• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

The Demand for Forest Sector Products

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "The Demand for Forest Sector Products"

Copied!
32
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

W O R K I N G P A P E R

THE

D B U N D

HIR

H)FU!Sl'

SECTOR

PRODUCTS

A E.

Andersson

R

Brhnlund G. Kornai

November 1984 WP-84-07

l n t e r n a t ~ o n a l l n s t ~ t u t e for Applied Systems Analysis

(2)

NOT FOR QUOTATION WITHOUT PERMISSION OF THE AUTHOR

THE DEIY[AND FOR

FDRESl'

SECTOR PRODUCTS

A E.

Andersson

R

Brsnnlund

G.

Kornai

November 1984 WP-84-67

Working P a p e r s a r e interim reports on work of the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis and have received only limited review. Views or opinions expressed herein do not necessarily represent those of the Institute or of its National Member Organizations.

INTERNATlONAL INSTITUTE FOR APPLIED SYSTEMS ANALYSIS 2361 Laxenburg. Austria

(3)

The objective .of the Forest Sector Project a t UASA is t o study long- t e r m development alternatives for the forest sector on a global basis.

The emphasis in the Project is on issues of major relevance to industrial and governmental policy makers in different regions of t h e world who are responsible for forestry policy, forest industrial strategy, and related trade policies.

The key elements of structural change in the forest industry a r e related to a variety of issues concerning demand, supply, and interna- tional trade of wood products. Such issues include the development of t h e global economy and population, new wood products and substitution for wood products, future supply of roundwood and alternative fiber sources, technology development for forestry and industry, pollution regulations, cost competitiveness. tariffs and non-tariff trade barriers, etc. The aim of the Project is t o analyze the consequences of future expectations and assumptions concerning such substantive issues.

In

this paper t h e issue of demand analysis for the forest sector pro- duct is analyzed from a theoretical and an econometric points of view.

An

intermediary demand approach is advocated and applied. For the econometric estimates presented a database for Canada is used. The results indicate t h a t the dual (cost) procedure to i n t e m e d i a t e d e m a n d function estimation is preferable to the use of production functions to generate demand equations.

Markku Kallio Project Leader

Forest Sector Project

(4)

CONTENTS

1.

INTRODUCTION

2.

THE FINAL DEMAND FOR FOREST SECTOR PRODUCTS

3.

THE THEORY OF INTERMEDIATE DEMAND

4.

TESTING FOR CONSTANT ELASTICITIES OF SUBSTITUTION

5 .

THE THEORY OF PRODUCTION AND INTERDEPENDENCIES

BETWEEN FIRMS

6.

THE FOREST SECTOR IN THE FRAMEWORK OF INPUT OUTPUT ANALYSIS

7 .

INPUT-OUTPUT ANALYSIS, PRODUCTION THEORY

AND

DUALITY

8.

COST FUNCTIONS AND INTERMEDIATE DEMAND M)R FOREST

PRODUCTS

9.

AN ECONOMETRIC STUDY OF INTERMEDIATE DEMAND

10.

CONCLUSIONS AND DIRECTIONS FOR FURTHER STUDIES

REFERENCES

(5)

THE

DEMAND

FOR FOREST SECTOR

PRODUCTS

hl E.

Andersson,

R

B r h n l u n d and G. Kornai

There are large variations between countries in per capita consump- tion of forest sector products. In 1979, the per capita consumption of paper was, for example. ten times larger in North America than in Latin America. This difference can to a large extent be explained by differences in standard of living. In the s a m e year, the per capita income of Latin America was also not much more t h a n one-tenth of the North American income per capita. For an international cross-section material, much of t h e variation of paper consumption follows the large variation in per capita income. A simple regression of paper c o n s u m p tion on income for an international sample of countries gives an income elasticity of 0.92. Among the high income countries, income per capita is not a good predictor. The consumption of paper was for instance

(6)

almost twice as large in the USA in relation to Switzerland in a period when the per capita income was almost 40% above the US income per capita. The regression among t h e ten highest income countries reveals t h a t in this group t h e r e is practically no correlation between general standard of living a n d per capita apparent consumption of paper.

Differences in prices can neither explain these cross-section differences.

