• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

5 Application: TFP Growth in the Old and New Ger- Ger-man Federal States

We now apply the two new TFP growth measures to study the source of GDP growth in the federal states of Germany after reunification. To this purpose, GDP and ”national” income account data are available beginning with 1992 for 16 states: 11 ”old” states (Bavaria, Baden-W¨urttemberg, Bremen, Hamburg, Hesse, Lower Saxony, North Rhine-Westphalia, Rhineland-Palatinate, Saarland, Schleswig-Holstein), 6 ”new” states (Berlin, Brandenburg, Mecklenburg-West Pommerania, Saxony-Anhalt, Saxony, and Thuringia).13 We employ the income and product accounts and capital stock estimates at the level of the federal states published by the Working Group for State Income and Product Accounts (Volkswirtschaftliche Gesamtrechnung der L¨ander in Stuttgart).14 This dataset allows us to revisit the findings of Burda and Hunt (2001), who assessed the widely divergent evolution of labor productivity and total factor productivity between East and West and within the two groups of states using the conventional Solow residual measure. Because the capital stock data for the new states are poor, especially for structures, the alternative DS and GD methods offer an opportunity to investigate TFP growth measurements with a ”treatment” group (East Germany) as well as a ”control” group (West Germany), where the ”treatment” is an unusually bad measurement of initial capital stocks. Reunification - both market competition and the revaluation of the east German mark - rendered about 80% of East German production noncompetitive (Akerlof, Rose, Yellen, and Hessenius (1991)), implying a large loss of value of existing equipment and structures. At the same time, many structures long carried at minimal book value were suddenly activated and employed by businesses, implying higher value of the capital stock.

In Table 5, we compare TFP growth using the Solow method and our stock-free TFP mea-surements for both the new and the old German states over two sub-periods: 1992-1997 and 1998-2003. The Solow residual estimates utilize an estimate of capital stocks provided by the state statistical agencies and the working group involved in collecting and standardizing the state income and product accounts. A constant capital share (0.33) was assumed. For the DS method, the annual rental price of capital (κ) was set to be constant over the entire period at a value of 0.0752. For the GD approach, a simple two-sided moving average of 2 years was used to estimate the trend. For both approaches, a constant rate of capital depreciation δ equal to 0.0754 was employed.

13Berlin is counted as a ”new state” consisting of the union of East and West Berlin, because the western half of Berlin, while under the protection and economic aegis of Western Germany until 1989, never enjoyed full status as aBundesland.

14The data can be downloaded at the websitehttp://www.vgrdl.de/ArbeitskreisVGR/ergebnisse.asp

Table5:TFPMeasurementinGermanFederalStates:AComparison StateSolowResidualDSGD 1992-19971998-20031992-19971998-20031992-199719 Easternstates Berlin2.60.71.7-0.40.6 Brandeburg7.32.05.70.33.4 Macklenburg-WesternPomerania6.61.24.7-0.43.4 Saxony7.82.16.20.53.3 Saxony-Anhalt7.22.05.40.53.4 Thuringia9.32.17.30.63.4 WesternStates BadenWuerttenberg2.22.11.01.50.5 Bavaria2.53.01.12.20.7 Bremen2.52.41.61.90.6 Hamburg3.01.52.01.00.8 Hessen2.61.91.51.30.6 LowerSaxony1.81.10.60.30.3 NorthRhine-Westphalia2.11.31.10.70.3 Rhineland-Palatinate1.51.20.30.40.3 Saarland1.41.60.30.80.2 Schleswig-Holstein2.41.51.30.70.6 AllGermany2.91.91.61.10.8

22

Table6:GrowthAccountingUsingtheThreeMethodsfortheperiod1992-1997:ACompa StateY Y(1−α)N NASolow ASolowKSolow KSolowADS ADSαKDS KDSAGD AGD Easternstates Berlin0.9-1.12.6-0.51.70.40.6 Brandeburg7.3-1.87.31.85.73.43.4 Macklenburg-WesternPomerania7.2-1.86.62.44.74.33.4 Saxony7.2-2.27.81.66.23.23.3 Saxony-Anhalt6.9-2.67.22.25.44.03.4 Thuringia8.3-2.99.31.97.33.93.4 WesternStates BadenWuerttenberg0.9-0.12.2-1.21.00.00.5 Bavaria1.4-0.12.5-1.01.10.40.7 Bremen0.3-0.82.5-1.41.6-0.40.6 Hamburg1.2-0.33.0-1.52.0-0.50.8 Hessen1.1-0.12.6-1.41.5-0.20.6 LowerSaxony0.80.21.8-1.20.6-0.10.3 NorthRhine-Westphalia0.5-0.22.1-1.41.1-0.40.3 Rhineland-Palatinate0.40.01.5-1.10.30.10.3 Saarland0.2-0.11.4-1.10.30.00.2 Schleswig-Holstein1.20.02.4-1.21.30.00.6 AllGermany1.5-0.52.9-0.91.60.40.8

