a SUR representation of the model that acknowledges the two particularities of the data: First, we show how equation (3.8) changes when survey nowcasts are observed for a subset of the variables in yt. For that purpose, we make the following definitions

st := partly observedM ×1 vector of survey nowcasts in equation (3.8) st := observed N ×1 vector of survey nowcasts with N < M

R := N ×M selection matrix obtained from IM by deleting the rows that refer to the elements ofyt, for which we do not observe nowcasts, such thatst =Rst

Pre-multiplying the part of equation (3.8) that refers to st byR, we obtain

" we can only identify these reduced form parameters.

Next, we show how the SUR representation of equation (3.19) changes when the time series of survey nowcasts st starts later. For that purpose, we denote the periods when only yt is observed by t = 1, . . . , t1. Accordingly, the periods when both yt and st are observed are t = t1+ 1, . . . , T. As an intermediate step to the SUR representation, we consider the matrix representation of equation (3.18). Specifically, the part referring to the survey nowcasts becomes

(other elements are defined as before). By vectorizing, we obtain the SUR representation:

with we adjust the prior distribution specified in section 2.3 by dropping the elements that refer to the unobserved parts of st.

The model specified through (3.32-3.33) has the structure of a multivariate linear seem-ingly unrelated regression (SUR) model, such that we can use (once again) standard results for its Bayesian estimation (see Geweke, 2005, p.162ff). Specifically, the full conditional posterior of β is

One complication arises with the full conditional posterior of the variance-covariance matrix (see Swamy and Mehta, 1975): It is not completely clear, how to use the time series of different length in computing the sample estimate of Σ. If we use for each of its elements the maximum number of observations available, Σ is not guaranteed to be invertible (see Schmidt, 1977). We avoid the problem by estimating the parameter of the full conditional posterior of Σ on the overlapping sample (t = t1 + 1, . . . , T), thus throwing away the observations of the earlier sub-sample in its computation. Specifically, as an approximation to the full conditional posterior of Σ we use

p(Σ|YT, β)∼IW(T −t1, UT−t1) (3.35)

3.D.2 Model with Wright’s democratic steady-state prior (sec-tion 3.2.3)

In appendix 3.C, we have derived the full conditional posterior distributions of {Λ,∆Λ}, {ψ,∆ψ} and Σ respectively. Here, we adjust the SUR representations leading to the full conditional posteriors of {Λ,∆Λ} (eq. 3.23) and {ψ,∆ψ} (eq. 3.29) to the case, when survey nowcasts are observed for a subset of the variables of the VAR, and their observations start later. Given the SUR representations and an appropriately adjusted prior distribution (see Appendix 3.D.1), the posterior is obtained from standard results

(see Geweke, 2005, p.162ff). The same complications as in Appendix 3.D.1 arise with respect to the posterior of Σ.

I. Full conditional posterior of {Λ,∆Λ}:

I.a. Pre-multiplying the part of (3.13) that refers tost byR, we obtain

"

where ψ+ is the reduced form ofRψ+ (other elements are defined as before).

I.b. As an intermediate step to the SUR representation, we consider the matrix represen-tation of equation (3.22). Specifically, the part referring to the survey nowcasts becomes

Sψ+

.By vectorizing, we see that the SUR representation (eq. 3.23) becomes

The full conditional posterior is obtained as in (3.34).

II. Full conditional posterior of

ψ,∆ψ :

II.a. Pre-multiplying (eq. 3.27) by R, we obtain st −X

II.b. Accordingly, the SUR representation in the spirit of (3.28) - that allows for a standard Bayesian treatment as in (3.34) - becomes

For the posterior of Σ, essentially, we use the same approximation as in (3.35).

Adrian, T. and H. Wu(2009): “The Term Structure of Inflation Expectations,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York, Staff Reports.

Andrade, P. and H. Le-Bihan (2013): “Inattentive Professional Forecasters,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 60, 967–982.

Ang, A., G. Bekaert, and M. Wei (2007): “The Term Structure of Real Rates and Expected Inflation,” NBER Working Paper.

Aruoba, S. B., F. X. Diebold, and C. Scotti (2009): “Real-Time Measurement of Business Conditions,” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 27, 417–427.

Atkeson, A. and L. Ohanian (2001): “Are Phillips Curves Useful for Forecasting Inflation?” Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review, 25, 2–11.

