• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

The Colonial Economy, 1863–1953

Unhappy is the Cambodian! Hemmed in between the Siamese on the one hand, and the Annamites on the other, who together have robbed him of his richest provinces, rendered immobile by the operation of a feudal law which prevents him from acquiring lands of his own, a vigorous hand is needed to support him, and enable him to preserve his autonomy, while the ameliorating infl uences of European civilization are gradually brought to bear upon him.

Dr Morice1

Long before the arrival of the French, foreigners had been taking account of Cambodia’s economic potential. When the Chinese envoy, Zhou Daguan, visited the Khmer empire at the end of the thirteenth century, the power and glory of the Angkorian kings had already diminished.

Zhou observed that whole villages had been laid waste. Soon Angkor itself would be besieged by the Siamese and attacks would continue for a cen-tury until the kings abandoned Angkor for a new capital at Lovek, north-west of the present capital, Phnom Penh. Despite this political decline, the lifestyle Zhou described was one of irresistible ease, as he recorded,

“Chinese sailors coming to the country note with pleasure that it is not necessary to wear clothes and, since rice is easily had, women easily persuaded, houses easily run, furniture easily come by, and trade easily carried on, a great many sailors desert to take up permanent residence.”2

At the time of Zhou’s visit in 1296, Cambodia was divided into more than 90 provinces or srok, and every village, no matter how small, he

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 30

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 30 6/15/10 12:06:46 PM6/15/10 12:06:46 PM

Th e Colonial Economy, 1863–1953 31

noted, had its own local offi cial and a wat or pagoda, Th eravada Buddhism being the dominant religion. Zhou described an affl uent, slave-owning population where “Families of wealth may own more than one hundred;

those of lesser means content themselves with ten or twenty; only the very poor have none.”3 Th e slaves, if not prisoners of war or insolvent debtors, were indigenous tribespeople, “wild men from the hills,” ac-cording to Zhou. He divided these montagnards into two categories: those who understood the dominant language and were sold in the towns as slaves, and those who refused to submit to civilisation and who wandered about the mountains. He reported on methods of rice cultivation and on self-seeding fl oating rice. He also saw pepper, growing “twisted round the stems of the rattan, fastening on like a hop vine.”4

Trade was the province of women and, Zhou observed, “For this reason, a Chinese arriving in the country loses no time in getting himself a mate, for he will fi nd her commercial instincts a great asset.”5 Th e daily markets he described diff ered little from local markets c. 2000, except for the currency of exchange. At the end of the thirteenth century, according to Zhou, “In small transactions barter is carried on with rice, cereals and Chinese objects; fabrics are next employed, and fi nally in big deals, gold or silver is used.”6 Th e precious products of the country, in terms of their export potential for the Chinese market, were rare woods, kingfi sher feathers, elephant tusks, rhinoceros horn, and beeswax; the more commonplace items included laka-wood, cardamoms, gamboge, lacquer and chaulmoogra oil. In return, the biggest demand was for Chinese gold and silver because, as Zhou noted, these minerals were not found in Cambodia.

Th ree hundred years later, Cambodia was again at war with Siam.

Lovek was plundered in 1594 and the king moved his court to Srei Santhor, near today’s Udong market, about 30 kilometres northwest of Phnom Penh. Spanish and Portuguese adventurers advised the Cambo-dian monarch to seek help from Spain. In 1604, Gabriel Quiroga de San Antonio, a Spanish Dominican friar, addressed King Philippe III urging the conquest of Cambodia for religious, as well as political and economic reasons.7 Th e Kingdom of Cambodia, he reminded his monarch, had been well known by the Portuguese for more than 108 years. He described the annual fl ooding of the Mekong, the abandoned city of Angkor, the royal court at Srei Santhor along with “the kingdom’s councils, the audience and the chancellery through which it is governed,” and the city of Churdumuco (Chatomuk, now Phnom Penh). Th e population there, he observed, was “very dense” and “among them there are leading citizens and common people.”8 All acknowledged only one king and they paid

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 31

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 31 6/15/10 12:06:47 PM6/15/10 12:06:47 PM

32 Economic History of Cambodia

the king and the high offi cials “a tithe of produce of the sea and soil.”

