• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Notwithstanding a series of important analytical issues - which might indeed be a source of serious interpretative conflict, a n d of which we have provided some illustrations - we do see a n ideal sequence of modes of interpretation and levels of description in which both the evolutionist a n d regulationist programmes could ambitiously fit. As sketched in Table 2, they run from a sort of 'nano-economics', wherein t h e abandonment of any magic of a perfect a n d invariant rationality forces a dialogue with cognitive and social psychology, organization theory, sociology, all the way t o grand historical conjectures on the long term destinies of contemporary forms of socio-economic organisation. Even a quick look a t t h e table highlights the enormous gaps between what we now a n d what such a n ideal evolutionary-institutionalist research programme would demand. These gaps a r e high a t all levels but in our view four issues a r e particularly urgent on the agenda.

A first one concerns co-evolutionary processes. T h e essence of t h e co-evolutionary point is t h a t what happens in each partly autonomous domain of the system (e.g. technology or insti- tutioilal structures) shapes a n d constrains what is going t o happen in t h e other ones. Hence, the overall dynamics is determined by the ways each domain evolves but also by t h e ways t h e various domains are coupled with each other.14 We have listed "co-evolution" under a separate level of description in order t o demarcate t h a t broad area covering e.g. the interactions between t h e forms of economic organisation, social a n d political institutions a n d technical change. How- ever, co-evolutionary issues appear a t all levels of description. For example, the emergence a n d development of each industry ought t o be seen a s a co-evolutionary process between technologies corporate organisations and supporting institutions (Nelson (1994)). Analogously, t h e origins of organisational routines (cf. above) is intimately a co-evolutionary process, shaped by diverse a n d probably conflicting selection criteria (i.e. problem-solving vs. governance requirements).

A second (and related) item which is high on t h e research agenda regards t h e transition across rliflerent socio-economic regimes of growth: for example, a t which level can such transitions be

1 4

A co-evolutiouary view runs against, for example, "technological determinism" (i.e. technology proceeds exclusively according t o its inner logics, and institutions ought simply t o adjust, with varying lags) but also t o

"social determinism" (e.g. technology is purely a "social construction"). On the contrary, the co-evolutionary view does accept t h a t technological change and social change have their own inner logics (possibly conflicting with each other) and does attempt t o explain e.g. the emerging trajectories of technical change as the outcome of such a coupling.

Table 2. Levels of Analysis.

Objects of analysis Examples of

(some still t o be explored) "analytical styles"

Level 0 From "macroeconomics" t o (i) Nature and origins of routines a n d , generally, From H.Simon t o Holland et al. (1986) microanalytic part

microeconomics 1,ehavioural norms of Nelson and Winter (1982); Cohen and Bacdayan

(ii) Learning processes (1994); Egidi (1994); organisational economics on (iii) Mechanisms of expectation formation "competences" , etc.; Coriat (1994a); Dosi et al. (1994);

(iv) Nature and evolution of micro organizations (e.g. Marengo (1992); Warglien (1995); Marengo and Tordjman (1995); possible economic applications of Fontana and business firms)

Buss (1994); and a lot to be done ...

(v) 'Embedding' mechanisms of individual behaviours . . into the institutional context

(i) Generic properties of growth fuelled by technical Explicit microfounded models with aggregate emergent

change statistical properties:

(ii) Industrial evolution e.g. Nelson and Winter (1982); Silverberg and Verspagen (iii) Self-organizing properties of labour markets (1994); Lesourne (199 1) Dosi et al. (1995)

(iv) T h e dynamics of consumption patterns

(i) Functional relations among aggregate variables More 'stylized' b u t (hopefully) institutionally richer macro (ii) Socio-economic regimes: consistency conditions models (not necessarily microfounded):

among processes of economic adjustment a n d from KeynesianIKaldorian models t o Boyer (1988a/b) ...

institutions Gordon (1994); Silverberg (1987)

(i) Co-evolutionary patterns between teclinologies, . . . A lot of appreciative theorizing from historians. . .

corporate organizations and broader institutions relatively little modeling (but cf. the suggestion in Nelson (ii) C o u ~ l e d institutional dvnamics.. . (1994) on industrial dynamics). . .