Bachmann, R., S. Elstner, and E. Sims(2013): “Uncertainty and Economic Activity:

Evidence from Business Survey Data,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 5, 217–249.

Banbura, M., D. Giannone, and L. Reichlin (2010): “Large Bayesian Vector Auto Regressions,” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 25, 71–92.

Batchelor, R. A. (1986): “Quantitative v. Qualitative Measures of Inflation Expecta-tions,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 48, 99–120.

Batchelor, R. A. and A. B. Orr (1988): “Inflation Expectations Revisited,” Eco-nomica, 55, 317–331.

Bauwens, L., M. Lubrano, and J. Richard(1999): Bayesian Inference in Dynamic Econometric Models, Advanced Texts in Econometrics, Oxford University Press.

Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120, 387–422.

Blair, J. and M. Lacy (2000): “Statistics of Ordinal Variation,” Sociological Methods and Research, 28, 251–280.

Bloom, N. (2009): “The Impact of Uncertainty Shocks,” Econometrica, 77, 623–685.

Breitung, J. and M. Schmeling (2013): “Quantifying Survey Expectations: What’s Wrong with the Probability Approach?” International Journal of Forecasting, 29, 142–

154.

Camacho, M. and G. Perez-Quiros(2010): “Introducing the Euro-Sting: Short-Term Indicator of Euro Area Growth,” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 25, 663–694.

Carlson, J. A. and M. J. Parkin (1975): “Inflation Expectations,” Economica, 42, 123–138.

Carroll, C. D. (2003): “Macroeconomic Expectations of Households and Professional Forecasters,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 269–298.

Chauvet, M. and S. Potter (2013): “Forecasting Output,” in Handbook of Economic Forecasting II, ed. by G. Elliott and A. Timmermann, Elsevier, 141–194.

Clark, T. E. and M. W. McCracken (2009): “Nested Forecast Model Comparisons:

A New Approach to Testing Equal Accuracy,” Research Working Paper RWP 09-11, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.

Clark, T. E. and K. D. West (2007): “Approximately Normal Tests for Equal Pre-dictive Accuracy in Nested Models,” Journal of Econometrics, 138, 291–311.

Coibion, O. and Y. Gorodnichenko (2010): “Information Rigidity and the Expecta-tions Formation Process: A Simple Framework and New Facts,” NBER Working Papers 16537, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

——— (2012): “What Can Survey Forecasts Tell Us about Information Rigidities?” Jour-nal of Political Economy, 120, 116–159.

Croushore, D.(1993): “Introducing: The Survey of Professional Forecasters,” Business Review, 6, 3–15.

Croushore, D. and T. Stark (2001): “A Real-Time Data Set for Macroeconomists,”

Journal of Econometrics, 105, 111–130.

——— (2007): “Consumer Sentiment Surveys: Worldwide Review and Assessment,” Jour-nal of Business Cycle Measurement and AJour-nalysis, 3, 7–42.

Dasgupta, S. and K. Lahiri (1992): “A Comparative Study of Alternative Methods of Quantifying Qualitative Survey Responses Using NAPM Data,” Journal of Business

& Economic Statistics, 10, 391–400.

——— (1993): “On the Use of Dispersion Measures from NAPM Surveys in Business Cycle Forecasting,” Journal of Forecasting, 12, 239–253.

Deaves, R., E. Lüders, and M. Schröder (2010): “The Dynamics of Overconfi-dence: Evidence from Stock Market Forecasters,” Journal of Economic Behavior &

Organization, 75, 402–412.

Del Negro, M. and F. Schorfheide (2013): “DSGE Model-Based Forecasting,” in Handbook of Economic Forecasting II, ed. by G. Elliott and A. Timmermann, Elsevier, 57–140.

Dick, C. D. and L. Menkhoff (2013): “Exchange Rate Expectations of Chartists and Fundamentalists,” Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 37, 1362–1383.

Diebold, F. X. and R. S. Mariano(1995): “Comparing Predictive Accuracy,” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 13, 253–263.

Doan, T., R. Litterman, and C. Sims (1984): “Forecasting and Conditional Projec-tion Using Realistic Prior DistribuProjec-tions,” Econometric Reviews, 3, 1–100.

Dovern, J., U. Fritsche, and J. Slacalek(2012): “Disagreement among Forecasters in G7 Countries,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 94, 1081–1096.

Dräger, L. and M. Lamla (2012): “Updating Inflation Expectations: Evidence from Micro-Data,” Economics Letters, 117, 807–810.

