• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Figure 7: GDP growth, selected coefficients from models with different block lengths

3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10

Note: We report median coefficients together with 90% confidence sets conditional on inclusion from separate estimations with varying block length between three and ten years.

the coefficients on average reserve requirements and its interaction with crises must be reconciled.

There are at least four possible arguments that link the results. First, credit is measured as shares of GDP. That is, if credit growth picks up after increasing reserve requirements, this indicates that credit increases relative to GDP. Second, the correlation of credit and GDP growth may not be extremely high in normal times, as indicated by the finding that credit cycles may take three to four times as long as business cycles (Drehmann et al., 2012). That is, the pure effect of average reserve requirements on growth does not necessarily need to point in the same direction. Third and with respect to the interaction effect, there may be a timing issue after a crisis. A financial crisis may trigger a credit crunch, which lowers investment and thus leads to a strong drop in real GDP growth. To achieve long-run growth in GDP, capital deepening must take place, which may take some time and some advance credit (Kydland and Prescott, 1982). That is, we could expect credit growth to pick up earlier than GDP growth after a crisis. The development of the interaction term over time, as shown in Figures 5 and 7, points to this possibility: coefficient estimates increase as the block length increases. Fourth, we control for credit variables in the regression on GDP growth. That is, the negative effect of reserve requirements on GDP growth is on top of the effect predicted purely by credit volumes, which all turn out to be more important for GDP growth once reserve requirements and crises are included as control variables. The fact that we find negative growth effects of reserve requirements on economic growth in tranquil times is thus not only related to the credit channel, but also due to other effects that are not explicitly controlled for in the specification.19 Negative growth effects from financial repression due to the distortionary nature of changes in reserve requirements have been often predicted in the theoretical literature (see, for instance Roubini and Sala-i Martin, 1995; Basu, 2001) depending on the complementarity (or lack thereof) of private and publicly provided inputs. Effects of changes in reserve requirements on macroeconomic variables that go beyond changes in investment are also reported by

19If we include an interaction effect mean(rr) with any of the three credit volume measures, we find that the individual effect of mean(rr) on GDP growth and its interaction with credit volumes are negative. This indicates that higher reserve requirements indeed weigh negatively on growth not only via a credit channel. A regression that includes interactions of mean(rr) with all three credit volumes simultaneously is hard to interpret due to high degrees of multicollinearity in the credit volume measures.

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

Glocker and Towbin (2015), who find reactions of exchange rates and inflation. This, together with a widening of interest rate spreads (Romer, 1985) may lead to net negative effects on economic activity.

Table 3: Nonlinear effects of reserve requirements

Baseline SD(RR) Difference(RR) RR squared

variable pip mean t-stat pip mean t-stat pip mean t-stat pip mean t-stat

mean(rr) 0.543 -1.266 -1.189 0.478 -1.092 -1.144 0.473 -1.080 -1.146 0.618 1.846 0.549

crisis 0.613 0.297 1.194 0.596 0.286 1.184 0.575 0.277 1.193 0.763 0.467 1.257

mean(rr)#crisis 0.209 0.583 0.773 0.160 0.404 0.570 0.151 0.385 0.582 0.397 -5.675 -1.226

sd(rr) 0.370 -0.624 -0.386

sd(rr)#crisis 0.138 0.526 0.484

maxdiff(rr) 0.359 -0.245 -0.366

maxdiff(rr)#crisis 0.129 0.214 0.463

mean(rr)2 0.740 -9.342 -1.282

mean(rr)2#crisis 0.494 23.526 1.431

Controls YES YES YES YES

Fixed effects YES YES YES YES

Observations 306 306 306 306

Note: Columns report the posterior inclusion probability (pip), unconditional mean (mean) and t-statistic conditional on inclusion (t-stat) of the coefficients.

The database of Federico et al. (2014) not only reports average reserve requirements but also differ-entiates requirements across maturities and/or currencies of regulated deposits. Thus, it allows for us to construct and investigate additional measures of reserve requirements that may shed light on the degree of differentiation embodied in different policy strategies with respect to reserves. During crises, more differentiation should allow policymakers a more targeted response to the crisis, having a positive effect on economic growth. During normal times, increased differentiation could either be positive (due to the same targeting argument), or regulatory complexity could weigh negatively on growth. We look at the standard deviation of requirements across categories, and the difference between maximum and minimum requirements to check these hypotheses.20 We use these variables individually and – as for mean(rr) – interact them with the crisis dummy. The findings on control variables are nearly unaffected, thus we report only variables of interest in Table 3. The differentiation measures have only a minor effect on the results obtained for the parameters of our baseline variables of interest. In addition, we find that inclusion probabilities are very similar to those ofmean(rr)and its interaction with the crisis dummy. Regarding the effects of differentiation (sd(rr), maxdiff(rr)and their interactions with the crisis variable), we can confirm the hypothesis of downsides during normal times and upsides during crisis times. However, posterior inclusion probabilities and t-stats are low, and the positive interaction effect is never strong enough to fully counter the negative effect during normal times.

