• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Background and Requirements for the SOVAM: Soviet Agricultural Model

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Background and Requirements for the SOVAM: Soviet Agricultural Model"

Copied!
25
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

NOT FOR QUOTATION WITHOUT PERMISSION OF THE AUTHOR

BACKGROUND AND

REQ- FOR THE

SOVAM: SOWET AGRICULTURAL MODEL

Vladimir N. Iakimets

November 1984

WP-84-97

Working Rzpers a r e interim reports on work of t h e International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis and have received only limited review. Views o r opinions expressed herein do not necessarily represent those of t h e Institute or of its National Member Organizations.

INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTE FOR APPLIED SYSTEMS ANALYSIS 2361 Laxenburg, Austria

(2)

Understanding the n a t u r e and dimensions of the world food problem and the policies available to alleviate i t has been the focal point of the IIASA Food and Agriculture Program since it began in 1977.

National food systems a r e highly interdependent, and yet the major policy options exist a t the national level. Therefore, to explore these options, i t is necessary both to develop policy models for national economies and to link them together by trade and capital transfers. For greater realism the models in this scheme a r e kept descriptive, rather than normative.

Over the years models of some twenty countries, which together account for nearly 80 percent of important. agriculural attributes such as area, production, population, exports, imports and so on, have been linked together to constitute what we call the basic linked system (BLS) of national models. One of t h e models is a model of the European member countries of the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (CMEA) treated as one nation.

For analyzing a number of policy issues of interest to these coun- tries we need to develop detailed national models for the

CMEA

countries.

A model for Hungary is already developed and work is in progress for the development of models of Bulgaria, CSSR, Poland and the USSR

-

with the help of collaborating groups in these countries.

Afirs't s t e p in t h e development of t h e agricultural model of t h e USSR was a review of t h e background for t h e development of agriculture in the USSR and a n assessment of t h e requirements t h a t a model useful for pol- icy analysis should meet.

Dr. Vladimir Iakimets presents here such a review and assessment.

Kirit S . Parikh Program Leader Food and Agriculture Program.

(3)

It is obvious t h a t t h e initial s t e p s of any model construction a r e t h e m o s t difficult ones and background and conceptual framework for t h e

SOVAM

such as described in t h i s paper cannot be prepared without substantial assistance a n d fruitful discussions. The a u t h o r would like to express his thanks t o all people who have helped him. First of all Academician

V.I.

Nazarenko, who r e a d t h i s paper and m a d e a lot of i m p o r t a n t notes. Dis- cussions with Prof. V. Fedorov helped t h e a u t h o r t o m a k e a c c u r a t e m a i n assumptions of t h e

SOVAM

construction. Notes m a d e by Prof. K. Parikh, Prof. F. Rabar, Prof. C. Csaki a n d Dr. M. Keyzer were very helpful.

The a u t h o r wishes t o t h a n k Cynthia Enzlberger for typing a n d Linda Dresh for editing first versions of this paper.

(4)

1. Introduction

2. Common requirements of national agricultural policy models 3. Specific requirements for t h e SOVAU and its conceptual framework

3.1 General indexes

3.2 Natural conditions and weather factor 3.3 Capital investments

3.4 Fertilizer production a n d application 3.5 Land resources and t h e i r distribution 3.6 Labour resources

3.7 Specific requirements of t h e SOVAM

3.8 Main assumptions for t h e SOVAM construction 4. Summary

References

-

vii

-

(5)

BACKGROUND

AND

REQU-

FOR THE

W A Y [ :

SOVIEI' AGRICULTURAL, MODEL

1. Introduction

The development of a set of linkable national models for agricultural policy analysis begun at IIASA, in 1977 within the framework of t h e Food and Agricul- ture Program (FAP) in collaboration with a network of institutions from different countries and international organizations. The main purpose of this work from the beginning was to create a tool for studying the effects of a country's governmental policy measures on the national and international food and agriculture situation and inverse effects of other countries governmental decision and measures undertaken by international organizations on the domestic food situation in each country. For a more detailed description of the FAP objectives, see for example (K. Parikh and F. Rabar (eds), 1981;

K.

Parikh,

1981,

M.

Keyzer 1980, G. Fischer a n d K. Frohberg, 1980).

The c u r r e n t s t a t e of the a r t of the FAP activity can briefly be evaluated as follows:

-

t h e methodology for the construction of national models with a common structure was created;

-

t h e approach for linkage of these models on t h e basis of the general theory of economic equilibrium was developed;

-

t h e software for implementation of calculations was originally developed;

-

t h e simplified and some detailed versions of national models and models of groups of countries were developed by t h e FAP and the network of colla- borating organizations;

-

t h e development of reference and some policy scenarios was made;

-

a number of runs for study of trade liberalization scenarios with the help of created system of models was made.

The aims of this paper are:

-

t o characterize the common requirements that a national agricultural pol- icy model should meet so t h a t it may be linked t o other national models used a t IIASA

-

to give a short description of the c u r r e n t s t a t e of Soviet agriculture and tendencies in its development, and

(6)

-

to determine the specific requirements for t h e Soviet Agricultural Model

(SOVAM)

from t h e point of view of their correspondence to t h e main direc- tions of t h e country's agro-food complex development and to outline the conceptual framework for t h e

SOVAhf.

2. Common requirements of national agricultural policy models

In order to organize t h e interaction of different countries agricultural pol- icy models these must m e e t several general requirements. Each national pol- icy model has t o reflect, by definition, the specifics of t h e country's food and agricultural system a n d their own government's measures. Furthermore, some common requirements generated mainly by a general equilibrium approach which had been accepted and adopted for the global linkage a r e imposed on each national model.

These requirements a r e t h e following:

(1) The national models commodity list must be t h e same as t h a t of IIASk I t m e a n s t h a t t h e national statistics on t h e wider list of commodities must be transformed from t h e initial data to the aggregated one in order to m e e t t h e classification of t h e FAP commodity list. The implementation of this requirement leads t o t h e execution of enough hard work t o prepare the aggregate tiles. The main steps of this work have to follow t h e aggregation procedure developed by G. Fischer and U. Sichra, 1983. It should be noted however t h a t each country's modelling team can use a wider list of com- modities than t h e r e is in the FAP commodity list. A wider list may be required for example in order to reflect the specifics of the country's agri- cultural sector. But in t h a t case it is necessary to develop a number of additional procedures to aggregate and disaggregate t h e commodity list, because each model participates in international exchange within a frame- work of the global linkage with t h e same commodity list.

(2) Each national model must work within a 15-20 years time horizon a n d the time increment is one year. This requirement means t h a t each model m u s t describe the long-range perspective of t h e agricultural sector's development and each year's changes in the domestic production, con- sumption and government measures should interact within t h e accepted approach. It should be pointed out also that t h e requirement of a common time increment h a s to be accepted in order to meet t h e condition of t h e equilibrium world price calculations.

(3) It is also assumed t h a t agricultural production is given a t t h e time point for exchange. In o t h e r words it means that a t t h e time of making the pro- duction decisions information is available from the exchange of previous years only and t h a t during exchange these production decisions, and hence supply, cannot be revised This requirement is determined mainly in order to reduce t h e computational complexities and provide t h e flexibil- ity in each model's supply module conceptualization.