23

Table7:GrowthAccountingUsingtheThreeMethodsfortheperiod1992-1997:AComparison StateY Y(1−α)N NASolow ASolowKSolow KSolowADS ADSαKDS KDSAGD AGD Easternstates Berlin-0.5-0.40.7-0.8-0.40.3-0.1 Brandeburg1.7-1.02.00.70.32.31.2 Macklenburg-WesternPomerania0.7-0.91.20.4-0.42.00.6 Saxony1.8-0.62.10.20.51.81.1 Saxony-Anhalt1.1-1.42.00.50.52.01.0 Thuringia1.9-0.32.10.20.61.61.1 WesternStates0.00.0 BadenWuerttenberg2.01.02.1-1.11.5-0.50.6 Bavaria3.00.93.0-0.92.2-0.11.2 Bremen1.40.12.4-1.11.9-0.60.7 Hamburg1.10.71.5-1.01.0-0.60.3 Hessen1.40.71.9-1.11.3-0.50.5 LowerSaxony1.00.91.1-1.00.3-0.20.2 NorthRhine-Westphalia1.00.91.3-1.20.7-0.60.2 Rhineland-Palatinate1.21.01.2-0.90.4-0.10.3 Saarland1.60.91.6-0.90.8-0.10.5 Schleswig-Holstein1.00.31.5-0.90.70.00.4 AllGermany1.50.61.9-0.91.1-0.10.6

24

Solow-residual type estimates. This observation holds both for the old and new German states. This implies that the cyclical fluctuations characteristic of TFP estimates - total factor productivity as measured by the Solow residual is the most important evidence invoked by the RBC school as the primary source of macroeocnomic fluctuations - are exaggerated due to fluctuations in the rate of capacity utilization. Both DS and GD methods show TFP growth to be much more stable over the two halves of the sample (1992-7 and 1998-2003). Second, the dispersion of TFP growth across the states is much less volatile in both subsets. This appears more plausible for a variety of reasons. Finally, the estimates of TFP using the DS and GD methods can be used to back out an implied contribution of capital to real growth, or, given a capital share, to growth in the true (i.e. actually utilized) capital stock. These estimates are also presented in Table 6. They show indeed a larger degree of fluctuation than that implied by official estimates of capital stock growth. They support the notion, already due to Burnside, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo (1995) and others, that the fluctuation of capital in use is an important source of measurement error and should be considered carefully when computing the solow residual. Our proposed alternatives have the advantage of shutting down this source of mismeasurement, to the extent that the utilization of the most recent investment more closely tracks the ”true” utilization rate.

6 Conclusion

Over the past half-century, the Solow residual has achieved widespread use in economics and management as a measurement of total factor productivity. Its acceptability is attributable to its simplicity and independence from statistical methods. Despite this acceptance, there has been no effort to evaluate systematically the quality of this measurement tool. This complacency is remarkable in light of potentially severe measurement problems associated with capital stock data. We have documented that the error, as measured by the root mean squared error - associated with the capital stock mismeasurement can be significant in a synthetic data set. These measurements can be characterized most generously as educated guesses of quantities for which reliable measurement or complete markets simply do not exist.

While the measurement error of the Solow residual decreases with sample size, it remains especially acute for short data sets or economies in transition. Thus, the Solow residual is least accurate in applications for which TFP measurements are most valuable. Such applications the transition to a market economy, the introduction of ICT capital in the production process, and the increasing employment of weightless assets such as advertising goodwill and research and development knowledge. (Corrado, Hulten, and Sichel (2006))

Both proposed alternatives to the Solow-Th¨ornqvist meaures can be thought of as a ”marginal-ization” of the error carried forward by the capital stock across time. Most recent investment is most likely to be properly valued at acquisition cost and to be fully utilized. Our results suggest that these methods could be applied to a number of investment context and types, thus widening the scope and appeal of applied TFP measurement.

References

Akerlof, G. A., A. K. Rose, J. L. Yellen, and H. Hessenius(1991): “East Germany in from the Cold: The Economic Aftermath of Currency Union,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 22(1991-1), 1–106.

Ambler, S., and A. Paquet (1994): “Stochastic Depreciation and the Business Cycle Puzzle,”International Economic Review, 35, 101–116.

Barro, R., and X. Sala-I-Martin (2003): “Economic Growth,” Discussion paper, MIT Press.

Barro, R. J. (1999): “Notes on Growth Accounting,” Journal of Economic Growth, 4, 119–137.

Burda, M. C., and J. Hunt (2001): “From Reunification to Economic Integration: Pro-ductivity and Labor Market in Eastern Germany,”Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 2, 1–71.

Burnside, C., M. Eichenbaum, andS. Rebelo(1995): “Capital Utilization and Returns to Scale,” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1995, ed. Ben S. Bernanke and Julio J.

Rotemberg, pp. 67–110.

Caselli, F. (2005): “Accounting for Cross-Country Income Differences,” Handbook of Eco-nomic Growth.

Christensen, L., D. Jorgenson, and L. Lau (1973): “Trasecendental Logarithmic Pro-duction Frontiers,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 55, 26-45.

Christiano, L., M. Eichenbaum, and C. Evans (2005): “Nominal Rigidities and the Dynamic Effects of a Shock to Monetary Policy,” Journal of Political Economy, pp. 1–45.

Cooley, T., and E. Prescott (1995): “Economic Growth and Business Cycles, in Fron-tiers of Business Cycle Research (ed. Thomas F. Cooley),” Princeton University Press, Princeton University Press.

Corrado, C., and J. Mattey (1997): “Capacity Utilization,” Journal of Economic Per-spectives, 11(1), 151–67.

Corrado, C. A., C. R. Hulten, and D. E. Sichel

Economic Growth,” NBER Working Papers 11948, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

Denison, E. (1962): “Source of Economic Growth in the United States and the Alternative before Us,” Committee for Economic Development.

(1972): “Some Major Issues in Productitivy Analysis: An Examination of the Estimates by Jorgenson and Griliches,” Survey of Current Business, 5(2), 1–27.

Diewert, W. E., and A. O. Nakamura(2003): “Index Number concepts, Measures and Decomposition of Productivity Growth,”Journal of Productivity Analysis, 19, 127–159.

(2007): “The Measurement of Productivity for Nations,” in Handbook of Econo-metrics, ed. by J. Heckman, and E. Leamer, vol. 6 of Handbook of Econometrics, chap. 66.

Elsevier.

F¨are, Rolf, e. a. (1989): “Productivity Developments in Swedish Hospitals: A Malmquist Output Index Approach,”Southern Illinois University at Carbondale. Department of Eco-nomics. Working Paper.

F¨are, R., S. Grosskopf, M. Norris, and Z. Zhang (1994): “Productivity Growth, Technical Progress, and Efficiency Change in Industrialized Countries,” American Eco-nomic Review, 84(1), 66–83.

Goldsmith, R. (1955): “The National Wealth of the United States in the Post-war Period,”

Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.

Gollop, F., and D. W. Jorgenson(1980): “United States Factor Productivity by Indus-try, 1947-1973,” in John W. Kendrick and Beatrice Vaccara (eds.), New Developments in Productivity Measurement and Analysis, Conference on Research in Income and Wealth, Chicago: University of Chicago Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research, 44(3).

Griliches, Z.(1980): “R&D and the Productivity Slowdown,” NBER Working Papers 0434, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.

(1996): “The Discovery of the Residual: A Historical Note,” Journal of Economic Literature, 34(3), 1324–1330.

Hall, R. E., and C. I. Jones (1999): “Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output Per Worker Than Others?,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(1), 83–116.

Hansen, G. D. (1985): “Indivisible labor and the business cycle,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 16(3), 309–327.

Harrison, S., and M. Weder(2002): “Did Sunspot Cause the Great Depression?,” Jour-nal of Economic Theory.

Hulten, C., E. Dean, and M. Harper (2001): “New Developments in Productivity Analysis (eds.),” (63).

Hulten, C. R. (1986): “Productivity change, capacity utilization, and the sources of effi-ciency growth,” Journal of Econometrics, 33(1-2), 31–50.

(1990): “The Measurement of Capital,” Fifty Years of Economic Measurement, E.R. Berndt and J.E. Triplett (eds.), Studies in Income and Wealth, The National Bureau of Economic Research, Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 54(June), 119–152.

Hulten, C. R. (1992): “Growth Accounting When Technical Change Is Embodied in Cap-ital,” American Economic Review, 82(4), 964–80.

Jacob, V., S. C. Sharma, and R. Grabowski (1997): “Capital Stock Estimates for Major Sectors and Disaggregated Manufacturing in Selected OECD Countries,” Applied Economics, 29(5), 563–79.

Jorgenson, D., and Z. Griliches (1967): “The Explanation of Productivity Change,”

Review of Economic Studies, 34, 249–283.