The fourth set of columns in Table 3 presents the model averaging results for models where the quadratic term of the reserve requirements covariate and its interaction with the crisis dummy are included as part of the pool of explanatory variables, capturing a potential nonlinear effect of average reserve requirements on economic growth. A quadratic relation could imply an “optimal level” of requirements, balancing growth against volatility. Indeed, we find that the posterior inclusion

proba-20These are, admittedly, blunt measures for the degree of regulatory differentiability, as they measure the de facto differentiation, rather than regulatory options.

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

Figure 8: Joint effect of crisis and reserve requirements: quadratic specifications

crisis mean(rr)

Note: The surface plot reports the quadratic function implied by the coefficients oncrisis, mean(rr), mean(rr)2 and their interactions. Black dots report actual observations.

bilities of these two variables are high, indicating a more complex nature of the link between economic growth and reserve requirements than that implied by linear models, and its modulation by crisis occurrence. The relationship unveiled by the data, however, does not support a simple hump-shaped link and reveals more complicated conditional correlations between these variables. The estimated partial relationship between crisis and reserve requirements (jointly) and economic growth is pre-sented in Figure 8. It reports the joint effect of individual and interaction terms and displays the actual observations on which our estimates are based. The dominating feature is a strong positive effect on growth for larger values of the crisis variable, consistent with the large positive coefficient in our estimations.21 On a more subtle note, we can see some differences when we vary the amount of reserve requirements. For low levels of the crisis occurrence variable (that is, for tranquil periods), the function is strongly hump-shaped. Moreover, the majority of observations have lower reserve require-ments than the function maximum. That is, higher reserve requirerequire-ments could have had a positive effect on growth. This finding is reassuring for the use of reserve requirements, which should provide a safeguard against crises and large economic fluctuations without affecting growth too negatively.

Apparently, this strategy works for medium levels of reserve requirements. For larger values of the crisis variable, we do not find the same hump-shaped relationship. Instead, the relationship flattens, indicating that reserve requirement levels do not affect the growth path after a long and severe finan-cial crisis. However, we must be careful about overinterpreting the results at high crisis values, as we have very few observations at such levels of the variable.

21Note that we calculate all variables as averages over five-year blocks. Thus, the crisis variable (which is binary on a yearly level) can take on the values{0,0.2,0.4,0.6,0.8,1}in the estimation.

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

Last, we account for the fact that many developing economies employed reserve requirements for monetary policy or as capital controls, rather than as macroprudential policy. As argued by Walsh (2012) in his discussion of the contribution by Glocker and Towbin (2012), reserve requirements may weigh more negatively on growth under fixed exchange rates. Higher reserve requirements increase the gap between lending and deposit rates necessary to maintain bank profitability. Thus, they should lead to higher capital outflows and currency devaluation. Under a fixed exchange rate regime (where devaluation is not an option), the central bank needs to increase its interest rate or continuously sell reserves in order to counteract the capital outflows. This interest rate tightening, in turn, has an additional negative effect on growth. We test whether we can confirm this hypothesis even in a setup with a focus on longer horizons and allowing for crises. To do so, we make use of the exchange rate arrangement classification of Ilzetzki et al. (2017). We construct two measures in addition to their coarse and fine classification schemes (where increasing index values are associated with lower degrees of exchange rate control). First, we remove all periods in which Ilzetzki et al. (2017) classify the currency as either free-falling or as a “dual market in which parallel market data are missing” (their two last categories). Second, we construct a simple dummy that is one if the fine index is equal or above the median (eight). In addition to exchange rate arrangements, we also test the interaction with the capital openness index of Chinn and Ito (2008).

Independent of the way we measure exchange rate arrangements, we cannot confirm the theoretical hypothesis.22 In all cases, increasingly fixed exchange rates (i.e., lower index values) together with higher reserve requirements tend to be followed by higher growth, as indicated by the negative coef-ficients on the interaction terms. Somewhat pointing in the opposite direction, larger capital account openness in interaction with higher reserve requirements are also good for growth. We draw from this set of results that both our results and the theoretical prediction should be taken with a grain of salt.