(4) Each country's agricultural policy model has t o be closed. I t means t h a t t h e behaviour of t h e whole economy must be described. For t h e sake of simplicity this requirement led to t h e representation of t h e r e s t of t h e economy of each country with t h e help of one aggregated commodity. For instance, t h e r e s t of the ecoriomy may be modelled by a Cobb-Douglas pro- duction function but need not be so modelled.

(7)

(5) A very important requirement for the national model is that the country's governmental decisions influencing the agricultural sector's development and the trade in food and agricultural commodities m u s t be explicitly for- mulated. It means t h a t the policy module of each national model must describe a t least two types of governmental decisions: concerned with internal production and exchange of commodities both domestically and internationally.

(6) Net export of each commodity must be a function of world market prices.

The country's n e t excess demand function for each commodity has to be homogeneous of degree zero in world market prices and its trade deficit.

Thus inflation, which affects all prices by the same proportion, has no impact on the net exports of the country.

All abovementioned requirements imposed on the national model must naturally be adjusted to the specifics of the country's economy.

3. Specific requirements for the

SDVAM

and its conceptual framework

It is clear t h a t apart from all the abovementioned general requirements, national agricultural models have to meet a number of special requirements in order to reflect the peculiarity of the country's agro-food sector, its potential and tendencies for development.

This section is devoted to the description of t h e c u r r e n t state and main directions of development of Soviet agriculture. On t h e basis of such a descrip- tion some conceptual points for t h e SOVAM construction are formulated and specific requirements which have to be met are identified and how they will be met are outlined.

3.1. General Indexes

In accordance with the decisions of the 26th CPSU Congress the USSR Food Program was elaborated and adapted in May 1982. The period of this program ends in 1990.

The main objectives of the Food Program are:

-

to raise the standard of living of the agricultural workers and to improve living and working conditions in the countryside;

-

to ensure a stable supply of the various types of foodstuffs for t h e country's population and agricultural raw materials for industry;

.

-

t o increase t h e consumption of high-quality food commodities on the basis of scientifically determined norms.

These goals are formulated in order to implement t h e strategic plans for t h e further growth of the national economy. Success in accomplishing the tasks of USSR social and economic development is currently dependent on accelerating the rates of development of the country's agro-industrial sector.

To attain these objectives the following directions were determined:

-

proportional and balanced development of t h e USSR agro-industrial com- plex, improvement of management, planning and economic stimulation in all its branches with maximal orientation of production for t h e attainment of a high final result;

-

provision of high growth rates of agricultural production on the basis of step-by-step intensification, effective utilization of land, every kind of strengthening of the material and technical basis, speeded up introduction of advanced methods of work and scientific achievements;

(8)

-

every kind of improvement in t h e utilization of industrial and technical potentials of t h e agro-industrial complex, considerable increases in r e t u r n s from capital i n v e s t m e n t s a n d m a t e r i a l resources, development of specialization a n d concentration of production on t h e basis of a broadening cooperation of different branches;

-

reduction of losses a n d increase of quality of agricultural commodities on t h e basis of wide application of progressive agricultural technologies and technologies of processing a n d storage of products;

-

f u r t h e r improvement of living conditions i n t h e country-side.

The Soviet Union has achieved m u c h in t h e development of its industrial output. If we compare t h e growth of o u t p u t in t h e key industries yearly since 1940, t h e n we can observe t h e s e achievements (Table 1).

Table 1. Growth of output in basic industries (1940

=

1)

% a n n u a l growth r a t e

Total industrial o u t p u t Power industry

Fuel industry Ferrous metalurgy Chemical and

petrochemical industry Machine building

a n d m e t a l working Light industry Food industry

Source: The USSR economy in 1980, pp. 37, 126

Comparative e s t i m a t i o n s of s u c h main indices of t h e

USSR

economic development such a s national income, industrial a n d agricultural output, pro- duction of producer a n d c o n s u m e r goods, a n d labour productivity for t h e period 1940-1980 a r e given in Table 2.

Over t h e past twenty years, t h e living s t a n d a r d of t h e Soviet people have significantly improved. The average m o n t h l y earnings of workers have more t h a n doubled between 1960 a n d 1980 in t h e

USSR.

There have also been i n c r e a s e s in various p a y m e n t s and benefits from t h e social consumption funds a n d increases in pensions. This had l e a d t o increasing demands by t h e Soviet people. For example, from 1965 t o 1980 t h e p e r capita consumption of m e a t a n d m e a t products went u p by 41 p e r c e n t , milk by 25 percent, vegetables by 35 p e r c e n t , a n d eggs by almost 100 p e r c e n t (P. Paskar, 1983, p.6). The population grew by 35 million in t h e s a m e period.

Soviet agriculture for this period m a d e considerable progress (see Table 3).

For instance, t h e average annual production of g r a i n rose from 130.3 million t o n s in t h e 7th five-year plan period t o 205 million tons in t h e 10th period (1976-1980).

(9)

Table 2. Development of the national economy (1940

=

1)

National i n c o m e 1 4.4 6.0 8.7 11.4 14.1 3.20

Industrial o u t p u t 1 5.2 7.9 12 17 2 1 4.04

Producer's goods 1 6.6 11 16 23 29 4.39

Consumer goods 1 3.2 4.4 6.5 9.0 11 3.44

Labour productivity 1 4.0 5.3 7.4 9.2 10.8 2.70

Agricultural o u t p u t 1 1.6 1.8 2.2 2.3 2.4 1.50 Source: The USSR economy in 1980, pp.37-38

Table 3. Dynamics of the Soviet Agricultural Output

Indexes

7th five- 8 t h five- 9 t h five- 10th five- y e a r period year period y e a r period year period

1961-1965 1966-1970 1971-1975 1976-1980 a n n u a l average

1. Gross f a r m output

(in comparable 1973 prices) 1,000 million roubles

2. grain (mill. tons) 3. raw cotton (mill. tons) 4. sugar b e e t (mill. tons) 5. vegetables (mill. tons) 6. m e a t (slaughter weight) (mill. tons) 7. milk, (mill. tons) 8. eggs, 1000 million

Source: The USSR economy for t h e period 1922-1982, p. 227

Despite t h e s e facts t h e steadily increasing demands of t h e Soviet people require f u r t h e r growth i n agricultural o u t p u t and f u r t h e r improvement in t h e s t r u c - t u r e of t h e i r diet.

It should be noted t h a t growth r a t e s of agricultural output in t h e Soviet Union could be higher. However in t h e first post-war decade t h e main efforts were devoted t o t h e large scale rehabilitation work.

At p r e s e n t Soviet agriculture is a highly intensive s e c t o r of t h e economy.