\ I 1

(iii) (Political discretionality, and institutional inertias a vast regulation-inspired empirical literature (cf. Boyer and Saillard (1995))

Level 4 "Grand history" General interpretative conjectures on long-term historical . . . from Karl Marx to . . . Schumpeter.. . t o Freeman and patterns . . . Perez (1988) . . . t o Aglietta (1982) and Boyer and Mistral

(1978) (just t o name the perspectives discussed in this work) . . . !!

detected? (which probably will be conditional on the type of transition one is talking about).

What are the effects of "higher level" changes (e.g. in the institutional set-ups or in the policy environment) upon micro-economic behaviour? And, conversely, under what circumstances non-average micro-behaviours become 'autocatalytic' and eventually induce higher-lee1 phase transitions? What kind of co-evolutionary processes do particular classes of transitions entail?;

etc.

A third priority item, in our view, concerns what could be called, in a shorthand, the relation- ships between emergence and embeddedness, or, putting it another way, the role of "bottom-up"

processes shaping/generating higher-level entities (or a t least aggregate statistical patterns) vs.

"top-down" processes by which higher level entities (e.g. institutions, established mechanisms of interaction, etc.) shapelgenerate 'lower level' behaviours. One of the claims underlying this whole paper is t h a t the links work both ways and that one ought t o account for "macrofounda- tion of the micro" as well as "microfoundations of the macro"

. .

. B u t how does one get beyond suggestive metaphors and elaborates more rigorous - albeit highly simplified - models which nonetheless capture the intuition? (Note t h a t what we mean is something more than a feed- back between a system-level state variable - say, a price or a market share

-,

and the argument of an individual decision algorithm - say, pricing or investment rules -: somewhat deeper, we think it is not beyond reach t o develop models whereby micro decision algorithms themselves are shaped by macro states and, conversely, possibly non-linear interactions among the former cha.nge collective interaction rules/constraints/perceived payoffslperceived opportunities . . . ).

But in turn, all this involves difficult issues concerning, again, coordination; relative time-scales of change; relative invariances of 'structures' and conditions of their stability

.

. . .

Fourth, we suggest t h a t the nature of learning processes, too, ought t o deserve a prior- ity attention. As Lundvall emphasizes (in this volume) the objects of learning ("know what",

"know why", "know how", "know who"

.

. .) are likely t o discriminate among classes of learning processes. And, certainly, the competence gap between the intrinsic complexity of any one cog- nitionldecision problem a t hand and the pre-existing abilities of (individual or collective) agents fundamentally shapes learning processes (for a discussion, cf. Dosi and Egidi (1991)). But, in turn, it is only a weird twist of contemporary economic thought t h a t gives credibility t o the idea t h a t increnlentalist procedures, either based on sophisticated hypothesis testing (such as in Bayesian models) or stimulus-response reinforcements are the general paradigm of learning (note t h a t this applies t o 'evolutionary games', but also t o most evolutionary models in general)

that one has developed so far.15

As a way forward, we suggest, possibly building upon preliminary (and still very rudimen- tary) attempts by e.g. Marengo (1992), Egidi (1994), Cohen and Bacdayan (1994), Marengo and Tordjman (1995) and also Dosi et al. (1994), a priority task is t o account for the formation and collective establishment of cognitive categories, problem-solving procedures ( . . .routines ??

. . . ) and expectations about the identities and behaviours of other social axtors

. .

. l 6

Yes, all this is an enormous task. Very fascinating and extremely difficult. The way we see it pursued, it involves tight and troublesome interchanges between empirical investigations, "ap- preciative theorizing" and formal modeling efforts. It is likely t o involve also major adjustments in the building blocks of institutionalist/evolutionary theories themselves.

Probably, we witness now a rare window of opportunity for fulfilling the promise of making economics an "evolutionary/institutionalist discipline". The blame for failing t o do so will fall mainly on ourselves, well before the sectarian attitudes of chair committees or international jour~lal editors . .