(1972): “Issue in Growth Accounting: A Reply to Edward F. Denison,” Survey of Current Business, 52, 65–94.

King, R. G., C. I. Plosser, and S. T. Rebelo(1988): “Production, growth and business cycles : I. The basic neoclassical model,”Journal of Monetary Economics, 21(2-3), 195–232.

King, R. S., and S. Rebelo (1999): “Resuscitating Real Business Cycles,” Handbook of Macroeconomics, edited by J. B. Taylor and M. Woodford, Volume 1B, 9271007. Amster-dam: Elsevier.

Kuznets, S.

Kydland, F. E., and E. C. Prescott (1988): “The workweek of capital and its cyclical implications,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 21(2-3), 343–360.

Maddison, A. (1992): “A Long-Run Perspective on Savings,” Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 94(2), 181–196.

Malmquist, S. (1953): “Index numbers and indifference surfaces,” Trabajos de Estadistica, 4, 209–242.

Mayes, D., and G. Young (1994): “Improving Estimates of the U.K. Capital Stock,”

National Institute Economic Review, pp. 84–96.

Mohnen, P., and T. ten Raa (2002): “Neoclassical Growth Accounting and Frontier Analysis: A Synthesis,” Journal of Productivity Analysis, 18, 111–28.

OECD (2001): “Measuring Capital, OECD Manual,” Discussion paper, OECD.

O’Mahony, M., and B. van Ark (2003): “EU Productivity and Competitiveness: An Industry Perspective Can Europe Resume the Catching-up Process?,” Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.

Prescott, E. C.(1986): “Theory ahead of business cycle measurement,”Quarterly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, pp. 9–22.

Reinsdorf, M., and M. Cover(2005): “Measurement of Capital Stocks, Consumption of Fixed Capital, and Capital Services,” .

Robinson, J. (1953): “The Production Function and the Theory of Capital,” The Review of Economic Studies.

Shephard, R. (1970): “Theory of Costs and Production Functions,”Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Sliker, B. (2007): “2007 R&D Satellite Account Methodologies: R&D Capital Stocks and Net Rates of Return,” R&d satellite account background paper, Bureau of Economic Anal-ysis/National Science Foundation.

Solow, R. M.(1957): “Technical Change and the Aggregate Production Function,”Review of Economics and Statistics,39:312-320.

Stock, J. H., and M. W. Watson (1999): “Business cycle fluctuations in us macroeco-nomic time series,”Handbook of Macroeconomics, 1, 3–64.

ten Raa, T., and V. Shestalova (2006): “Alternative Measures of Total Factor Produc-tivity Growth,” CentER Discussion Papers 54, CentER.

Th¨ornqvist, L. (1936): “The Bank of Finland’s Consumption Price Index,” Bank of Fin-land Monthly Bulletin, 10, 1-8.

Tinbergen, J. (1942): “Zur Theorie der Langfristigen Wirtschaftstsentwicklung,”

Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv, 55(1), 511–49.

Ward, M. (1976): “The Measurement of Capital. The Methodology of Capital Stock Esti-mates in OECD Countries.,” OECD Paris.

Wen, Y. (1998): “Capacity Utilization under Increasing Returns to Scale,” Journal of Eco-nomic Theory, 81(1), 7–36.

Appendix 1: The Stochastic Growth Model

First Order Conditions and Decentralized Market Equilibrium

Let λt denote the Lagrange multiplier corresponding to the periodic resource constraint (14) The first-order conditions for the household are, for t ≥0 :

Ct : λt = 1 Ct

Kt+1 : λt =βEtt+1(1−δ+Ut+1κt+1)] (23) Nt : θ(1−N¯)−ηtωt (24)

Ut: BUtχ−1t+1 (25)

First-order conditions for the firms

Nt : (1−α)At(UtKt)αNt−αt (26) Kt: αAtUtαKtα−1Nt1−αt (27) the production function

Yt=AtKtαNt−α (28) and the aggregate resource constraint (since ωtNttUt−1Kt−1 =Yt).

Kt+1 = (1−δt)Kt+Yt−Ct (29) The equilibrium of this decentralized economy is defined as the sequences of wages{ωt}, rental prices for capital {κt}, output {Yt}, consumption,{Ct}, employment {Nt}, capital stocks {Kt+1}, and the capacity utilization rate {Ut} such that the above equations hold for t ≥ 0 plus a suitable transversality condition to guarantee that the capital stock path is indeed consistent with utility maximization. The equilibrium of the problem will be, due to the first and second welfare theorems, unique and equivalent to the one chosen by a social planner with the objective of maximizing the utility of the representative household.