As was s e e n in Table 3, agricultural output h a s been boosted over t h e p a s t 20 years. The high r a t e of intensification in Soviet a g r i c u l t u r e i s due t o sizeable capital investments. The scale and pace of intensification are d e t e r m i n e d by

(10)

t h e agricultural enterprises i n collaboration with Government. For these years a system of s t a t e measures for stimulation of agricultural production was created in order to help the farms in t h e intensive development of cropping and stock breeding. The high r a t e of intensification in USSR agriculture is illus- t r a t e d in Table 4.

Table 4. Intensification of the

USSR

Agriculture (1940

=

1)

Indexes 1940 1965 1970 1975 1980

1. Area under crops 1 1.39 1.37 1.45 1.44

2. Value of agricultural production assets including livestock ( a t the end of year)

--total 1 4.59 6.61 10.87 15.81

-for 100 h a of farmland 1 4.08 5.85 9.56 13.81

3. Gross farm output 1 1.8 2.2 2.3 2.4

Source: The USSR economy in 1980, pp. 37, 212, 224

As can be seen from Table 4, the sown areas for this period increased by 40 percent and total gross farrn output by 140 percent. To ensure f u r t h e r accelerated intensification of agriculture during the 1980s, the Soviet s t a t e will continues to concentrate funds and resources in order to tackle t h e problems arising from t h e targeted growth of agricultural production. Within the frame- work of t h e agro-industrial complex, the problem of further intensification is formulated in order t o increase crop yields and livestock productivity and intensify the utilization of input resources (labour, capital, fertilizers and so on) t o improve t h e diet s t r u c t u r e of Soviet people, etc.

It was stressed a t t h e CPSLT Central Committee's plenary meeting in May 1982 t h a t adopting this Food Program h a s both economic and political significance. According t o this program in t h e 12th five-year plan period (1986- 1990) t h e s t a t e shall allocate, for the national agro-industrial complex, capital investments amounting t o 33-35 percent of the total capital investments in t h e national economy (and including 27-28 percent of the total for agriculture).

The diet of the Soviet people is quite sufficient now in t e r m s of calories.

The diet p a t t e r n has improved considerably over the period from 1950 to 1980.

These changes in t h e per capita consumption of foodstuffs are given in Table 5.

(11)

Table 5.

Per

capita

annual

consumption of foodst&

(in

kg)

1950 1965 1970 1975 1980 1990.

(planned figures) Meat and m e a t products

(including animal fats

a n d bypr oduc ts) 26

Milk and dairy products

(in t e r m s of milk) 172

Eggs (pieces) 60

Fish and fish products 7

Vegetable oil 2.7

Potatoes 24 1

Vegetables and melons 5 1

Fruits and berries 1 1

Breads and cereal products 172 Sugar***

Source: N.

A

Tikhonov, p. 180

*

The USSR economy for t h e period 1922-1982, p. 73

** K.

Bogolyubov, p. 113

***

The USSR economy in 1980, p. 405

The data in Table 5 shows u s t h a t t h e consumption of high-quality protein rich food products has been increasing for t h e period under consideration. The last column of this table contains t h e d a t a for the desired level of the per cap- i t a consumption of these foodstuffs, determined in the USSR Food Program.

The problem is t o improve t h e s t r u c t u r e of t h e diet, particularly t o increase t h e s h a r e of m e a t , milk and vegetables in it.

At present bread a n d cereals satisfy 30 to 50 percent of man's energy requirements, 30 to 40 percent requirements in protein, 50 to 60 percent in vitamin

B

and up to 80 percent in vitamin

E.

(P. Paskar, p.14) The aim of t h e Food Program i s t o improve t h e diet by increasing t h e share of protein con- sumption. According to t h e Food Program t h e per capita consumption of stable foodstuffs will be: m e a t and m e a t products

-

70 kg, fish products

-

19 kg, milk and dairy products

-

330 -340 kg, eggs

-

260-266 units, vegetable oil

-

13.2 kg, vegetables a n d melons

-

126-135 kg. fruit a n d berries

-

66-70 kg, potatoes

-

110

kg, sugar - 45.5 kg and bread and bakery products

-

135 kg.

According t o t h e Food Program t h e functioning of the whole agro-industrial complex in the country needs to be improved. In order to achieve this i t will be necessary t o implement corresponding changes and establish a new correlation of intersectoral ties, because now a n imbalance exists in development r a t e s among the branches of industry which a r e connected with agriculture: t r a n - sport, processing, services and so on. Implementation of these tasks should lead eventually to qualitative changes in t h e national economy and t o the crea- tion of new economic mechanisms.

During t h e c u r r e n t and t h e next five-year plan period, t h e question of investment efficiency, increases in t h e agricultural productivity of soil

(12)

utilization, production capacities in agriculture, labour, and material resources, b e t t e r coordination of links between agriculture a n d o t h e r branches of agro-industrial complex m u s t be addressed

The main goals for t h e n e x t decade are:

a increase labour productivity 1.5 times

increase agricultural output p e r hectare by 30 p e r c e n t

reduce considerably t h e expenditure of resources p e r unit of agricultural output

reduce losses of all types of agricultural products (for example by improv- ing t h e protein balance in feed).

reduce expenditures of feed p e r unit of livestock output 5-7% in 1990 com- pared to 1980.

increase r e t u r n on m i n e r a l fertilizers by 12 - 15% through rational alloca- tion and utilization.

It is clear t h a t t h e s e main directions a n d tendencies for t h e future development of t h e USSR agrofood complex determined in t h e Food Program have t o be taken i n t o a c c o u n t during t h e SOVAM construction.

3.2.

Natural

conditions and weather factor

The n a t u r a l conditions a r e not very favourable for agricultural activity in t h e Soviet Union. More t h a n 60 percent of the farmland lies in too dry o r too moist areas. (For comparison this figure is only 1% in t h e USA). Only 1.1 per- c e n t of t h e plowland in t h e USSR lies in zones with 700 m m annual precipitation level (this level provides favourable conditions for g u a r a n t e e d big harvests). For comparison in t h e USA 60 percent of plowland lies in such favourable zones (N.k Tikhonov). In addition m o r e than 50 percent of t h e total plowland of t h e USSR (- 100 million ha) a r e poor in phosphorus.

The weather is a very important factor influencing t h e agricultural o u t p u t in the USSR. Vast damage is caused to agriculture by droughts which periodi- cally hit main agricultural regions. The analytical d a t a of climatic conditions on t h e t e r r i t o r y of t h e USSR given by Yu. k Izrael (On m e a s u r e s for t h e country's Food Program implementation, Planovoe Khozyaystwo, V.4. 1983) is given in Table 6.

Table 6. Data on the droughts

Type of droughts Decrease i n grain Occurence of Years yields i n % droughts, 1 t i m e

extraordinary 30-40 in 100 years 1975

extreme 20-30 in 10-15 years 1963,1965,1981

severe 10-20 in 5 - 7 y e a r s 1954, 1955, 1957, 1967 1972, 1973, 1980

moderate 5-7 in 4 years 1951, 1964, 1969

1974, 1982

(13)

The grain o u t p u t of t h e Soviet Union strongly depends on weather condi- tions. In Table 7 o n e c a n see t h e yearly variability in t h e range of outputs of grain crops. Taking into account t h a t t h e total acreage for t h e period under consideration h a d slight changes we can s a y t h a t approximately t h e s a m e vari- ability in grain yield h a d occurred. I t should be noted, however, t h a t due t o intensification of agricultural production t h e g e n e r a l tendency to t h e grain output growth is observed. The huge capital investment planned for agricul- t u r e will also be o r i e n t e d towards t h e development of new agricultural techno- logies to r e d u c e t h e dependency of o u t p u t on weather conditions.