First, the time horizon at which predictions of the theoretical model hold is most likely shorter than in our empirical analysis. Furthermore, the theoretical model does not explicitly account for crises, which may heavily influence our estimation results. There remains a considerable number of systemic banking crises even if we exclude periods where exchange rates were freely falling.

6 Conclusion

This paper investigates the effect of reserve requirements on medium- to long-run credit and GDP growth. Adding to the previous literature on reserve requirements, we employ a large international panel study. Our Bayesian estimation framework, aimed at explicitly assessing model uncertainty and incorporating it to our estimates, provides robust evidence on the importance of reserve requirements for growth, and its effect. In terms of credit growth, previously indicated negative effects of reserve requirements seem to be short-lived. After five years, we instead find a robust positive effect of past requirements on current credit growth. In terms of GDP growth, reserve requirements have on average the expected negative effect of regulation, and although they seem to be somewhat helpful on average in mitigating the effects of a crisis, their effect is not robust to specification uncertainty in the economic growth regressions entertained. A nonlinear estimation suggests that medium levels of

22Table A.5 in the Appendix presents the results.

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

reserve requirements may in fact be optimal for medium- to long-run growth.

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

References

Abbas, S. A., Belhocine, N., El-Ganainy, A., and Horton, M. (2011). Historical patterns and dynamics of public debt – evidence from a new database. IMF Economic Review, 59(4):717–742.

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J. A. (2005). Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth.Handbook of economic growth, 1:385–472.

Aghion, P., Angeletos, G.-M., Banerjee, A., and Manova, K. (2010). Volatility and Growth: Credit Constraints and the Composition of Investment. Journal of Monetary Economics, 57(3):246–265.

Aizenman, J., Chinn, M. D., and Ito, H. (2017). Financial spillovers and macroprudential policies. NBER Working Paper 24105, NBER.

Arregui, N., Beneš, J., Krznar, I., and Mitra, S. (2013). Evaluating the Net Benefits of Macroprudential Policy: A Cookbook. IMF Working Papers 13/167.

Barro, R. J. and Lee, J. W. (2013). A new data set of educational attainment in the world, 1950–2010. Journal of development economics, 104:184–198.

Basu, P. (2001). Reserve Ratio, Seigniorage and Growth. Journal of Macroeconomics, 23(3):397 – 416.

Becker, C., Ossandon Busch, M., and Tonzer, L. (2017). Macroprudential policy and intra-group dynamics: The effects of reserve requirements in brazil. IWH Discussion Paper 21/2017.

Benigno, G., Chen, H., Otrok, C., Rebucci, A., and Young, E. R. (2013). Financial crises and macro-prudential policies.

Journal of International Economics, 89(2):453–470.

Bernanke, B. S. and Blinder, A. S. (1988). Credit, money, and aggregate demand. The American Economic Review, 78(2):435–439.

Bloom, D. E., Canning, D., Fink, G., and Finlay, J. E. (2007). Does age structure forecast economic growth? International Journal of Forecasting, 23(4):569–585.

Bordo, M. D. and Haubrich, J. G. (2017). Deep recessions, fast recoveries, and financial crises: Evidence from the american record. Economic Inquiry, 55(1):527–541.

Bordo, M. D., Meissner, C. M., and Stuckler, D. (2010). Foreign currency debt, financial crises and economic growth: A long-run view. Journal of international Money and Finance, 29(4):642–665.

Borio, C. and Shim, I. (2007). What can (macro-)prudential policy do to support monetary policy? BIS Working Papers 242, Bank for International Settlements.

Camors, C. D. and Peydro, J.-L. (2014). Macroprudential and monetary policy: loan-level evidence from reserve require-ments. Technical report, mimeo, Universitat Pompeu Fabra, Spain.

Cerra, V. and Saxena, S. C. (2008). Growth dynamics: the myth of economic recovery. American Economic Review, 98(1):439–57.

Cerutti, E., Claessens, S., and Laeven, L. (2017). The Use and Effectiveness of Macroprudential Policies: New Evidence.

Journal of Financial Stability, 28:203–224.

Chinn, M. D. and Ito, H. (2006). What matters for financial development? capital controls, institutions, and interactions.

Journal of development economics, 81(1):163–192.

Chinn, M. D. and Ito, H. (2008). A new measure of financial openness.Journal of comparative policy analysis, 10(3):309–

322.

Chipman, H. (1996). Bayesian variable selection with related predictors. Canadian Journal of Statistics, 24(1):17–36.