Th e many buff aloes were used for ploughing the soil “without an iron ploughshare because it is very light.”9 Potential items for trade included cotton, silk, incense, benzoin, rice and “all the lacquer which is sold across the world.” He falsely reported the “renowned” mines for silver, gold, lead, copper and tin to support his argument that colonising the kingdom would increase the revenues of the Spanish king and “enrich his vassals greatly.” Apart from this bounty, Cambodia, he argued, was “the necessary door which will open to the priceless wealth of the Kingdom of Laos.”10

Th e Spanish king, needless to say, did not add Cambodia to his empire and the fortunes of the Khmer kingdom continued to decline at the hands of its neighbours. In 1794, the srok of the northwest, Battambang and Siem Reap, were transferred to the jurisdiction of Siam.11 Th is was just the beginning of the paring of Cambodian territory. During the fi rst half of the nineteenth century, Cambodia as a sovereign state almost disappeared as a result of repeated invasions, usually at the behest of princes contesting succession to the throne and seeking support from one neighbouring country or the other. In 1811, the Th ai army invaded, sacked and burnt the capital, and during the retreat of 1813 carried off a large slice of the population. Cambodia was divided into two spheres of infl uence with the Mekong acting as the line of demarcation between the Th ai sphere in the west and the Vietnamese in the east.

Th e 1820s and 1830s were decades of Vietnamese hegemony. Unlike the Th ais who seemed intent only on territory (and the populations), the Vietnamese attempted to institutionalise their control by organising systems of tax collection and rice storage and forming a standing army, among other administrative reforms. Th ese eff orts, David Chandler notes, had little eff ect. He suggests that powerful srok offi cials responded to Vietnamese rule with “intentional incompetence” so that by the end of the 1830s there were still no records of landholdings or accurate population statistics, and the collection of rice for the army and the mobilisation of workers remained in the hands of the Khmer offi cials who, he said,

“enjoyed considerable freedom of action.”12

Th e administrative reforms may have had little impact on people’s lives, but when Vietnamese edicts touched on Khmer daily customs, such as attire and hairstyles, the people were provoked. Th e anti-Vietnamese rebellion of 1840–41 occurred “because the survival of Cambodian institutions, however disorderly, … however powerless and corrupt, were thought to be at stake.”13 In 1841, the Siamese invaded again.

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 32

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 32 6/15/10 12:06:48 PM6/15/10 12:06:48 PM

Th e Colonial Economy, 1863–1953 33

By the middle of the nineteenth century, Cambodia was literally at the mercy of its neighbours. Th e population was small and dispersed, inhabiting a territory roughly half its present size. Th e total population was probably less than 750,000. Th e chronicles from the 1840s, Chandler writes, are fi lled with references to famines, battles, refugees and epi-demics.14 Th e population was then, as now, overwhelmingly rural, and that population was concentrated in the plain to the south and east of Phnom Penh which, as Jean Delvert observed, off ered poor conditions for agriculture but was safe from the routes of invasion and retreat of foreign armies. Administratively, there were 32 srok ruled by the chaovay srok who gathered taxes in rice and mobilised manpower although only irre-gularly, on demand. Chandler notes that in theory at least, every able-bodied male owed the king three months’ service annually but, in fact, these calls for corvée were few.15

Th e majority Khmer population followed their traditional occupa-tion of rice farming and fulfi lled the roles for offi cials. Commerce, foreign trade and the riparian market gardens were the preserve of the Chinese, while the Cham fi shed and raised cattle. Compared to other states in the region, Cambodia was poor. Agricultural surpluses were uncommon, landholdings were small, yields were low, and irrigation systems were rare.

Th ere were few roads, so the villages were defenceless against bandits and rapacious offi cials.

Foreign trade was almost non-existent by 1850. Phnom Penh was eff ectively cut off from the outside world, and visitors required Vietnamese permission to reach it via the Mekong. Ports on the Gulf of Siam such as Kampot, Chandler records, were more integrated with Vietnamese and Th ai economies than with their own.16 Nevertheless, a few Japanese and Chinese ships still bore cargoes of ivory and pepper, cardamoms, hides, tortoise shells and aromatic woods from central Cambodia, although the quantities were small.