Table 7 . Dimensions of variability of crop production

Grain Output. mill. t o n s Variability ampli tude 15ve year i n average m a x min max-min, in percent

period a n n u a l mill. t to average

Source: J. Yakunin, p. 69.

I t is evident t h a t t h e specific c h a r a c t e r n a t u r a l conditions of t h e

USSR

and the weather f a c t o r have to be reflected within t h e framework of the SOVAM.

3.3.

Capital

Investment

The next. i m p o r t a n t Feature of t h e SOVAM is i t s capacity for considering governmental decisions determining t h e different variants of transformations in capital i n v e s t m e n t s , acreage distribution, fertilizer application and so on.

Let u s d e s c r i b e briefly t h e r e c e n t situation with t h e main input resources listed above in o r d e r t o understand what kind of decisions we n e e d for improve- m e n t of t h e r e s o u r c e utilization.

For t h e l a s t 15 y e a r s t h e Soviet s t a t e implemented essential redistribution of resources a n d capital investments in favour of agriculture. In

N.A

Tikhonov t h e following Q u r e s a r e given: between 1918 and 1982 investments in agricul- t u r e made u p 565.000 million roubles. More t h a n 00 percent of i t (458.000 mil- lion roubles) were s p e n t between 1966-1982. For t h i s period ( t h r e e last five- years) t h e m a i n fixed capital and m a t e r i a l circulating capital in agriculture were increased by a factor of 2.5. I t provided for a n increase i n agricultural output O F 7.7 t i m e s in spite of unfavourable weather conditions in several years during t h i s period. Up t o t h e beginning of t h e r e c e n t five-year period t h e capi- tal Axed for a g r i c u l t u r a l equaled 217.000 million rubles. I t should be n o t e d t h a t these i n v e s t m e n t s were of a long-range n a t u r e . They were connected with expenditures for increasing fixed capital (buildings, machinery, productive livestock a n d s o on). Such s t r a t e g y in capital investment provided essential strengthening of t h e m a t e r i a l base of Soviet agriculture.

For example, before 1980 virtually h l l provision for housing of livestock was achieved. The previous capital i n v e s t m e n t s s t r u c t u r e could b e described as

(14)

extensive. To increase r e t u r n s on capital investments, i t has been suggested to increase part of t h e circulating capital (seeds, fertilizers, pesticides, feed a n d so on).

According t o N. Borchenko, (p. 36) t h e bases for increasing t h e growth r a t e s of agricultural output is t o improve t h e utilization of circulating capital under moderate growth rates of fixed capital, stabilization of acreage and slight increases in t h e livestock population. In the above cited paper it i s noted t h a t during t h e period of t h e Food Program, considerable changes will be made within t h e framework of production. The part of capital investments directed t o soil improvement will be increased, t h e crop production output (mainly feed output) and livestock production output will be increased and storage facilities will be improved. Improving t h e safety of products, enlargement of facilities for t r e a t m e n t a n d packing of food commodities etc, will be a major concern. For t h e 11th five-year period (1981-85) 190,000 million roubles will be provided for t h e development of agriculture. And t h e s t r u c t u r e of these investments is different compared to t h a t for t h e previous five-year period. Let us note t h a t almost t h e same amount (190,000 million roubles a t constant prices) was spent in t h e agricultural sector between 1918 and 1970.

The r e c e n t strategy and future tendencies in capital investments for USSR agriculture have to be reflected by corresponding means within the framework of t h e SOVAM (for example by different scenarios).

3.4. Fertilizer production and application

One of t h e more important input resources i n crop production i s fertilizer.

I t

is estimated by agricultural scientists t h a t 50 percent of crop yield increase is provided by mineral fertilizer application (N.G. Peshev, p. 6). For comparison (I. Chrulev, 1972) specific weight of meteorological factors is estimated to be 15 percent, hybrid seeds

-

8 percent and irrigation - 5 percent. Then according t o t h e Food Program one of t h e main factors for the intensification of t h e agricul- tural production is t h e f u r t h e r development of utilization of chemicals. For t h e period from 1965 to 1980, in t h e USSR t h e r e was a rapid growth in mineral fertilizer deliveries to farms. The figures a r e t h e following: deliveries of mineral fertilizers from 6.3 million tons (in t e r m s of 100 percent. content of n u t r i e n t s ) in 1965 increased to 18.8 million tons in 1980 (3.3 times); deliveries of feed chemical additives from 16 thousand tons to 520 thousand tons (32 times) and farm chemicals from 350 t o 658 thousand tons (1.9 times).

Organic fertilizer application for this period increased 2.2 times h-om 359.2 million tons in 1965 t o 803 million tons in 1980.

In 1980 t h e average per hectare fertilizer application in the USSR was 76 kg (in t e r m s of nutrients) including 51 kg for grain, 215 kg for corn, 417 kg for cot- ton, 438 kg for sugar beets, 190 kg for flax, 59 kg for sunflower, 294 kg for veget- ables, 274 kg f.or potatoes, and 63 kg for feed crops, (0. Sokolov, p. 111). In t h e s a m e year t h e average per hectare organic fertilizer application was equal to 3.9 tons including 2.1 tons for grain crops, 7.5 tons for cotton, 20 tons for sugar beets, 22.8 tons for vegetables, 46.1 tons for potatoes and 3.7 tons for feed crops (0. Sokolov, p. 11 1).

Today t h e Soviet Union takes t h e first place in t h e world in total mineral fertilizer production. The comparative growth of mineral fertilizer production is given i n Table 8 (extracted from N.G. Peshev, p. 10)

(15)

Table 8. Mineral fertilizers production by years (in t e r m s of 100 percent con- tent of nutrients, mill. tons)

World 29.6 45.5 67.4 102.3 127.9

USSR 3.3 7.4 13.1 22.2 3 1.5

USA 7.4 11.0 14.6 21.9

According t o (P. Paskar, p. 26) an analysis of mineral fertilizer utilization shows t h a t for t h e period 1976-1980, t h e average annual additional production owing to fertilizer was 32.2 million tons of grain, 3.3 million tons of raw cotton, 26 million tons of sugar beets, 9 million tons of potatoes, 5.5 million tons of vegetables, 120 thousand tons of flax fibre, 600 thousand tons of sunflower seeds It is considered t h a t in future Soviet agricultural crop production will require t h e provision of mineral fertilizer deliveries with average proportion N:P:K

=

1:l: 1 (N.G. Peshev).

For t h e period from 1950 t o 1975, t h e s h a r e of nitrogen fertilizers within t h e total volume of production increased from 25 to 35 percent, and the share of phosphorous fertilizers decreased from 42 t o 26 percent. The increase of t h e nitrogen fertilizers production was connected with t h e development of feed base, for livestock production. .