.

151ncidentally, "Bayesian" and "Pavlovian" learning have most characteristics in common since both claim (i) what Sarage would have called a "small world" hypothesis (the notional set of events and response strategies is given from the s t a r t ) ; and (ii) there is a striking transparence of the links between actions and consequences.

Hence, ultimately, the difference between the two just rests on what the theorist assumes the agent t o consciously know, without much influence on the ultimate outcomes. So, for example, it is easy for biologists overwhelmed by ecoiiomists' fascination t o build models of rats who behave in equilibrium "as . . .if" understanding strategies in- volving first-order conditions and Lagrange multipliers, or conversely, respectable economists claiming 'Pavlovian' convergence t o sophisticated Rational Expectation equilibria.

''By way of a comparison, recall that even in the most sophisticated state-of-the-art accounts, in economics, of behaviours and interactions (even under conditions of imperfect information) agents are assumed t o obviously have the correct 'transparent' understanding of the causal links of the environment, t o obviously know how t o solve the technical problems a t hand . . .

References

Abramovitz, M. (1989). Thinking About Growth, CambridgeINew York, Cambridge University Press.

Aglietta, M. (1974). Accumulation et re'gulation du capitalisme en longue pe'riode. L'exemple des Etats-linis (1870-1970), Thdse, Paris, October.

Aglietta, M. (1932). Regulation and Crisis of Capitalism, New York, Monthly Review Press.

Aglietta, M. (1993). "La finance au Japon, Changements de structures et adaptations des comportements". Communication au colloque; Mode de rdgulation a u Japon et Relations Internationales: de l'histoire longue aux transformations rkcentes" in: Japon in Extenso, Revue, No. 33, 1994.

Amendola, G., G. Dosi and E. Papagni (1993). "The Dynamics of International Competitive- ness", Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv.

Aoki, M. (1995). "Unintended fit: Organisational Evolution and Government Design of Institu- tions in Japan", Working Paper, Department of Economics, Stanford University.

Arthur, B., Y. Ermoliev and Y. Kaniovski (1987). "Path-Dependent Processes and the Emer- gence of Macrostructures", European Journal of Operations Research, (30)294-303.

Basalla, G. (1988). The Evolution of Technology, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

Basle, M., Mazier, J., and J . F . Vidal (1984). "Quand les crise durent

... ",

Economica, Paris.

Bowles, S. and H. Gintis (1993). "The Revenge of Homo Economicus: Contested Exchange and the Revival of Political Economy", Journal of Economic Perspectives, (7)83-102.

Boyer, R. (1973). La crise: une mise en perspective historique" in: Critique de 1'Economie Politique, Revue, Paris.

Boyer, R. and J . Mistral (1978). Accumulation, Inflation et Crise, Paris, PUF.

Boyer, R. (1986a). La The'orie de la Re'gulation, une analyse critique, La Ddcouverte, Paris.

Boyer, R. (1986b). La flexibilite' du travail en Europe, La Decouverte, Paris.

Boyer, R. (1987). "Regulation7', in: The New Palgrave, London, Macmillan.

Boyer, R. (1988a). "Technical Change and the Theory of 'Registration"', in: Dosi et. al. (1988).

Boyer, R. (1988b). "Formalizing Growth Regimes", in: Dosi et. al. (1988)

Boyer, R. (1990). The Regulation School. A Critical Introduction, New York, Columbia Univer- sity Press.

Boyer, R. and A. Orlean (1991a). "Les transformations des conventions salariales entre thdorie et histoire. D'Henry Ford au fordisme". Revue Economique, 42(2)233-272, Mars.

Boyer, R. and A. Orlean (1992). "How Do Conventions Evolve?", Journal of Evolutionary Economics,

Boyer, R. and Y. Saillard (eds.) (1995). Theorie de la Regulation. L'etat des savoir, Paris, La Decouvert

.

Caroli, E. (1995). Formation, Institutions et Croissance Economique, These IEP, Paris.

CEPREMAP, (1977). Approches de l'inflation: l'exemple francais, Convention de recherches, No. 22, mimeo, December.

Chia.roinonte, F., G. Dosi and L. Orsenigo (1992). "Innovative Learning and Institutions in t h e Process of Development: On the Microfoundations of Growth Regimes", in R. Thomson (ed.) Learning and Technological Change, London, Macmillan.

Chiaromonte, F. and G. Dosi (1993). "Heterogeneity, Competition and Macroeconomic Dynam- ics", Structural Change and Economic Dynamics, (4)39-6.

Commons, J.R. (1934). Institutional: Its Place in Political Economy, University of Wisconsin Press, Madison.

Cohen, M. and Bacdayan (1994). "Organizational Routines As Stored Procedural Memory:

Evidence From a Laboratory Study", Organization Sciences, 5554-5.

Coriat, B. (1982). L'atelier et le Chronometre, Bourgeois, Paris.

Coriat, B. (1990). L'atelier et le Robot, Bourgeois, Paris.

Coriat, B. (1991-94). Penser a 1'Envers - Travail et Organisation duns la firme Japonaise, C.

Bourgois; 2nd revised edition Bourgois/Choix 1994.

Coriat, B. (1993). "L'hypothkse du Compagnie-isme" in: Mondes en Developpement Revue, No.

4, Paris.

Coriat, B. (1994). "La Theorie de la Regulation. Origines, Specificitks, Enjeux", in: Future Anterieur, Paris, L'Harmattan; special issue of The'orie de la Re'gulation et critique de la Raison Economique.

Coriat, B. (1994a). "Variety, Routines and Networks: The metamorphosis of the Fordist Firms", Industrial and Corporate Change, 4(1), Oxford University Press.

Coriat, B. and G. Dosi (1995). "Learning How t o Govern and Learning How t o Solve Prob- lems. On the Coevolution of Competences, Conflicts and Organisational Routines", IIASA Working Paper, WP-95-06, Laxenburg, Austria; forthcoming in: A. Chandler, P. Hagstrom and 0. Sijlvell (eds.), The Dynamic Firm, Oxford, Oxford University Press.

Coriat, B. and 0. Weinstein (1995). Les nouvelles The'ories de l'Entreprise, in: Hachette, Paris.

Conlisk, J. (1989). "An Aggregate Model of Technical Change", Quarterly Journal of Economics, (104)787-821.

David, P. (1975). Technical Choice, Innovation and Economic Growth, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

David, P.A. (1985). "Clio and the Economics of QWERTY", American Economic Review.

Papers and Proceedings, (75)332-7.

David, P.A. (1992). "Heroes, Herds and Hysteresis in Technological Change: Thomas Edison and the Battle of the Systems", Industrial and Corporate Change, (1)139-180.

David, P.A. (1994). "Why Are Institutions the Carriers of History?", Structural Change and Economic Dynamics.

Day, R. and G. Eliasson (eds.) (1986). The Dynamics of Market Economics, Amsterdam, North Holland.

Delorme, R. and C. Andrk (1983). L'Etat et I'Economie, Seuil, Paris.

DiMaggio, P. J. and W.W. Powell (1991). "The iron cage revisited: Institutional Isomorphism and Collective Rationality in Organisational Fields", in: W.W. Powell and P.J. DiMag- gio (eds.) The New Institutionalism in Organisational Analysis, Chicago, University of Chicago Press.

Dosi, G . (1982). "Technical paradigms and technical trajectories, t h e Determinants and Di- rections of Technical Change and the Transformation of the Economy", Research Policy, March.

Dosi, G . (1984). Teci~nical Change and Industrial Transformation, Macmillan, London.

Dosi, G. (1988). "Sources, Procedures and Microeconomic Effects of Innovation", Journal of Economic Literature, (26)126-173.

Dosi, G., C. Freeman, R.R.Nelson, G. Silverberg, L. Soete (eds.) (1988) Technical Change and Economic Theory, London, Francis Pinter; New York, Columbia University Press.

Dosi, G., I<. Pavitt and L. Soete (1990). The Economics of Technological Change and Interna- tional Trade, Brighton, Wheatsheaf and New York, New York University Press.