Th e French naturalist, Henri Mouhot, entered the Kingdom of Cambodia through Kampot in June 1859. His response to the Cambodian society and its ruined economy was that of a European rationalist and liberal progressive of his time. Like almost every other Western reformer since, he predicted that with good governance, investment in agriculture and proper regard for human rights, Cambodia could return to its former glory. Having seen the ruins of Angkor, he compared Cambodia unfavourably with its past:

Now, for a country to be rich and powerful, a produce relatively great and an extended commerce must be presumed. Doubtless, Cambodia was formerly thus favoured, and would be so at the present day under

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 33

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 33 6/15/10 12:06:48 PM6/15/10 12:06:48 PM

34 Economic History of Cambodia

Idyllic impressions of Cambodia at the time of naturalist Henri Mouhot’s visit in 1860

A colonial era rubber warehouse at Tonle Bet, Kompong Cham province

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 34

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 34 6/15/10 12:06:48 PM6/15/10 12:06:48 PM

Th e Colonial Economy, 1863–1953 35

a wise government, if labour and agriculture were encouraged instead of despised, if the ruling powers exercised a less absolute despotism, and, above all, if slavery were abolished — that miserable institution which is a bar to all progress, reduces man to the level of the brute, and prevents him from cultivating more than suffi cient for his own actual wants.17

He journeyed directly to Udong, the royal capital, which then had a population of around 12,000. From there, he went to Phnom Penh, the

“great bazaar of Cambodia” with a regular population of 10,000, almost all Chinese, and a fl oating, and presumably transient one of more than double that fi gure made up of Khmers and Cochinchinese who lived on their fi shing boats. He wrote, “It was the time when most of the fi shermen, returning from the Great Lake, stop at Phnom Penh to sell part of their catch, and when a crowd of small merchants fl ock there to buy cotton which is gathered in before the rains.”18 Apart from his forays overland into Stieng territory on the Mimot Plateau, Mouhot’s travels in Cambodia were largely by water or along the banks of rivers. From this perspective, he judged the soil to be generally fertile, “as fertile as Lower Cochinchina, … which yields so abundant a return for all that is put in the ground” and blamed the poor Khmer diet on the laziness of the farmer and offi cial incompetence.19

Overall, he found Cambodia’s condition to be “deplorable.” Th e population, he noted, had been seriously diminished by the incessant wars. “I do not think that the country now contains above a million of inhabitants,” he estimated, “and, according to the last census, the number of free men fi t to carry arms is returned at 30,000.”20 Th e number of Chinese was “relatively great” and there were also Malays and a fl oating population of Annamites, “amounting to two or three thousand.” Accu-rate statistics on the size of the population were not available, he noted, because calculations only indicated males fi t for active service.

Among the various products he listed (tobacco, pepper, ginger, sugar, gamboge, coff ee, silk, and cotton), he was most interested in the cotton crop which might have supplemented French needs should the American Civil War interrupt trans-Atlantic trade. On Koh Sautin, now an island district of Kompong Cham province, he found that cotton growers rented “lots” from the Crown for one pound per lot; each lot returning an income of more than 1,200 francs. He also admired the forests and their products and reported that the mountains contained gold, lead, zinc, copper and iron, “the last two in some abundance.”21 Th erefore, he wondered at the lack of exports and blamed it all on corrupt offi cials and the sloth of the farmer, although he had some sympathy for the

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 35

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 35 6/15/10 12:06:50 PM6/15/10 12:06:50 PM

36 Economic History of Cambodia

latter, noting, “Th e taxes now weigh solely on the cultivator and pro-ducer: the more he raises, the more he has to pay: disposed, therefore, to indolence by the infl uence of the climate, he has little inducement to combat this vice.”22

In 1860, during Mouhot’s travels in the region, the Khmer king died. In the internecine fi ght for succession that ensued, Siam again found leverage and Cambodia succumbed once more to their infl uence. Th e head of the Catholic mission in Cambodia, Bishop Miche, urged French intervention to restore order. Th e French, however, were more persuaded by the hope of securing access to the Mekong which, if navigable to its source, would allow French penetration of southwest China. Control over Cambodia would also prevent Vietnamese opponents to their rule from fi nding sanctuary in Cambodia. Th e French authorities concluded a protectorate treaty with King Norodom I in August 1863.