On the whole, there is a marked difference in the use of forest sector pro- ducts between USA and Western Europe, which cannot be explained by differences in standard of living or relative prices. In order to under- stand these differences, an analysis of differences in economic and tech- nological s t r u c t u r e is needed. It is, of course, anyhow possible to use a time series model involving t h e

GNP

for each country. This is, however, a valid procedure only if t h e economic structure underlying the growing

GNP

is changing in t h e same way in the prediction period as in t h e obser- vation period.

Future demand for forest products can also be assumed t o be characterized by changing response patterns in different regions of the world. Over t h e long t e r m , impacts of a number of technological changes need to be evaluated. Examples such as advances in electronic informa- tion technologies, the development of super absorbent material and new packaging materials will affect the demand for forest products. This will probably be noticeable earlier and more strongly in some countries t h a n

in

others. In some regions of the world, the impacts of the changing energy scene on both forest products and on competitive energy carriers need our consideration.

(7)

2. THE FINAL DEMAND FOR PORESl' SECTOR P R O D U m

Demand functions a r e stimulus-response function showing how a given vector of price-stimuli will trigger off demand responses among users of t h e commodities. In economic theory, consumers (households or governments) a r e assumed to choose a s e t of consumer goods (food, clothing, housing, literature, etc.) in a condition of a constraining budget. Such a budget constraint can be seen as a s u m of quantities of different commodities consumed, weighted by the respective commodity prices, which has t o be kept within t h e limits of t h e available income.

The problem of t h e consumer is then often formulated as a maximization problem, in which t h e consumer chooses different commodities so as to maximize some utility i n d c a t o r , while staying within the limits of the available budget.

Assume t h a t consumers' preferences can be captured by a scalar utility function U ( Z ) a n d t h a t they aspire a maximization of utility sub- ject to t h e i r income constraint

xpizi = y ,

t h e n we have the equivalent

i

max

L =

u ( z ) - ~ ( p ~ z -y) Iz 1

which has a s conditions of a maximum

P T z - y = o

; and l e t

. . , . . .

,

. . .

% I " '

Unn

-Pn Det

lLll u12 - p l

1

uZ1

uZZ -p2

,*I -2 O

,

. .

, , Det

(8)

all larger than 0.

Denoting Dij for the co-factor of row i and column j of the Hessian deter- minant given above and

D

for the determinant value, we also have

where

qj =

D j i U D

The implication of condition (3) is t h a t some commodities must be substitutes for each other although some can be complements. This means t h a t if t h e price of paper increases, the consumption of some other commodities must increase (i.e., theater performances, car ser- vices, etc.) although some might decrease (i.e., book reading. letter writ- ing. etc.). The extent of such substitution is the major consideration of consumer demand theory. It can further be proved that

B

Ln z, 0 In zi

where

4, =

and Eij

=

, i.e., price- and income elasticities

a

ln pi

a

ln y

are constraining each other. A high income elasticity for paper thus requires high price elasticities on the average (if we have aggregated away complements).

Although consumer theory sheds some light on the problem of gen- erating testable demand functions, it tends to be too general for econometric purposes. As can be seen from (2). (3), (4). these conditions do not generate enough structure for statistical testing and estimation purposes. The only consequence of t h e analysis is a stimulus-response function which is called the individual demand function

(9)

ktpl, . .

, p i .

. .

, p , , y h ) according to which each consumer h demand for commodity i is determined by aU prices and his purchasing power as represented by income yh. These demand functions Dih(p , y h ) where p

=

[P,], can be aggregated into a household consumption

~ ~ ( p , y )

= C

~ ~, y h ) (where p y

=

[ y h ] . This is illustrated by Figure I. In

h

general, we should t h u s expect a heterogeneous consumer population t o generate a non-linear demand function even if each consumer is regu- lated by a linear demand function.

(10)

Our arguments against t h e use of the demand theory offered above for an econometric study of forest sector demand are t h e following:

(1) As a general theory of demand in which u ( z ) is the preference function of any decision maker (manager of a firm, government or household purchases), it is t o o general t o generate statistical hypotheses.

(2) As a general theory of t h e consumer it uses too little of t h e s t r u c t u r a l information on individual consumers' behavior as developed by t h e behavioral sciences.

(3) If seen a s a special theory of the consumer demand, it would cover a very limited s h a r e (10-20%) of t h e total forest sector demand.

3.