Durbin, J. and S. Koopman (2012): Time Series Analysis by State Space Methods, Oxford University Press Oxford, 2 ed.

Ehrmann, M., S. Eijffinger, and M. Fratzscher (2012): “The Role of Central Bank Transparency for Guiding Private Sector Forecasts,” The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 114, 1018–1052.

1–14.

Faust, J. and J. H. Wright (2013): “Forecasting Inflation,” inHandbook of Economic Forecasting II, ed. by G. Elliott and A. Timmermann, Elsevier, 2–56.

Frale, C., M. Marcellino, G. L. Mazzi, and T. Proietti (2011): “EUROMIND:

A Monthly Indicator of the Euro Area Economic Conditions,” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in Society), 174, 439–470.

Geweke, J. (2005): Contemporary Bayesian Econometrics and Statistics, Wiley Series in Probability and Statistics, Wiley.

Ghysels, E. and J. H. Wright(2009): “Forecasting Professional Forecasters,” Journal of Business & Economic Statistics, 27, 504–516.

Giacomini, R. and H. White(2006): “Tests of Conditional Predictive Ability,” Econo-metrica, 74, 1545–1578.

Gibbs, J. P. and D. L. Poston (1975): “The Division of Labor: Conceptualization and Related Measures,” Social Forces, 53, 468–476.

Gilbert, T., C. Scotti, G. Strasser, and C. Vega (2010): “Why do Certain Macroeconomic News Announcements have a Big Impact on Asset Prices?” Working Paper.

Gürkaynak, R. S., B. Sack, and J. H. Wright(2010): “The TIPS Yield Curve and Inflation Compensation,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2, 70–92.

Haubrich, J., G. G. Pennacchi, and P. Ritchken (2008): “Estimating Real and Nominal Term Structures using Treasury Yields, Inflation, Inflation Forecasts, and Inflation Swap Rates,” Working Paper 0810, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

Hess, D. and A. Niessen (2010): “The Early News Catches the Attention: On the Relative Price Impact of Similar Economic Indicators,” Journal of Futures Markets, 30, 909–937.

Hubert, P.(2013): “FOMC Forecasts as a Focal Point for Private Expectations,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Forthcoming.

Ing, C.-K. and C.-Z. Wei(2003): “On Same-Realization Prediction in an Infinite-Order Autoregressive Process,” Journal of Multivariate Analysis, 85, 130–155.

Julier, S. and J. Uhlmann (1997): “A New Extension of the Kalman Filter to Nonlin-ear Systems,” in Proc. AeroSense: 11th Int. Symp. Aerospace/Defense Sensing, Simu-lation and Controls, 182–193.

Kalman, R. (1960): “A New Approach to Linear Filtering and Prediction Problems,”

Transactions of the ASME-Journal of Basic Engineering, 82, 35–45.

Kilian, L. (2009): “Not All Oil Price Shocks Are Alike: Disentangling Demand and Supply Shocks in the Crude Oil Market,” American Economic Review, 99, 1053–1069.

Kim, D. and A. Orphanides(2012): “Term Structure Estimation with Survey Data on Interest Rate Forecasts,” Journal of Financial & Quantitative Analysis, 47, 241–272.

Kim, S., N. Shephard, and S. Chib(1998): “Stochastic Volatility: Likelihood Inference and Comparison with ARCH Models,” The Review of Economic Studies, 65, 361–393.

Koopman, S. J.(1997): “Exact Initial Kalman Filtering and Smoothing for Nonstation-ary Time Series Models,” Journal of the American Statistical Association, 92, 1630–

1638.

Krüger, F. (2014): “Combining Density Forecasts under Various Scoring Rules: An Analysis of UK Inflation,” Working Paper, Heidelberg Institute for Theoretical Studies.

Kvalseth, T. (1995): “Coefficients of Variation for Nominal and Ordinal Categorical Data,” Perceptual and Motor Skills, 80, 843–847.

Lahiri, K. and X. Sheng (2008): “Evolution of Forecast Disagreement in a Bayesian Learning Model,” Journal of Econometrics, 144, 325–340.

Lahiri, K. and Y. Zhao (2014): “Quantifying Survey Expectations: A Critical Review and Generalization of the Carlson-Parkin Method,” International Journal of Forecast-ing, forthcoming.

Lamla, M. J. and T. Maag (2012): “The Role of Media for Inflation Forecast Dis-agreement of Households and Professional Forecasters,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 44, 1325–1350.

Löffler, G. (1999): “Refining the Carlson-Parkin Method,” Economics Letters, 64, 167–171.

ganization, 72, 638–655.

Maag, T. (2009): “On the Accuracy of the Probability Method for Quantifying Beliefs about Inflation,” KOF Working Paper No. 230.

Mankiw, N. G. and R. Reis (2002): “Sticky Information versus Sticky Prices: A Proposal to Replace the New Keynesian Phillips Curve,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1295–1328.

Mankiw, N. G., R. Reis, and J. Wolfers(2004): “Disagreement about Inflation Ex-pectations,” in NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2003, ed. by M. Gertler and K. Rogoff, MA: MIT Press, 209–248.

Menkhoff, L., R. R. Rebitzky, and M. Schröder (2009): “Heterogeneity in Ex-change Rate Expectations: Evidence on the Chartist-Fundamentalist Approach,” Jour-nal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 70, 241–252.

Mudholkar, G. S. (2004): “Fisher’s Z-Transformation,” in Encyclopedia of Statistical Sciences, John Wiley & Sons, Inc.

Nardo, M. (2003): “The Quantification of Qualitative Survey Data: A Critical Assess-ment,” Journal of Economic Surveys, 17, 645–668.

Newey, W. K. and K. D. West (1987): “A Simple, Positive Semi-Definite, Het-eroskedasticity and Autocorrelation Consistent Covariance Matrix,” Econometrica, 55, 703–708.

Nolte, I., S. Nolte, and W. Pohlmeier(2014): “What Determines Forecasters’ Fore-cast Errors?” Working Paper, Center for Quantitative Methods and Survey Research (CMS), University of Konstanz.

Nolte, I. and W. Pohlmeier (2007): “Using Forecasts of Forecasters to Forecast,”

International Journal of Forecasting, 23, 15–28.

Pesaran, M. H. and M. Weale (2006): “Survey Expectations,” in Handbook of Eco-nomic Forecasting I, ed. by G. Elliott, C. W. Granger, and A. Timmermann, North-Holland, 715–776.

Reardon, S. F. (2009): “Measures of Ordinal Segregation,” Research on Economic In-equality, 17, 129–155.

Schmeling, M. and A. Schrimpf (2011): “Expected Inflation, Expected Stock Re-turns, and Money Illusion: What Can We Learn from Survey Expectations,” European Economic Review, 55, 702–719.

Schmidt, P. (1977): “Estimation of Seemingly Unrelated Regressions with Unequal Numbers of Observations,” Journal of Econometrics, 5, 365–377.

Smith, J. and M. McAleer (1995): “Alternative Procedures for Converting Qual-itative Response Data to QuantQual-itative Expectations: An Application to Australian Manufacturing,” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 10, 165–185.

Swamy, P. and J. Mehta (1975): “On Bayesian Estimation of Seemingly Unrelated Regressions when Some Observations are Missing,” Journal of Econometrics, 3, 157–

169.

Theil, H. (1955): “Recent Experiences with the Munich Business Test: An Expository Article,” Econometrica, 23, 184–192.

Villani, M.(2009): “Steady-State Priors for Vector Autoregressions,” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 24, 630–650.

Wan, E. A. and R. Van Der Merwe (2000): “The Unscented Kalman Filter for Nonlinear Estimation,” in Adaptive Systems for Signal Processing, Communications, and Control Symposium 2000. AS-SPCC. The IEEE 2000, IEEE, 153–158.

Wright, J. H.(2013): “Evaluating Real-Time VAR Forecasts with an Informative Demo-cratic Prior,” Journal of Applied Econometrics, 28, 762–776.

Ich versichere hiermit, dass ich Kapitel 1 der vorliegenden Arbeit ohne Hilfe Dritter und ohne Benutzung anderer als der angegebenen Hilfsmittel verfasst habe.

Kapitel 2 entstammt einer gemeinsamen Arbeit mit Xuguang Sheng von der American University in Washington, D.C. und Jingyun Yang vom Rush University Medical Center in Chicago. Meine individuelle Leistung bei der Erstellung des Kapitels beträgt 45 %.

Kapitel 3 entstammt einer gemeinsamen Arbeit mit Christoph Frey von der Universität Konstanz. Meine individuelle Leistung bei der Erstellung des Kapitels beträgt 65 %.