• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

We empirically investigate the welfare effect of a historical institutional change from markets to quotas in the presence of frictions. Both systems allocated water to farmers for irrigation.

A market institution was active for more than 700 years in the southern Spanish town of Mula. In 1966, a fixed quota system replaced the auction. Under the quota system, farmers who owned a plot of land in the irrigated area were entitled to a fixed amount of water, proportional to the size of their plot. In the absence of frictions, a market is efficient because it allocates water according to the valuation of farmers. When frictions are present, however, markets may not be efficient. Frictions arose in Mula because farmers had to pay in cash for the water that they purchased, but did not always have enough cash during the critical season, when they needed the water the most. When farmers are liquidity constrained, the efficiency of auctions relative to quotas is theoretically ambiguous.

It is then an empirical question to assess which institution is more efficient. We show that some farmers were liquidity constrained in Mula, as some historians have suggested. Poor farmers bought less water than wealthy farmers during the critical season, and obtained lower revenue per tree as a result. To compute welfare under auctions and quotas, we estimated the dynamic demand system under the auction accounting for three main features of the empirical setting: intertemporal substitution, liquidity constraints, and seasonality.

37

We used the estimated demand system to compare welfare under markets, quotas, and the highest-valuation allocation.

The contributions of this paper are twofold. First, from a historical perspective, we pro-vide empirical epro-vidence of a source of inefficiency in water markets. Second, from an indus-trial organization perspective, we propose a dynamic demand model that includes storability, seasonality, and liquidity constraints. Ignoring the presence of liquidity constraints biases the estimated inverse demand and demand elasticity downwards. To perform the estimation we used only the choices of farmers who were not liquidity constrained; then, we used the model to infer the conduct of all farmers in a counterfactual setting in which no one was liquidity constrained. Our approach may also be applied to other settings by identifying, for example, rational agents, informed consumers, buyers affected by inertia, or other frictions, and simulating counterfactuals where those features are not present.

Our analysis is subject to several limitations. First, the empirical results in this paper apply only to the empirical setting in Mula. One should not conclude that all water markets are inefficient. We have presented an empirical framework incorporating the main compo-nents found in other water markets: seasonal demand, storability, and liquidity constraints.

Our framework can be adapted to assess the efficiency of water markets in other empirical settings. Second, the results from our welfare analysis in Mula only apply to the 24 apricot farmers used in our sample. Finally, our model does not allow for systematic (or perma-nent) differences in productivity across farmers. We believe this is sensible in the empirical context of Mula for the reasons discussed in the paper. Our goal was to investigate how the institutional change, from markets to quotas, affected efficiency for apricot farmers in Mula. However, allowing for systematic or serially correlated differences in productivity may generate dynamic sample selection on unobservables, and may be a central explanation in favor of the efficiency of markets in general. Enriching the model in such dimension is an avenue for future research.

References

[1] Aguirregabiria, V., 2005, “Nonparametric Identification of Behavioral Responses to Counterfactual Pol-icy Interventions in Dynamic Discrete Decision Processes,” Economics Letters, Vol. 87, 393–398.

[2] Aguirregabiria, V., and Mira P., 2007, “Sequential estimation of dynamic discrete games,”Econometrica, Vol. 75, No. 1, 1–53.

[3] Aguirregabiria, V., and Nevo, A., 2013, “Recent Developments in Empirical IO: Dynamic Demand and Dynamic Games,” Advances in Economics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications: Tenth World Congress.

[4] Albuquerque, R., and Hopenhayn, H. A., 2004, “Optimal Lending Contracts and Firm Dynamics,”

Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 71, No. 2, 285-315.

[5] Arcidiacono, P., and Miller, R. A., 2011, “Conditional choice probability estimation of dynamic discrete choice models with unobserved heterogeneity,” Econometrica, Vol. 79, No. 6, 1823-1867.

[6] Athey, A., Coey, D. and Levin, J., 2013, “Set-Asides and Subsidies in Auctions,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, Vol. 5, No. 1, 1-27.

[7] Banerjee, A. V., and Moll, B., 2010, “Why Does Misallocation Persist?,” American Economic Journal:

Macroeconomics, Vol. 2, No. 1, 189-206.