Changes in deliveries of mineral fertilizers t o farms by years a r e shown in Table 9.

Table 9. Delivery of mineral fertilizers to agriculture

million tons in t e r m s of

100 percent content of n u t r i e n t s Proportion

Years N P2°5

K

Total

l4

P2°5 K

Source:

The USSR economy in 1980, p.237

**

The USSR agriculture, pp. 137-143

Analysis of data from Table 9 shows t h a t t h e total production and delivery of mineral fertilizers to agriculture increased 15 times from 1950 t o 1980. How- ever for t h i s period t h e s h a r e of diflerent fertilizers

in

total volume drastically

(16)

changed in favour of nitrogen fertilizers, and now we need to learn what struc- ture of this production would be more preferable.

Another question related to the increasing efficiency of mineral fertilizer application requires t h e solution of t h e problem of a rational distribution of fer- tilizers for agricultural crops. Comparative data of actual and normative efficiency of fertilizer application for different crops a r e given in Table 10.

Table 10. Elliciency of fertilizers application

*gain in yield in **Application (in 1980) m e t r i c centner per

1 metric centner of kg/ha (in re turn per each increase of fertilizer terms of ruble of expenditures

application nutrients) on fertilizers, ruble

Crop normative actual

1. Potato 26 9 274

2. Vegetables 46 13 294

3. Sugarbeets 23 11 438

4. Raw cotton 2.7 417

5. Grain 4.4 4.9 5 1

extracted from Planovoe Khozyaystwo, V.4. 1983

**

0. Sokolov, 1982, p.111-112

These data show t h a t industrial crops received t h e main increase of mineral fertilizers deliveries however these a r e characterized by low actual gains in yields in comparison to t h e normative gain. Then it may be expedient to redistribute fertilizer application to different crops over the period of Food Program implementation. According to 0. Sokolov, 1982) almost 80 percent of t h e increase in fertilizer deliveries will be directed to grain and feed crops.

And so we need t o take into consideration within the framework of the SOVAM the possibility of evaluating t h e various alternatives for redistribution of fertilizers between different crops. Another aspect of fertilizer application relates t o their efficiency in different regions of the USSR The following data on gain of grain output per 1 ton of fertilizer application is given by 0. Sokolov (1982): 2.7 tons for t h e central region of the RSFSR (Russian Soviet Federative Socialist Republic); and

1.6 tons for the North-West region of t h e RSFSR,

The actual r e t u r n from fertilizers is different from one region t o another.

It is therefore also necessary to determine ways to improve the distribution of fertilizers by regions too.

3.5. land resources and their distribution

The Soviet Union occupies one sixth of the land surface of our planet. It possesses t h e largest territory in the world: 224,022 million hectares including areas of the White Sea (90 thousand square kilometers) and the Sea of Asov (37,3 thousand square kilometers). To the end of 1981, all agricultural land (arable land, orchards, long-fallow lands, vineyards, hay fields and pastures) make up 553.7 million hectares. including 226.6 million hectares of arable land,

(17)

34.9 million hectares of hay fields and 286.9 million hectares of pastures.

From the point of view of agricultural activities t h e most significant is t h e high latitudinal position of the territory of the USSR For comparison, t h e Tran- scaucasia, the Soviet Asian republics and the Ulu-aine, have t h e same latitudi- nal position as the northern part of the USA and as t h e southern p a r t of Canada, t h e major Canadian cities a r e further south than Moscow.

The major landscape zones of the USSR include tundra, taiga, mixed forests deserts, lowlands, and mountains. Vast areas of t h e Soviet Union are unsuited to agricultural activities and are marginal, mainly because of the high latitudi- nal and internal continental position. The greater part of t h e arable belt con- sisting of extensive plains lies in zones of risk agriculture characterized by fre- quent winter cold or s u m m e r drought. In addition, large areas of arable soil are poor in phosphorous.

Nevertheless, t h e r e a r e many ways to intensify the agricultural production and to improve the productivity in zones with more or less favourable climatic conditions. One of these is the r e c e n t implementation of scientifically well- founded system of agriculture. Such systems have been developed for several agricultural regions of the country. The t e r m scientifically well-founded sys- t e m of agriculture includes: rational crop rotations, regional s t r u c t u r e of acreage with fallow lands, industrial seed growing, utilization of high-productive varieties and hybrids, application of industrial technology to crop production, effective utilization of reclaimed lands, mineral and organic fertilizers, of soil improvement. One of t h e examples of such a regional system of agriculture was developed for Stavropol (Nikonov AA. (ed) 1980). According to V.K. Mesyats (1983), crop rotations all around the country were introduced for 77 percent of the arable land. For t h e last 2-3 years t h e cropping p a t t e r n was improved. For example the area of fallow land in 1982 equalled 18 million ha. The goal is to increase this area to 20-22 million ha (-9 percent of t h e country's arable land).

However, the improvement of t h e inland utilization and cropping p a t t e r n also requires the consideration of not only the possibilities of bioclimatic and natural potentials of t h e country's land, but the demand for various agricul- tural products and the provision of input resources and t h e material and machinery for their production.

For example, currently, t h e country needs to increase t h e volume of lives- tock commodities production. This requires t h a t t h e production and utilization of feed m u s t be increased and improved. The concentrates of grain and simple mixed feed used for livestock feeding currently a r e characterized by deficit of protein. In order to obtain a balance of mixed feed (and then t o save 15-20 per- c e n t of concentrate feed

-

25-30 million tons of grain annually), i t will be necessary to reconsider t h e s t r u c t u r e of t h e land under cultivation mainly by t h e enlargement of acreage for pulses, oil plants, corn a n d s o on. The following desired s t r u c t u r e is suggested a s desirable for feedgrain balance. (L.S. Stefan- yuk, Planovoe Khozyaystwo V.12. 1982): oats 35

-

40% corn 16 -18 percent, pulses 12 -15 percent and wheat 20 -25 percent (instead of actual share

-

50 per-

cent). The production of roughage succulent and pasture feed m u s t be increased. According t o V.K. Mesyats Planovoe Khozyaystwo V.4 (1983) in 1983 t h e acreage for perennial herbs was expected t o increase to 29 million ha.

Another question to be considered is the regional location of different crops.

There is t h e following data (Zagaitov, P.Polovinkin, p.50)

-

One h a of irrigated land in t h e Low and Middle Volga region can produce t h e s a m e volume of t h e grass meal as 2.5 h a of cultivated hay in the Belorus- sia.

(18)

-

2.5 h a of Belorussian land for grain is able t o produce 1.8 times more grain t h a n 1 h a of i r r i g a t e d land in t h e Volga region.

After comparing t h e s e d a t a and other factors, t h e authors concluded t h a t t h e new a r e a s of i r r i g a t e d land between t h e rivers Volga a n d Ural should ration- ally be used for establishing a large specialized zone for t h e production of g r a s s meal and seeds of p e r e n n i a l grasses.