Dosi, G. (199 1). "Perspectives on Evolutionary Theory", Science and Public Policy, 18353-361.

Dosi, G. and L. Marengo (1993). "Some Elements of An Evolutionary Theory of Organisational Competences", in: R.W. England (1994).

Dosi, G., S. Fabiani, R. Aversi and M. Meacci (1994). "The Dynamics of International Dif- ferentiation: A Multi-Country Evolutionary Model", Industrial and Corporate Change, (3)225-242.

Dosi, G., C. Freeman and S. Fabiani (1994). "The Process of Economic Development: Introduc- ing Some Stylized Facts and Theories on Technologies, Firms and Institutions", Industrial

and Corporate Change, (3)l-46.

Dosi, G. (1995). "Hierarchies, Markets and Power: Some Foundational Issues on the Natue of Contemnporary Economic Organisations", Industrial and Corporate Change, 4: 1-19.

Dosi, G., 0. Marsili, L. Orsenigo and R. Salvatore (1995). "Learning, Market Selection and the Evolution of Industrial Structures, Small Business Economics, forthcoming.

Dupuy, J.P. (1980). "Convention et Common Knowledge", Revue e'conomique, 40(2)381-400.

Dupuy, J.P., F . Emard-Duvernay, 0. Favereau, A. Orlean, R. Salais,, and L. Thevenot (1989).

"L'6conomie des conventions", Revue e'conomique, 40(2).

Eggertsson, T . (1990). Economic Behaviour and Institutions, Cambridge University Press, Cam- bridge.

Egidi, M. (1994). Routines, Hierarchies of Problems, Procedural Behaviour: Some Evidence from Experiments, IIASA Working Paper WP-94-58, Laxenburg, Austria. Eliasson, G.

(1986). "Micro-Heterogeneity of Firms and Stability of Industrial Growth", in: England, R.W. (Ed.) (1994). Evolutionary Concepts in Contemporary Economics, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press.

Fagerberg, J . (1994). "Technology and International Differences in Growth Rates", Journal of Economic Literature, (32)1147-1175.

Favereau, 0. (1986). "La formalisation du role des conventions dans l'allocation des resources7', in: R. Salais (ed.) Le travail. Marche's, rGgles, conventions, INSEE-Economica, Paris.

Fontana, W . and L. Buss (1994). "'The Arrival of the Fittest': Toward a Theory of Biological Organisation", Bulletin of Mathematical Biology, 1-64.

Fontana, W. and L. Buss (1994a). "What Would Be Conserved If the 'Tape Were Run Twice!'.

Proc. Nat. Acad. Sci., USA.

Freeman, C. (1982). The Economics of Industrial Innovation, 2nd edition, Francis Pinter, London.

Freeman, C. and C. Perez (1988). "Structural Crises of Adjustment", in: Dosi e t . al.

Freeman, C. (1994). "The Economics of Technical Change", Cambridge Journal of Economics, 18463-514.

Granstrand, 0. (ed) (1994). The Economics of Technology, Amsterdam, ElsevierINorth Holland.

Grandstad, G. and P. Selle (1995), "Cultural Theory and the New Institutionalism", Journal of Theoretical Politics, (7)5-27.

Granovetter, M. (1985). "Economic Action and Social Structure: T h e Problem of Embedded- ness", American Journal of Sociology, 91: 481-510.

Hamilton, G.G. and R.C. Feenstra (1995). "Variety of Hierarchies and Markets: An Introduc- tion", Industrial and Corporate Change, 4: 51-91.

Hanusch, H. (1988) (Ed.). Evolutionary Economics, Cambridge University Press.

Hayek, F. (1937). "Economic and Knowledge", Economica, 4.

Hodgson, G. (1988). Economics and Institutions, Cambridge, Polity Press; Philadelphia, PA, University of Pennsylvania Press.

Hodgson, G. (1993). Economics and Evolution, Cambridge, Polity Press; Ann Arbor, NII, Michigan University Press.

Holland, J.H., K.J. Holyoak, R.E. Nisbett and P.R. Thagaro (1986). Induction, Cambridge, MA, MIT Press.