[8] Berry, S., Levinsohn, J., and Pakes, A., 1995, “Automobile Prices in Market Equilibrium,”Econometrica, Vol. 63, No. 4, 841-90.

[9] Blevins, J. R., 2016, “Sequential Monte Carlo Methods for Estimating Dynamic Microeconomic Models,”

Journal of Applied Econometrics, Vol. 31, No. 5, 773-804.

[10] Boizot, C., Robin, J. M., and Visser, M., 2001, “The demand for food products: an analysis of inter-purchase times and inter-purchased quantities,” Economic Journal, Vol. 111, No. 470, 391-419.

[11] Bronnenberg, B. J., Dubé, J. P., Gentzkow, M., and Shapiro, J. M., 2015, “Do pharmacists buy Bayer?

Informed shoppers and the brand premium,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 130, No. 4, 1669-1726.

[12] Bubb, R., Kaur, S., and Mullainathan, S., 2016, “Contracting Failures in the Village Economy,” working paper.

[13] Che Y.-K., and Gale, I., 1998, “Standard Auctions with Financially-Constrained Buyers,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 65, No. 1, 1-21.

[14] Che Y.-K., Gale, I., and Kim J., 2013, “Assigning Resources to Budget-Constrained Agents,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 80, No. 1, 73-107.

[15] Coman, K., 1911, “Some Unsettled Problems of Irrigation,” American Economic Review, Vol. 1, No. 1, 1-19.

[16] Connault, B., 2016, “Hidden rust models,” working paper.

[17] Donna, J. D., and Espín-Sánchez, J. A., 2017, “Let the Punishment Fit The Criminal,” working paper.

[18] Donna, J. D., and Espín-Sánchez, J. A., 2018, “Complements and Substitutes in Sequential Auctions:

The Case of Water Auctions,” RAND Journal of Economics,Vol. 49, No. 1, 87–127.

[19] Espín-Sánchez, J. A., 2017, “Institutional Institutional Inertia: Persistent Inefficient Institutions in Spain,” Journal of Economic History, Vol. 77, No. 3, 692-723.

[20] Garrido, S., 2011, “Governing scarcity. Water Markets, Equity and Efficiency in pre-1950s Eastern Spain,” International Journal of the Commons, Vol. 5, No. 2., 513-534.

[21] González Castaño, J., and Llamas Ruiz, P., 1991,El agua en la Ciudad de Mula, S. XVI-XX., Comu-nidad de Regantes Pantano de la Cierva,Mula.

39

[22] Gowrisankaran, G., and Rysman, M., 2012, “Dynamics of Consumer Demand for New Durable Goods,”

Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 120, No. 6, 1173-1219.

[23] Guinnane, T. W., 2001, “Cooperatives As Information Machines: German Rural Credit Cooperatives, 1883 1914,” Journal of Economic History, Vol. 61, No. 2, 366-389.

[24] Grafton, R. Q., Libecap, G., McGlennon, S., Landry, C., and O’Brien, B., 2011, “An Integrated As-sessment of Water Markets: A Cross-Country Comparison,” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy, Vol. 5, No. 2, 219-239.

[25] Handel, B. R., and Kolstad, J. T., 2015, “Health Insurance for “Humans”: Information Frictions, Plan Choice, and Consumer Welfare,” American Economic Review, Vol. 105, No. 8, 2449-2500.

[26] Hendel, I., and Nevo, A., 2006, “Measuring the implications of sales and consumer inventory behavior,”

Econometrica, Vol. 74, No. 6, 1637-1673.

[27] Hotz, J., and Miller, R., 1993, “Conditional Choice Probabilities and the Estimation of Dynamic Mod-els,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 60, No. 3, 497-529.

[28] Hotz, J., Miller, R., Sanders, S., and Smith, J., 1994, “A Simulation Estimator for Dynamic Models of Discrete Choice,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 61, No. 2., 265-289.

[29] Hu Y., and Shum M., 2012, “Nonparametric identification of dynamic models with unobserved state variables,” Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 171, 32–44.

[30] Jayachandran, S., 2013, “Liquidity Constraints and Deforestation: The Limitations of Payments for Ecosystem Services,” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Vol. 103, No. 2, 309-313.