I t c a n n o t be an exaggeration t o say t h a t t h e problem of t h e rational ioca- tion and specialization of various agricultural commodities production is one of t h e most i m p o r t a n t in t h e country. This problem becomes especially c l e a r from an analysis of t h e wide variability of soil-climatic and economic conditions for agricultural production existing in different regions. These conditions influence t h e e 5 c i e n c y of production of some commodity from one zone t o another. According t o (G. Rudenko, G. Miloserdov, p.17) t h i s efficiency varies almost 7 times from o n e administrative region of t h e c o u n t r y t o another.

Large a r e a s of f a r m l a n d in t h e Soviet Union n e e d t o be constantly improved. According t o P. Paskar (1983, pp 29-30) t h e m o s t important problem is t o i n s u r e sufficient m o i s t u r e c o n t e n t of t h e soil, because n e a r l y 70% of i t lacks sufficient m o i s t u r e .

We m u s t also n o t e t h a t emciency of fertilizers application is sharply reduced if i t is applied without taking into a c c o u n t agrorneteorological condi- tions. For example, reducing t h e a m o u n t of soil m o i s t u r e in a 20 c e n t i m e t e r t o p soil layer t o 20 m i l l i m e t e r s leads t o decreased uptake of soil n u t r i e n t s by roots of plants (E. Ulanova, p. 69) a n d mineral fertilizers a r e in fact not absorbed by t h e plants. Besides s u c h factors a s precipitation a n d soil moisture, uptake of fertilizers i s also strongly dependent on t e m p e r a t u r e . If t h e soil t e m - p e r a t u r e is lower t h a n 1 0

"

C t h e n all processes of mineral e l e m e n t s utilization a r e depressed. ( k l . Korovin, 1972).

Taking into consideration s u c h dependence of fertilizer application efficiency on agrometeorological conditions a n d weather fluctuations on t h e territory of t h e USSR ( s e e section 3.2) i t is necessary t o make agriculture more independent of droughts. Comprehensive l a n d improvement programs of t h e Soviet s t a t e envisage m e a s u r e s for l a n d b e t t e r m e n t . At p r e s e n t t h e total a r e a of irrigated and d r a i n e d lands i s 31.6 million h a and t h e reclaimed lands pro- duce a t h i r d of t h e g r o s s o u t p u t of t h e plant-growing s e c t o r (P. Paskar, p. 31).

Under the Food P r o g r a m by 1990 i t i s planned t o expand these lands to over 70 million ha.

In o t h e r words, t h e SOVAM h a s t o provide possibilities for comparison of various variants of l a n d r e s o u r c e s utilization.

3.6.

Iabour resources

To c h a r a c t e r i z e i n detail labour resources for agricultural production we can use several indexes s u c h as: availability, s t r u c t u r e of labour by s e x and age, qualifications, employment, etc.

If we follow t h e s a m e s t r u c t u r e of production module for t h e SOVAM a s for t h e FAP national model with common s t r u c t u r e , t h e n we m u s t be able t o deter- m i n e t h e availability of labour for f u t u r e periods taking i n t o account t h e previ- o u s statistical d a t a a n d m a i n tendencies of t h e labour resources changes. The problems of quantitative a n d qualitative reproduction of labour resources in socialistic agricultural f a r m s a r e discussed in (Yalas, J. Schwarzbach, P. 1984).

Table 11 contains corresponding statistical d a t a e x t r a c t e d from t h e Statistical Yearbook, "The USSR National Economy in 1980".

(19)

-

15-

Table 1 1. Agricultural Labour Statistics (

Sovkho z

)

Indexes 1965 1970 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980

1. Average annual

numbers, thousands 8928 9419 10521 10767 10999 11258 11381 11650 2. Growth rates of t h e

average annual numbers

(1940= 100) 330 348 389 398 407 417 421 431 3. Average monthly wages, 75.0 10 1.0 126.8 134.6 139.1 143.0 146.0 149.2 roubles including:

--workers 72.5 98.8 125.3 133.5 138.1 142.5 145.3 149.0 --specialists 136.3 162.5 180.2 182.9 186 186.1 186.9 185.7 --office workers 82.2 95.6 114.5 119.1 121.2 122.4 123.2 123.0 4. Specialists with

higher and secondary

education, thousands 626 973 1400 1856

5. Machine operators

thousands 773 808 1234 1250 1318 1414 1442 1488

including:

tractor operators 550 559 718 703 729 796 790 806

combine operators 84 63 118 118 146 152 147 164

car drivers 63 95 184 192 206 215 205 210

Source: The USSR National Economy in 1980.

3.7. Specific requirements to the SOVN

This short essay of t h e c u r r e n t s t a t e and development tasks for Soviet agri- culture allows note to be made h e r e of t h e main specific requirements for the SOVAM from the point of view of its expected utility for t h e analysis of future strategies for production and trade. First of all t h e general requirement is to take into account the main directions and tendencies reflected by t h e USSR Food Program until 1990.

For the c u r r e n t stage of t h e Soviet agriculture development, these can be formulated as follows:

-

to m e e t requirements of t h e Soviet people in food and agricultural pro- ducts in accordance with scientifically determined standards;

-

to achieve high growth r a t e s in farm production on t h e basis of intensification;

-

to improve t h e economic management mechanism and t h e s t r u c t u r e of t h e country's agro-industrial complex in accordance with c u r r e n t stage of t h e national economic development;

- to

reach the maximum self-sufficiency of the Soviet Union in main pro- ducts.

In order to satisfy t h e general requirements, t h e SOVAM has to possess characteristics which will p e r m i t i t to take into account t h e specific c h a r a c t e r of Soviet agriculture development described in the previous sections of this paper.

(20)

3.0. Main assumptions for the XlVAhl construction

The guidelines for the development of the national economy are provided on the basis of the state plans system. I t is predetermined by t h e public owner- ship of t h e means of production, land, mineral resources and factories in the Soviet Union. The system of planned economic management helps t o secure coordination in t h e functioning of t h e socialistic economy, t o ensure balance of its development. The system of plans consists of comprehensive long-term pro- grams for scientific and technological progress, ten-year guidelines for economic and social development, five-year plans and annual plans.

Let us give a very short description of this system. For more detailed read- ing see Tikhonov, 1983. The initial indices of the Soviet economy development a r e advanced by the CPSU Congresses and then they are considered by t h e Ple- nums of the CPSU Central Committee and the USSR Council of Ministers. Thus, the main national economic targeted characteristics of development such as development rates of industry, agriculture, transport and communications, proportions between consumption and accumulation funds in the national income, growth rates of salaries, growth rates of labour productivity etc. are determined initially by t h e USSR State Planning Committee. Then on t h e basis of these targets t h e plans of republics, branches of industry, agriculture and enterprises are drafted. These drafts and amendments to them from enter- prises teams and local bodies a r e used for making a detailed draft. This draft is discussed by the USSR Council of Ministers, corresponding commissions of the USSR Supreme Soviet and other organizations. Then the draft of the State Plan f o r the Economic and Social Development of the USSR is submitted t o the CPSU Central Committee for consideration and endorsement. After i t i s approved a t the session of the Soviet Supreme Soviet t h e final draft acquires t h e force of law. And now t h e enterprises begin t o prepare their annual plans. Thus, cen- tralized guidance in drafting state, sectoral, territorial and other plans is com- bined with t h e initiative of workers' collectives.