Jessop, B. (1989). "Regulation Theories in Retrospect and Prospect", Economics et Societe's, (4)7-62.

Kaniovski, Y. and P. Young (1994). "Learning Dynamics in Games with Stochastic Perturba- tions", IIASA Working Paper, WP-94-30; forthcoming in Games and Economic Behaviour, 1995.

Klepper, S. (1993). "Entry, Exit, Growth and Innovation over the Product Cycle", Carnegie- Mellon University, Working Paper.

I<uran, T . (1991). "Cognitive Limitations and Preference Evolution", Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics.

Levinthal, D. (1990). "Organisational Adaptation and Environmental Selection. Interrelated Processes of Change", Organisation Science, (2)140-145.

Lewis, D.K. (1969). Convention: A Philosophical Study. Cambridge, Harvard University Press, 213p.

Lindgren, R. (1992). "Evolutionary Phenomena in Simple Dynamics", in: C.G. Langton (ed.) Artificial Life II. Proc. Interdisciplinary Workshop on the Synthesis and Simulation of Living Systems a t Los Alamos, February 1990, Addison-Wesley, Redwood City, pp. 295- 312.

Lordon, F . (1993). Endogenous Structural Change and Crisis in a Multiple Time-Scales Growth Model, CEPREMAP Working Paper 9324, Paris.

Lundvall, B.A. (ed.)(1992). National Systems of Innovation, London, Francis Pinter.

Malerba, F . and L. Orsenigo (1994). "The Dynamics and Evolution of Industries", Laxenburg, Austria, IIASA, Working Paper, WP-94-120.

March, J.G. and J.P. Olsen (1989). Rediscovering Institutions. The Organizational Basis of Policies, New York, Free Press.

Marengo, L. (1992). "Coordination and Organisational Learning in the Firm", Journal of Evo- lutionary Economics, (2)313-326.

Marengo, L. and H. Tordjman (1995). "Speculation, Heterogeneity and Learning: A Model of Exchange Rate Dynamics", IIASA Working Paper, WP-95-17, Laxenburg, Austria.

Metcalfe, S. (1992). Variety, Structure and Change. An Evolutionary Perspective on t h e Com- petitive Process", Revue d'Economie Industrielle, (65)46-61.

Mokyr, J . (1990). The Lever of Riches, Oxford, Oxford University Press.

Nakicenovic, N. and A. Griibler (eds.) (1992). Diflusion of Technologies and Social Behaviour, Berlin/Heidelberg/New York, Springer Verlag.

R. Nelson and S. Winter (1982). An Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change, Bellkap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge (Mass.).

Nelson, R.R. (1987). Understanding Technical Change As An Evolutionary Process, North Holland.

Nelson, R.R. and G. Wright (1992) "The Rise and Fall of American Technological Leadership:

T h e Post-War Era in Historical Perspective", Journal of Economic Literature, (30)1931- 1964.

Nelson, R.R. (ed.) (1993). National Innovation Systems. A Comparative Study, Oxford/New York, Oxford University Press.

Nelson, R. (1995). "Recent Evolutionary Theorizing about Economic Change", Journal of Economic Literature, 33: 48-90.

North, D. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change and Economic Performance, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

North, D. (1991). "Institutions", Journal of Economic Perspectives, (5)97-112.

Orlean, A. (ed.) (1994). L 'economie des conventions, P U F , Paris.

Palmer, R.G., W.B. Arthur, J.H. Holland, B. LeBaron and P. Taylor (1994), "Artificial Economic Life: A Simple Model of a Stockmarket", Physica D, (75)264-274.

Patel, P. and I<. Pavitt (1994). "Uneven (and Divergent) Technological Accumulation among dvanced Countries: Evidence and a Framework of Explanation", Industrial and Corporate

Change, (3)759-.

Rosenberg, N. (1976). Perspectives on Technology, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

Rosenberg, N. (1982). Inside the Blackbox, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

P. Saviotti and S. Metcalfe (eds.) (1991). Evolutionary Economics, London/Chur, Harwood Academic Press.

Schwartz, M. and M. Thompson (1990). Divided We Stand. Redefining Politics, Technology and Social Choice, Brighton, Harvester Wheatsheaf.