THE

THEORY O F DWEXlEDIATE DEWMI

In t h e c e n t e r of intermediate demand theory is t h e firm with one or many plants. A commodity like sawnwood is used as one of t h e many inputs (vl.

. . .

, v,) t o be transformed by the use of t h e fixed equipment t o generate a s e t of outputs ( q l ,

. . .

,q,), say, chairs, tables, beds and o t h e r pieces of furniture demanded by households, hotels, hospitals, and offices, etc. The model of t h e plant can t h u s be illustrated by Figure 2.

The black box representation of t h e firm (or plant), can be summarized in

which is a transformation function or a n implicit production function according t o which t h e inputs vector v a r e transformed into t h e

(11)

Public Goods

Sawnwood

t PLANT FOR Beds - H o t e l s

P l a s t i c

FURNITURE Chairs H o s p i t a l s Metal

Energy

PRODUCTION Labor

Public Bads

outputg-vector q . The public goods and bads a r e suppressed. We assume that

F

is a t least twice differentiable, increasing with

q

and decreasing with v , and strictly quasi-convex.

The behavior of t h e firm or plant manager can under a capitalistic regime be assumed to be one of profit maximization ( a t the firm level) or cost minimization (at t h e plant level). The reasoning behind this assumption is one of social Darwinism. Any firm or plant operating under some other rule would not exist for long. Not maximizing profits in an environment where other similar Arms maximize profits would imply a slower r a t e of capital accumulation a n d a relative decline of the

(12)

non-optimizing units.

At

a g e n e r a l equilibrium where profits above m a r k e t r e m u n e r a t i o n of m a n a g e m e n t services a r e forced to zero, non- optimizing behavior would imply t h e bankruptcy, i.e., death, of all non- optimizing Arms. No such a r g u m e n t c a n be raised in favor of optimizing behavior among consumers o r monopolistic organizations, like govern- m e n t bodies.

The profit is defined as t h e difference between revenues f r o m sales a n d costs of purchasing inputs:

where

n, =

o u t p u t prices

D,

=

i n p u t prices

(The s e t of o u t p u t a d input p r i c e s is in t h e sequel symbolized by t h e vector

p).

Profit

V

c a n be maximized s u b j e c t t o t h e transformation function c o n s t r a i n t

F.

max

L = nTq - oTv +

AF(~ .v)

[ q 1 4

The necessary conditions of optimality of (7) a r e t h e following:

The tirm should t h u s adjust any pair of outputs until t h e r a t i o [ ( d ~ / aqi)/ (aF/ aqk)] equals t h e given o u t p u t price ratio

[ni/ sr,]. I t

should f u r t h e r m o r e adjust a n y pair of inputs until t h e r a t i o

(13)

( a F / Ow,)/ ( a F / a v l ) equals t h e given relative input price ( o j / o l ) .

Rational behavior of firms thus dictates t h a t the firms must observe the parametrically changing price vector

p

and adjust through substitu- tion among inputs or outputs until the "marginal rates of substitution".

( - d g i / d q k ) and (-d v j / d v l ) correspond to the price ratios ( n k / n i ) and d F aF

( u L / o j ) or until n i / o,

= 4

-/

-1.

aqi avj

Total differentiation of ( 8 ) is a means of determining the response pattern of a firm to any given small change of output- or input prices.

or in matrix form Mdz

+

f d h = d p where

f

=

t F

,,...,

F,], and d p

=

t - d n , ,..., d o , {

The consequence of a change in the price structure on the adjustable input a n d output quantities can be determined by matrix inversion of (Bb)

dz

=

(AH)-'(dp -f d h )

It can be shown (Henderson-Quandt 1980) that

(14)

i.e., if an output price increases (ceteris paribus), t h e firm will increase t h a t output a n d if t h e price of an input increases t h e firm will also decrease t h e use of t h a t input. This unique response p a t t e r n implies t h a t slopes of demand and supply curves a r e clear c u t t o a n e x t e n t not found in consumer theory.

Further specification of response p a t t e r n s can be achieved only if we a r e prepared t o m a k e the transformation function F(q .v) more specific.

One way of specifying F is by assuming t h a t t h e firm (or plant) produces one output ( q ) only. We can t h e n write an explicit transformation func- tion, called a production function, i.e.:

One can f u r t h e r specify q(v) as, for example, t h e constant elasticity of substitution function, which is a special case of t h e Minkowski mean value function:

with profit maximization we t h e n g e t testable hypotheses of response as derived conditions of optimality:

a n d k = b n %

where o

= -

l + p l + p ai

(15)

4.