Crespo Cuaresma, J. (2011). How different is Africa? A comment on Masanjala and Papageorgiou (2008). Journal of Applied Econometrics, 26(6):1041–1047.

Cui, W. and George, E. I. (2008). Empirical bayes vs. fully bayes variable selection. Journal of Statistical Planning and Inference, 138(4):888–900.

Devereux, J. and Dwyer, G. P. (2016). What determines output losses after banking crises? Journal of International Money and Finance, 69:69–94.

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

Drehmann, M., Borio, C., and Tsatsaronis, K. (2012). Characterising the Financial Cycle: Don’t Lose Sight of the Medium Term! BIS Working Papers 380.

Federico, P., Vegh, C. A., and Vuletin, G. (2014). Reserve requirement policy over the business cycle. NBER Working Paper 20612, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Feinman, J. N. (1993). Reserve requirements: history, current practice, and potential reform. Federal Reserve Bulletin, 79:569.

Feldkircher, M. and Zeugner, S. (2009). Benchmark priors revisited: On adaptive shrinkage and the supermodel effect in Bayesian model averaging. IMF Working Paper WP/09/202.

Fernández, C., Ley, E., and Steel, M. F. (2001a). Benchmark priors for Bayesian model averaging. Journal of Econo-metrics, 100:381–427.

Fernández, C., Ley, E., and Steel, M. F. (2001b). Model uncertainty in cross-country growth regressions. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 16:563–576.

Forbes, K. J. (2007). One cost of the chilean capital controls: increased financial constraints for smaller traded firms.

Journal of International Economics, 71(2):294–323.

Foster, D. P. and George, E. I. (1994). The risk inflation criterion for multiple regression. The Annals of Statistics, 22(4):1947–1975.

Frankel, J. A. and Romer, D. (1999). Does trade cause growth? American Economic Review, pages 379–399.

Glocker, C. and Towbin, P. (2012). Reserve requirements for price and financial stability: When are they effective?

International Journal of Central Banking.

Glocker, C. and Towbin, P. (2015). Reserve requirements as a macroprudential instrument–empirical evidence from brazil. Journal of Macroeconomics, 44:158–176.

Gomis-Porqueras, P. (2002). Multiple reserve requirements in a monetary growth model.Economic theory, 19(4):791–810.

Gray, S. (2011). Central bank balances and reserve requirements. IMF Working Paper 11/36.

Ilzetzki, E., Reinhart, C. M., and Rogoff, K. S. (2017). Exchange arrangements entering the 21st century: Which anchor will hold? NBER Working Paper 23134, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Jeanne, O. and Korinek, A. (2013). Macroprudential regulation versus mopping up after the crash. NBER Working Paper 18675.

Kaminsky, G. L. and Reinhart, C. M. (1999). The Twin Crises: the Causes of Banking and Balance-of-Payments Problems. American Economic Review, 89(3):473–500.

Kass, R. and Wasserman, L. (1995). A reference Bayesian test for nested hypotheses and its relationship to the Schwarz criterion. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 90(431):928–934.

King, R. G. and Levine, R. (1993). Finance and growth: Schumpeter might be right.The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108(3):717–737.

Kydland, F. E. and Prescott, E. C. (1982). Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica, 50(6):1345–1370.

Laeven, L. and Valencia, F. (2013). Systemic Banking Crises Database. IMF Economic Review, 61(2):225–270.

Ley, E. and Steel, M. (2007). Jointness in Bayesian variable selection with applications to growth regression. Journal of Macroeconomics, 29(3):476–493.

Ley, E. and Steel, M. F. (2009). On the effect of prior assumptions in Bayesian model averaging with applications to growth regressions. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 24(4):651–674.

Ley, E. and Steel, M. F. (2012). Mixtures of g-priors for Bayesian model averaging with economic applications. Journal of Econometrics, 171(2):251–266.

Liang, F., Paulo, R., Molina, G., Clyde, M. A., and Berger, J. O. (2008). Mixtures of g priors for Bayesian variable selection. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 103(481):410–423.

Lindh, T. and Malmberg, B. (1999). Age structure effects and growth in the oecd, 1950–1990. Journal of Population Economics, 12(3):431–449.

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

Loungani, P. and Rush, M. (1995). The effect of changes in reserve requirements on investment and gnp. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 27(2):511–526.

Ma, C. (2018). Financial stability, growth and macroprudential policy. Mimeo, Johns Hopkins University.

Magud, N. E., Reinhart, C. M., and Rogoff, K. S. (2018). Capital Controls: Myth and Reality–A Portfolio Balance Approach. Annals of Economics and Finance, 19(1):1–47.