Silverberg, G. (1987). "Technical Progress, Capitala Accumulation and Effective Demand: A Self-organization Model", in: D. Batten, J . Casti and B. Johansson (eds.), Economic Evolution and Structural Adjustment, Berlin/New York, Springer Verlag.

Silverberg, G., G . Dosi and L. Orsenigo (1988). "Innovation, Diversity and Diffusion. A Self- Organisation Model", Economic Journal, (98)1032-1054.

Silverberg G . and L. Soete (eds.) (1993). The Economics of Growth and Technical Change:

Technologies, Nations, Agents, Aldershot, Edward Elgar.

Silverberg, G . and B. Verspagen (1994). "Learning, Innovation and Economic Growth. A Long- Run Model of Industrial Dynamics", Industrial and Corporate Change, (3)199-223.

Silverberg, G . and B. Verspagen (1995). "Evolutionary Theorizing on Economic Growth", IIASA Working Paper WP-95-78; forthcoming in K. Dopfer (ed.), The Evolutionary Principles of Economics, Norwell, MA, Kluwer Ac. Publishers.

Silverberg, G. and B. Verspagen (1995a). "From the Artificial to the Endogenous: Modelling Evolutionary Adaptation and Economic Growth", IIASA, Working Paper, WP-95-

,

Lax- enburg, Austria.

Solow, J.A. (1990). The Labour Market As A Social Institution, Basil Blackwell.

Tordjman, H. (1993). Dynamiques spe'culations, he'te'roge'ne'ite' des agents et apprentissage: le cas des tauz de change. Thkse CEFI, UniversitG d'Aix-Marseille 11, Janvier 1994.

Utterback, J . and F. Suarez (1992). "Innovation, Competition and Market Structure", Research Policy, (21)l-21.

Veblen, T . (1898). "Why Is Economics Not An Evolutionary Science?", Quarterly Journal of Economics, (12).

Verspagen, B. (1993). Uneven Growth Between Independent Economics. The Evolutionary Dynamics of Growth and Technology, Aldershot, Avebury.

Vincenti (1990). What Do Engineers Do and How Do They Know It?, Baltimore, Johns Hopkins University Press.

Warglien, M. (1995). "Hierarchical Selection and Organisational Adaptation", Industrial and Corporate Change, (4)161-186.

Williamson, 0 .E. (1975). Market and Hierarchies, New York, The Free Press.

Williamson, O.E. and W.G. Ouchi (1981). "The Markets and Hierarchies and Visible Hand Perspectives", in: A.H. van de Ven and W.F. Joice (eds.) Perspectives on Organisational Design and Behaviour, Wiley, New York.

Williamson, O.E. (1985). The Economic Institutions of Capitalism, New York, Free Press.

Williamson, O.E. (1990). "The Firm As A Nexus of Treaties: An Introduction", in: M. Aoki, spective", Industrial and Corporate Change, 4: 1-19.

Winter, S.G. (1964). "Economical Natural Selection and the Theory of the Firm", Yale Eco- nomic Essays.

Winter, S.G. (1982). "An Essay on t h e Theory of Production", in: S.H. Hymans (ed.), Eco- nomics and the World Around It, Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press.

Winter, S.G. (1984). "Schumpeterian Competition under Alternative Technological Regimes", Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organisation, (5)287-320.

Winter, S.G. (1986). T h e Research Program of the Behavioural Theory of t h e Firm: Orthodox Critiques and Evolutionary Perspectives", in: B. Gilad and S. Kaish (eds.), Handbook of Behavioural Economics, Greenwich, Conn. JAI Press.

Winter, S.G. (1987a). "Natural Selection and Evolution", New Palgrave, 3, Macmillan.

Winter, S.G. (1987b). "Competition and Selection", New Palgrave, 2, Macmillan.

Winter, S.G. (1987b). "Competition and Selection", New Palgrave, 2, Macmillan.