1. The Soviet food and agriculture system is a constituent part of the USSR's whole socialist economy. Domestic market as such h a s an insignificant role in agricultural production development. Hence main assumptions for the Soviet agricultural policy model construction have t o reflect the features of the socialist planned economy. Thus, t h e SOVAM structure and information flows have to be different from those of models for countries with market economies.

All the abovementioned facts mean first of all that a number of normative ele- m e n t s such as target levels of production and consumption, planned growth r a t e s etc. have to be considered.

A s e t of these normative elements for t h e Soviet agricultural development .can be found in state plans a n d especially in the USSR Food Program.

Assumption 1.

Being descriptive in nature as many of t h e FAP models are, t h e SOVAM has t o contain the normative elements in order to reflect planned c h a r a c t e r of the socialist agricultural development.

2. The social production is based on the division of labour. Hence the determination of its proportions in accordance with capabilities and require- ments of t h e society is its overall feature. The advantage of the planned social- ist economy is the ability for formation of national-economic proportions of the organization of production. Coordination between the country's social require- m e n t s and its material a n d Bnancial resources is achieved due t o the

(21)

elaboration of a s y s t e m of balances: balances of social product and national income, of fixed assets, of manpower resources, of t h e population's cash income and expenditures e t c . According t o proportions of t h e USSR economy develop- m e n t , determined in these balances, t h e target levels, growth rates and struc- t u r e of output of production a r e specified. These a r e reflected by long-term plans. It is also t r u e for t h e Soviet agricultural system.

Assumption 2.

Target levels, growth r a t e s and s t r u c t u r e of output of agricultural produc- tion are specified within t h e framework of t h e SOVAM exogenously.

3. Once t h e s t a t e plans for t h e Soviet economy development as a whole and for the agricultural s e c t o r development in particular, have been approved and t h e brought into force. then t a r g e t levels, growth rates and other indexes Axed in these plans have t o be implemented as close a s possible t o these targets.

Deviations of real agricultural output from target levels in t h e Soviet Union are mainly conditioned by weather fluctuations.

Realizing the existence of such deviations in some years various measures a r e envisaged in t h e country in order t o minimize t h e m , for instance, by intensification of domestic production, improvement of stocks management.

etc.

Assumption 3.

Alternatives for minimization of deviations of real domestic agricultural output from t a r g e t levels have t o be considered explicitly within t h e framework of t h e SOVAM a n d have t o be determined endogenously.

4. Besides t h e productive sphere rational proportions of Soviet economic development a r e also determined for t h e sphere of distribution. In general these a r e based on proportions whereby t h e national income is divided into con- sumption and accumulation funds. According t o 'Iikhonov

N.A

(1983, p.95) "the size of t h e consumption funds s e t s t h e economic limit t o t h e growth of t h e real incomes of t h e population, thereby determining t h e scale a n d growth rates of living standards. while t h e size of t h e accumulation funds determines t h e potential possibilities of f u r t h e r expanding production." As far a s the levels of internal consumption i n agricultural and food commodities a r e concerned we have considered those in Section 3.1 (see Table 5 for per capita consumption, for example.)

Assumption 4.

Annual t a r g e t levels of internal consumption in agricultural and food com- modities and its growth r a t e s a r e specified exogenously.

5. Implementation of these targets is one of t h e main tasks for t h e whole economy. The s t a t e policy is oriented towards permanent and stable improve- m e n t in t h e living standards of t h e population. A set of measures concerning internal agricultural production, commodities distribution, foreign trade. etc.

intended for t h e fulfillment of t h e s e targets a r e envisaged by t h e State. Attain- m e n t of determined level of self-sufficiency in main agricultural commodities is considered as one of t h e preferable ways for t h e period under consideration and various alternatives for implementation of determined target levels of con- sumption in t h e s e commodities a r e studied.

(22)

Versions for t h e consumption targets in agricultural commodities have to be modelled explicitly within the framework of the SOVAM and comparison of these versions and selection of the preferable one has to be envisaged endogenously.

6. The system of balances which a r e elaborated by planning ofices is also intended for determination of distribution of rational proportions of the country's material and financial resources between different sectors of the economy and their utilization. Provision for t h e agricultural sector corresponding input resources such as capital investments, fertilizers, machinery, etc., is calculated according to these balances and long-term places by various regulations.

Representation of labour requirements is, for example, one of the impor- t a n t aspects within the system OF agricultural production planning. The main factors which a r e considered here are: employment, labor productivity, educa- tion, qualidcations, s t r u c t u r e by age and sex, etc. The s t a t e pays great atten- tion to long-term planning of labour requirements a n d its utilization a s well as t o problems of raising t h e living standards of workers in agriculture and to working and social conditions in the countryside. All these questions were reflected in t h e USSR Food Program. Labour movements within agriculture and between agricultural and other sectors of t h e economy are determined by corresponding regulations of government. Then t h e dynamics of labour input for agriculture in t h e SOVAM could be modelled according to historical trends, adjusted to t h e supposed governmental future policy.

Assumption 6.

General volumes of input resources (capital investments, labour, fertiliz- ers, etc.) for t h e agricultural sector for t h e period under consideration a r e specified exogenously.

7. One of the essential parts of the USSR economic system is the institu- tion of the s t a t e foreign trade monopoly. State monopoly of foreign trade means t h a t all foreign economic relations a r e executed by t h e State. Existence of this monopoly permits planning export and import on t h e basis of the country's economic potentialities and requirements a s well as ensuring t h e priority of national i n t e r e s t s over those for individual enterprises a n d social groups.

Thanks to this t h e USSR's foreign trade promote t h e fulfillment of national tasks and t h e solution of internal social and economic problems.

The s t a t e foreign t r a d e monopoly in the Soviet Union has flexible and branching organizational system, including t h e Ministry for Foreign Trade of t h e USSR which implements general control of foreign trade and supervises the activity of export-import associations, the State Committee of t h e USSR for Foreign Economic Relations which promotes economic ties with t h e socialist and Developing countries and a number of other institutions, for example foreign trade associations each of which specialized in a particular group of commodities. These associations a r e the main organizations to e n t e r into com- mercial deals with Foreign firms. They have a specified independence in their operations and commercial activity and function under centralized manage- m e n t of foreign economic relations on the basis of annual and long t e r m plans and plan assignments.

The import plans for these associations are compiled according to require- m e n t s of various economic sectors, ministries and enterprises and t h e export plans a r e drawn u p on t h e basis of the production plans, assignments of

(23)

different industries and enterprises.

The state foreign trade monopoly also covers all export/import activities in agricultural and food commodities. The volumes and s t r u c t u r e of foreign trade in these commodities have to meet internal needs, trade agreements, quotas and other policy instruments.

Assumption 7.