Marshall, M., Gurr, T., and Jaggers, K. (2016). Polity iv project. political regime characteristics and transitions, 1800–

2015. dataset users’ manual. Technical report, Center for Systemic Peace.

Masanjala, W. H. and Papageorgiou, C. (2008). Rough and lonely road to prosperity: a reexamination of the sources of growth in africa using bayesian model averaging. Journal of Applied Econometrics, 23(5):671–682.

Mendoza, M. E. G. and Bianchi, J. (2011). Overborrowing, financial crises and ’macro-prudential’ policy? IMF Working Paper 11/24.

Montoro, C. and Moreno, R. (2011). The use of reserve requirements as a policy instrument in latin america.

Moral-Benito, E. (2012). Determinants of Economic Growth: a Bayesian Panel Data Approach. Review of Economics and Statistics, 94(2):566–579.

Raftery, A. E. (1995). Bayesian model selection in social research. Sociological Methodology, 25:111–163.

Ramey, G. and Ramey, V. A. (1995). Cross-Country Evidence on the Link Between Volatility and Growth. American Economic Review, 85(5):1138–1151.

Rancière, R., Tornell, A., and Westermann, F. (2008). Systemic Crises and Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(1):359–406.

Reinhart, C. M. and Reinhart, V. R. (1999). On the use of reserve requirements in dealing with capital flow problems.

International Journal of Finance & Economics, 4(1):27–54.

Reinhart, C. M. and Rogoff, K. S. (2009).This time is different: Eight centuries of financial folly. Princeton University Press.

Reinhart, C. M. and Rogoff, K. S. (2014). Recovery from financial crises: Evidence from 100 episodes. The American Economic Review, 104(5):50–55.

Richter, B., Schularick, M., and Shim, I. (2018). The Costs of Macroprudential Policy. Working paper.

Robitaille, P. et al. (2011). Liquidity and reserve requirements in brazil. International Finance Discussion Papers 1021.

Romer, D. (1985). Financial Intermediation, Reserve Requirements, and Inside Money: A General Equilibrium Analysis.

Journal of Monetary Economics, 16(2):175–194.

Roubini, N. and Sala-i Martin, X. (1995). A Growth Model of Inflation, Tax Evasion, and Financial Repression.Journal of Monetary Economics, 35(2):275–301.

Sala-i-Martin, X., Doppelhofer, G., and Miller, R. I. (2004). Determinants of long-term growth: A Bayesian averaging of classical estimates (BACE) approach. American Economic Review, 94(4):813–835.

Schoenmaker, D. (2014). Macroprudentialism: A VoxEU. org EBook. CEPR press.

Schwarz, G. (1978). Estimating the dimension of a model. The Annals of Statistics, 6(2):461–464.

Tovar, C. E., Garcia-Escribano, M., and Martin, M. V. (2012). Credit growth and the effectiveness of reserve requirements and other macroprudential instruments in latin america. IMF Working Paper 12/142.

Vargas, H. et al. (2011). Monetary policy and the exchange rate in colombia. BIS background papers, page 129.

Walsh, C. E. (2012). Discussion of “reserve requirements for price and financial stability: when are they effective?”.

International Journal of Central Banking, 8(1):115–126.

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

Appendix

ACCEPTED MANUSCRIPT

Table A.1: Variable sources and description

Variable Name Source Description

crisis Laeven and Valencia (2013) Dummy for systemic banking crisis

reserve requirements Federico et al. (2014) Level of reserve requirements, potentially differenti-ated across currencies and maturities of deposits gdp growth/capita World Bank WDI GDP/capita growth (annual %)

credit by financial sector World Bank WDI Domestic Credit Provided By Financial Sector (%GDP)

bank credit to private sector World Bank WDI Domestic Credit To Private Sector By Banks (%GDP)

credit to private sector World Bank WDI Domestic Credit To Private Sector (%GDP)

gdp/capita IMF World Economic

Out-look Gross Domestic Product Per Capita, Current Prices investment/gdp World Bank WDI Gross Capital Formation (%GDP)

household consumption World Bank WDI Household Final Consumption Expenditure (%GDP) govt. consumption World Bank WDI General government final consumption expenditure

(%GDP)

govt. debt (Abbas et al., 2011) Govt. Debt (%GDP) from the Historical Public Debt Database, updated yearly

inflation, cpi World Bank WDI Inflation, CPI (annual %)

inflation, gdp deflator World Bank WDI Inflation, GDP deflator (annual %)

inflation, gdp deflator World Bank WDI Inflation, GDP deflator (annual %)

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE