• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

The Case of Two Heterogeneous Countries

Im Dokument Three Essays on Education Investments (Seite 113-116)

In the previous section, I analyzed two identical countries and determined the main drivers of tuition fee differentials. In this section, in contrast, I study the case of two heterogeneous countries. More precisely, I focus on countries that offer education of different quality: I assume in the following thathi 6= hj holds and that, without loss of generality,f(ha) = ha2.14 The contribution of this section is to study the effect of education quality differences between countries on tuition fee differentials. In the following subsections, I discuss first briefly how the model is solved when countries differ in the offered education quality.

Second, I employ a numerical example to analyze how education quality affects tuition fee differentials in equilibrium.

3.4.1 Solving the Model

In principal, the solution of the model with two nonidentical countries follows the same steps as the solution for the case of two identical countries: First, one solves the labor migration decision, second, the student migration decision and third, the government’s decision problem. The result are best responses of one country to the policy choice of the other country. Using these best responses, one may solve for the policy choices in a Nash equilibrium. However, the model with two nonidentical countries cannot be analytically solved for equilibrium tuition fee differentials. I therefore use a numerical example to study the effect of differences in education quality on tuition fee differentials. Details of the solution are provided in Appendix 3.7.5.

3.4.2 Numerical Example

This subsection solves for tuition fee differentials in a Nash equilibrium using a numerical example. In the numerical example, I fix all variables besides the education quality in countryi. I then vary the value ofhiand calculate the equilibrium tuition fee differential in countryiandj. When varyinghi, changes in∆si reveal how the difference in equilibrium tuition fees is affected by the quality of education at home, while changes in ∆sj reveal how the difference in equilibrium tuition fees is affected by the quality of education abroad.

Note that this is a comparative static analysis.

14In other words, I assume that human capital production follows a concave production function: ha =

cawitha=i, j.

I choose the following values for the variables in the numerical example:

E[ms] = 0.05 ∆ms = 1

E[mg] = 0.4 ∆mg = 1 (3.9)

β = 0.3 w= 1

hj = 1 and varyhiwithin the bandwidth of

0.6≤hi ≤1.68. (3.10)

I choose the variables such that the assumptions in (A.1) are fulfilled. Furthermore, the model shall be solved by inner solutions which means that student numbers in both coun-tries are strictly between zero and one. This condition is met by imposing the bandwidth specified in (3.10).15

Given the variable choice presented above, the resulting differences in equilibrium tu-ition fees in country i andj are displayed in Figures 3.2(a) and 3.2(b). I conclude from the two figures that the equilibrium tuition fee differential is increasing in the education quality offered within the same country whereas it is decreasing in the education quality offered abroad. In other words, the country that offers better education charges relatively more to foreign students than to domestic students.

The intuition for this result is the following. Governments aim to attract students in order to maximize GDP. The expected contribution of a student to the country’s GDP de-pends on two factors: (i) the student’s human capital acquired upon graduation and (ii) the student’s probability to stay in the study location after graduation. The human capital of a student is similar across domestic and foreign students of one country because all of them receive the same quality of education and have the same abilities. The stay rate, in con-trast, differs between domestic and foreign students since foreign students are more likely to leave the study location after graduation than domestic students. Thus, there exists an advantage in attracting a native instead of a foreigner simply because the native is more likely to stay and to contribute to the country’s GDP in the future. Governments take into account this advantage when choosing tuition fees for domestic and for foreign students.

Note that the advantage of attracting a native instead of a foreigner is increasing in the hu-man capital students acquire upon graduation. As a consequence, the government prefers

15If one of the countries offers a much higher education quality than the other, all students prefer to study in this country and the model is ‘solved by a corner solution’. Imposing the bandwidth in (3.10) rules out such cases.

1 1.2 1.4 1.6 0.8

hi 0.02

0.04 0.06 0.08

∆si

−0.02

(a) in countryi

1 1.2 1.4 1.6

0.8

hi 0.02

0.04

∆sj

−0.02

−0.04

−0.06

(b) in countryj

Figure 3.2: The difference in equilibrium tuition fees for different values of education qualityhiwhenhj is constant.

to attract more domestic and less foreign students when the education quality is rising (ce-teris paribus). This goal can be achieved by lowering the tuition fee for domestic students and raising the tuition fee for foreign students. Or in other words, the reduction in the tuition fee for domestic students is financed by raising the tuition fee for foreign students.

Consequently, the tuition fee differential rises as shown in Figure 3.2(a). The other country with unchanged education quality, country j in the numerical example, just reacts to the changes in tuition fees in countryi.

The advantage of educating a native instead of a foreigner can also be determined mathematically. Let me first derive the expected contribution to the GDP of a domestic and of a foreign student in countryi:

∂GDPi

∂Sii =w∂Hi

∂Sii =whiPr[mg >(ti−tj)hiw],

∂GDPi

∂Sij =w∂Hi

∂Sij =whiPr[mg−β >(ti−tj)hiw].

Since the stay rate is higher for domestic students, i.e.,

Pr[mg >(ti−tj)hiw]>Pr[mg−β >(ti−tj)hiw]

forβ > 0, a domestic student contributes more to the future GDP than a foreign student.

The advantage of attracting and providing education to a native derives as

∂GDPi

∂Sii −∂GDPi

∂Sij =whi

β

∆mg. (3.11)

Equation (3.11) shows clearly the above discussed relationship between education quality and the advantage in attracting natives: the higher the provided quality of educationhi, the higher the advantage of attracting natives.

Equation (3.11) also provides a formal explanation for the positive effect ofβon tuition fee differentials, as discussed in the previous section. The advantage of attracting natives is increasing inβ. When the migration advantage of foreigners rises (ceteris paribus), govern-ments prefer to attract more natives and less foreigners which is achieved by raising tuition fee differentials. As a consequence, a risingβ leads to increasing tuition fee differentials.

Im Dokument Three Essays on Education Investments (Seite 113-116)