Volumes of foreign trade in agricultural and food commodities both for import and export have t o m e e t both lower and upper constraints given exo- genously. Structure of foreign trade in these commodities i s specified by cen- tral authorities.

8. An important complement of state foreign t r a d e monopoly in t h e Soviet Union is state foreign exchange monopoly. According t o i t t h e s t a t e takes pos- session of all foreign exchange earnings from export a n d other foreign economic operations and from t h e extraction of precious metals in t h e USSR.

All operation with foreign currencies a r e carried out under t h e control of the State Bank of t h e USSR a s well as the Bank of the USSR Foreign Trade. State foreign exchange monopoly enables accumulation of t h e necessary foreign exchange funds a n d t o use t h e m for t h e development of the national economy.

For this aim annual export-import and foreign exchange plans a s well as long t e r m plans are drawn up as a p a r t of t h e overall economic plans of the USSR.

According to this plan, t h e s t a t e determines how and over what periods foreign exchange resources should be used. The rules of using foreign exchange resources have t o be satisfied for import-export operations i n the sphere of agricultural commodities trade.

Assumption 8.

Financial constraints for import and export in agricultural and food com- moditiers a r e determined by exogenously given foreign trade deficit.

9. Another important feature for the socialist economy is t h a t direct rela- tionships between domestic and international markets a r e absent. Domestic consumer and producer prices on agricultural and food commodities express internal policy options and for overwhelming majority of these commodities these prices do not r e l a t e to world market prices. The fact i s t h a t world prices a r e subject to fluctuations a n d to follow t h e m implicitly would be inconsistent with a planned economy.

The principles of i n t e r n a l price formation radically differ from t h e practice of the free market. All i n t e r n a l prices a r e established i n a planned way by state bodies. In the process of determining these prices, s u c h factors as commodity production cost, t h e rate of profit and also social significance of t h e commodity a r e taken into account. Domestic prices in the USSR a r e a n i n s t r u m e n t for implementation of t h e social and economic policy of t h e state.

Assumption 9.

Domestic producer a n d consumer prices on main agricultural and food commodities do not relate t o t h e i r world market prices. Retail prices of most goods a r e stable for t h e period under consideration.

This paper gives a s h o r t description of t h e c u r r e n t state of t h e Soviet agri- culture and tendencies of i t s development. The a u t h o r has attempted t o out- line the specific requirements for the Soviet Agricultural Model (SOVAM) first of

(24)

all from t h e point of view of t h e i r correspondence t o t h e main directions of t h e country's agro-food complex development. The main assumptions for t h e SOVAM construction were given h e r e also in order t o outline t h e conceptual framework for t h e SOVAM. It i s supposed t h a t t h e next paper will contain t h e first version of t h e formal description of t h e Soviet model as a whole or some of i t s submodels.

(25)

References

Tikhonov, N.k 1983. Soviet Economy: Achievements, Problems, Prospects.

Novosti P r e s s Agency Publishing House, Moscow.

Nikonov, k k 1980. The System of Agriculture of Stavropol Region, Stavropol Publishing House, Stavropol (in Russian)

Peshev, N.G. 1980. Economic Problems of t h e rational utilization of t h e Phos- p h a t e Raw Material. Publishing House "Nauka", Leningrad (in Russian) Khrulev, J.M. 1972. The role of Chemistry i n intensification of agricultural pro-

duction, "Znanie", Moscow (in Russian)

Parikh, K. a n d F. Rabar (eds) 1981. Food for all in a sustainable world: The IIASA Food a n d Agriculture Program, SR-81-2

Keyzer, M . k 1980. An outline of IIASA's Food a n d Agriculture Model, WP-80-09 Parikh, K.S. 1981. Exploring National Food Policies in a n International Setting:

The Food a n d Agriculture Program of IIASk WP-8 1-12.

nscher G. a n d

K.

Frohberg. 1980. Simplified National Models

-

The Condensed version of t h e Food and Agriculture Model System of t h e IlASk WP-80-56 Fischer G. a n d U. Sichra, 1983. The Aggregation of Agricultural Supply Utiliza-

tion Accounts. WP-83-42.

Sichra, U. Calculation of t h e World Price for t h e detailed a n d t h e small FAP commodity lists. unpublished paper.

The USSR economy in 1980, Statistical Yearbook. Central Statistical Board Publishing House, Moscow, 198 1: (in Russian)

The USSR economy for t h e period 1922-1982. Anniversary Statistical Yearbook Central Statistical Board Publishing House. Moscow, 1982 (in Russian)

K.

Bogolyubov, 1983. Development of t h e Agrarian S e c t o r in t h e USSR. Novosti P r e s s Agency Publishing House, Moscow.

Paskar,

P.

1983. Agro-industrial complex: Growth prospects. Novosti P r e s s Agency Publishing House, Moscow.

Yakunin, 1. 1982. To i n c r e a s e t h e grain resources

-

t h e key t a s k of t h e agro- industial complex, Planovoe khozyaystwo (in Russian)

Borchenko, N. 1982. Agriculture - initial basis for t h e food problem solution, Planovoe Khozyaystwo, V. 8 (in Russian)

Sokolov. 0. 1982. The role of chemistry i n t h e Food Program implementation Planovoe Khozyaystwo, V.7 (in Russian)

Zagaitov I. a n d P. Polovinkin. 1982. Increasing stability of agricultural produc- tion. Planovoe Khozyaystwo V. 10. (in Russian)

Rudenko, G. a n d Miloserdov,

V.

1982. Improvement of economic mechanism in agro-industrial complex, Planovoe Khozyaystwo, V. 3.

Yalafi, J. a n d P. Schwarzbach, 1984. Reproduction of l a b u r resources in social- istic agricultural enterprises, International farming journal, VoL. 1, Mos- cow (in Russian).

Ulanova., E.S. 1975. Agrometeorological conditions a n d yields of winter wheat, Leningrad (in Russian)

Korovin. AJ. 1972. The role of t e m p e r a t u r e in m i n e r a l nutrition of plants, Len- i n g r a d (in Russian)

Mesyats, V.K. 1983. Planovoe Khozyaystwo, V.4. (in Russian)

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

The linkage model of IIASX's Food and Agriculture Program (FAP) can be described a s a n econometric world model which investigates the interaction of

Views or opinions expressed herein do not necessarily repre- sent those of the Institute or of its National Member Organizations... FA0 Supply

computer languages. These models are generally applied to estimation of chemical losses in percolation or groundwater. Most continuous simulation models must be calibrated and are

The agricultural production module shows acreages of crops, labor alloca- tion, capital allocation, nitrogen fertilizer application, production of crops, animals,

Majority of the poor live in rural areas and their incomes are directly linked to the agricultural sector, as shown in Table 1 for the low income Asian developing countries (World

Instruments in this category in- clude food and income subsidies to low-income persons as well as policies affecting production such as taxes and subsidies on land, investment

Because this function can be used for analysis of multi-input (i.e., more than two inputs) production technology without imposing a p r i o r i any restrictions on the

The major blocks of the latter submodel are related to production (linear programming models for socialist agriculture and food processing sector, non- linear optimization model