[31] Jofre-Bonet, M., and Pesendorfer, M., 2003, “Estimation of a Dynamic Auction Game,” Econometrica, Vol. 71, No. 5, 1443-1489.

[32] Johnson, E. M., and Rehavi, M. M., 2016, “Physicians treating physicians: Information and incentives in childbirth,” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, Vol. 8, No. 1, 115-141.

[33] Ketcham, J. D., Kuminoff, N. V., and Powers, C. A., 2016, “Estimating the heterogeneous welfare effects of choice architecture: An application to the medicare prescription drug insurance market,”

NBER working paper No. w22732.

[34] Laffont, J.-J., and Matoussi, M. S., 1995, “Moral Hazard, Financial Constraints and Sharecropping in El Oulja,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 62, No. 3, 381-399.

[35] Libecap, G. D., 2011, “Institutional Path Dependence in Adaptation to Climate: Coman’s “Some Un-settled Problems of Irrigation,” American Economic Review, Vol. 101, No. 1, 64-80.

[36] Maass, A., and Anderson, R. L., 1978,... and the Desert Shall Rejoice: Conflict, Growth, and Justice in Arid Environments, The MIT Press.

[37] Magnac, T., and D. Thesmar, 2002, “Identifying Dynamic Discrete Decision Processes,” Econometrica, Vol. 70, No. 2, 801–816.

[38] Marion, J., 2007, “Are bid preferences benign? The effect of small business subsidies in highway pro-curement auctions,” Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 91, 1591-1624.

[39] Musso y Fontes, J., 1847,Historia de los riegos de Lorca, Imprenta José Carle-Palacios.

[40] Moll, B., 2014, “Productivity Losses from Financial Frictions: Can Self-Financing Undo Capital Misal-location?,” American Economic Review, Vol. 104, No. 10, 3186-3221.

[41] Norets A., 2009, “Inference in dynamic discrete choice models with serially correlated unobserved state variables,” Econometrica, Vol. 77, 1665–1682.

[42] Ohio Supercomputer Center. 1987, “Columbus OH: Ohio Supercomputer Center,”

http://osc.edu/ark:/19495/f5s1ph73.

[43] Pérez-Pastor, A., Domingo, R., and Torrecillas, A., 2009, “Response of apricot trees to deficit irrigation strategies,” Irrigation Science, Vol. 27, 231-242.

[44] Pérez Picazo, Ma. T., and Lemeunier, G., 1985, “Agua y coyuntura económica. Las transformaciones de los regadíos murcianos (1450-1926),” Cuadernos de Geografía Humana.

[45] Pires, T., and Salvo, A., 2015, “Cash-Constrained Households and Product Size,” working paper.

[46] Rosenzweig, M. R., and Wolpin, K. I., 1993, “Constraints, Consumption Smoothing, and the Accumula-tion of Durable ProducAccumula-tion Assets in Low-Income Countries: Investments in Bullocks in India,”Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 101, No. 2, 223-244.

[47] Rust, J., 1996, “Numerical Dynamic Programming in Economics,” inHandbook of Computational Eco-nomics, Vol. 1, ed by. H. Amman, D. Kendrick, and J. Rust. Amsterdam: North- Holland, 619–729.

[48] Timmins, C., 2002, “Measuring the Dynamic Efficiency Costs of Regulators’ Preferences: Municipal Water Utilities in the Arid West,” Econometrica, Vol. 70, No. 2, 603-629.

[49] Torrecillas, A., Domingo, R., Galego, R., and Ruiz-Sánchez, M.C., 2000, “Apricot tree response to withholding irrigation at different phenological periods,” Scientia Horticulturae, Vol. 85, 201-205.

[50] Udry, C., 1994, “Risk and Insurance in a Rural Credit Market: An Empirical Investigation in Northern Nigeria,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 61, No. 3, 495-526.

[51] Vörösmarty, C. J., McIntyre, P. B., Gessner, M. O., Dudgeon, D., Prusevich, A., Green, P., Glidden, S., Bunn, S. E., Sullivan, C. A., Reidy Liermann, C., and Davies, P. M., 2010, “Global threats to human water security and river biodiversity,” Nature, Vol. 467, 555-561.

41