Th e expedition of the French Commission for the Exploration of the Mekong set out from Saigon in June 1866 with the aim of fi nding a route to Yunnan. Arriving in Phnom Penh, Louis de Carné, a member of that expedition, noted that the city that once boasted a population of 50,000 had been reduced to about one-tenth of that size, while the total population, in his estimation, was barely one million, including 40,000 slaves and 20,000 “savages.” Like Mouhot, de Carné was intrigued by the condition of Cambodian slaves: those for debt, those of the king, and the slaves of the pagoda. True slavery, he decided, “slavery simply from being basely carried off , with no deliverance but by death or escape,” was only that infl icted on the “savages,” that is, members of the indigenous populations of the highlands. In Phnom Penh they brought 800 francs but their value fl uctuated, “like that of other things, according to the law of supply and demand.”23

Th e expedition proceeded up the Tonle Sap river to Kompong Luong where the French resident lived “with his gunboat moored close to his house, near enough to the king to direct and watch him.”24 On the Great Lake, de Carné saw thousands of Vietnamese fi shing boats, their loads deep with the fi sh they had taken. Such was the value of the catch, he wrote, that the Vietnamese sometimes gave one hundred per cent for money borrowed to buy the salt needed to preserve it. “Th e legal interest in Cambodia is from forty to one hundred per cent a year!” he wrote in astonishment.25

Like Mouhot, de Carné’s impression of Cambodian agriculture was formed by what he saw from his vantage point on the Mekong. He saw large quantities of maize and cotton, and like Mouhot, singled out cotton for special mention. “Th e island of Koh Sautin yields, by itself, an annual

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 36

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 36 6/15/10 12:06:51 PM6/15/10 12:06:51 PM

Th e Colonial Economy, 1863–1953 37

revenue of 15,000 francs to the king’s mother, and this represents hardly a tenth of the value of the total production,” he noted.26

At Kratie, the expedition exchanged their steamer for canoes and regarded this as their true point of departure. Th is really was the Cam-bodian frontier. Th e adjoining province of Stung Treng had been lost in the eighteenth century and, as de Carné recorded, the provincial town of Stung Treng was “the fi rst village of Laos.” Th e navigation diffi culties began almost immediately. With eloquent resignation, he admitted:

Th e truth began, at last, to force itself on the most sanguine among us.

Steamers can never plough the Mekong, as they do the Amazon or the Mississippi; and Saigon can never be united to the western provinces of China by this immense river-way, whose waters make it so mighty, but which seems, after all, to be a work unfi nished.27

Th e French ambition of “establishing a dominion in the eastern peninsula of Asia that would go far to rival in wealth and power the empire which the British have founded in Hindustan” was dashed by the fi ndings of the commission. Unlike the Ganges which had led the British “to wide, rich, and populous countries in the interior,” the Mekong instead “conducted the weary travellers within the jaws of unsoundable gorges, overhung by Alpine precipices … or loses itself in a labyrinth of islets, of weeds, and of trees rising from the bosom of the waters.”28 Th e Cambodian Protectorate was, nevertheless, a fait accompli and with dogged optimism, the French committed themselves to the task of amelioration:

Cambodia is a country of magnifi cent natural resources, and has a noble river — the Mekong — fl owing through its midst. It produces dye-woods, ebony, rice, cotton, indigo, sesame, gamboge, sugar, tobacco, iron, jasmine, and wild cattle, “all in profusion, and all useless for want of enterprise and capital.” Th e French are anxious to supply these wants; and considering the position they hold, no doubt they will succeed in having their own way.29

Policies

Two over-riding principles dictated the early policy of French rule in Indochina: an unquestioning faith in progress and the moral superiority of the white race. In French colonial terms, these principles translated into mise en valeur and the mission civilisatrice. Quite literally, the new imperialism of the nineteenth century set out consciously “to modernize, develop, instruct, and civilize.”30

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 37

Chap 1 (30-72).indd 37 6/15/10 12:06:51 PM6/15/10 12:06:51 PM

38 Economic History of Cambodia

No less than the British, Edward Said notes, the French were interested in profi t, plantations and cheap labour, but in France’s empire, he adds, “One senses little equivalent of the British ‘departmental view,’

and much more the personal style of being French in a great assimila-tionist enterprise.”31 Acclaimed historian, E.J. Hobsbawm concurs, “France believed in transforming its subjects into Frenchmen, notional

and much more the personal style of being French in a great assimila-tionist enterprise.”31 Acclaimed historian, E.J. Hobsbawm concurs, “France believed in transforming its subjects into Frenchmen, notional