TESllNG FOR

C O m A N T ELASIICITIIZS

OF - O N

As can be seen from equation (12) the same elasticity of substitution between different inputs is assumed in this specification of t h e model.

This assumption has been tested for three of t h e most important forest product user sectors, namely n o n - r e s i d e n t i a l , r e s i d e n t i a l , and r e p n i r c o m t m c t i o n . The data base used for this t e s t is the constant price input-output series for Canada 1961-1974 as published by Statistics Canada.

The model used is equation (12) with a linear time effect and an added time effect and a stochastic error term with assumed mean value of zero a n d an assumed normal distribution with further assumed uncorrelated errors over time periods. The ordinary least squares method is used for estimating the regression equations. Table 1 gives the results. In t h e table only input pairs showing statistically significant parameters have been included. As can be seen from t h e table, statisti- cal significance criteria could hardly make credible the assumption of equation (11) combined with a short term profit maximizing behavior of firms. This is further strengthened by the fact t h a t a number of u-values estimated, but not reported, are not significant from zero.

5.

THE THEORY OF

PRODUCTION AND INTERDEPENDENCIES BllxwElmFIRMs

The modern theory of production abstains from a simplistic two or t h r e e factor analysis of inputs conversion into outputs. Instead, a multi- tude of inputs, like wood, pulp, different types of paper products, chemi- cals, metals, labor, energy, etc., a r e interacting in the transformation

(16)

TABLE 1. Results for constant elasticity of substitution regressions for construc- tion sectors of Canada based on data for period 1961-1974.

--- ' Fabr. wood p r o d ' p~

(4) (3)

Repair constr.

Lumber & Timber

] =

-0.73 In

- P~~ -

0.08t

ln

[

Fabr. wood prod.

P~

(3) (2.0)

Non res. constr.

Lumber

'

Timber ]

=

-0.6 in

-

PLT

-

0.03t ln

[

Fabr. metal prod. P~~

(2) (3.0)

Non res. constr.

. .

A J

-

" ' Y " "' " . " T "

Cement prod. PCP

Non res. constr.

Lumber & Timber

=

in

-

ln

[

Struct. Met. prod.

+

0.03t

PSH

(3.7) (1.3)

Res. constr.

[Panels

In p ,P

]

=

-1.84 In-

+

0.03t Iron & steel prod. Prks

Res. constr.

Fabr. wood prod.

] =

-1.4 ln-

ln

[

Cement p r o d

Pm +

O.OSt

PCP

(2.3) (3.4)

Res. constr.

(17)

into one or many outputs. This procedure has two main advantages.

Firstly, i t better approximates the actual technological situation of modern firms. Secondly, it more clearly t h a n in classical economic analysis of production by t h e use of land. labor, and capital inputs, puts t h e emphasis on interdependencies between different firms or aggregates of firms a s users and producers of intermediary commodities.

Two economic research fields have emerged and developed from this emphasis on interdependencies between producers. One primarily microeconomic class of models is a c t i v i t y a n a l y s i s . The other primarily macroeconomic class of models is i n p u t - o u t p u t analysis. A bridging class of models is t h e von Neumann type of models of which input-output models and

LP

models a r e special cases.

One simplification of t h e von Neumann model made in input-output models i s the assumption t h a t each aggregate of firms produces one commodity only or t h a t all firm information can be converted into a commodity by commodity framework.

In t h e production theory discussed in sections 3 and 4, we have shown t h a t t h e inputs of commodities and primary factors like labor per output unit are generally influenced by t h e prices expected t o be ruling.

Avoidance to adapt input s t r u c t u r e s to a changing price structure would not be a viable behavior in a market economy unless all actors would be equally rigid. Such an assumption would obviously be a t variance with common observations of

flrm

behavior. Thus, we can safely assume t h a t every qj is a Function OF the price vector

p

o r equivalently

A

=

A ( ~ ) : w h e r e A ( p ) i % j ( p ) j For (i,j

=

l , , . . , n )

(18)

If

this is t h e case, we can see t h e general interdependency problem for a linearly homogeneous economy as a price equilibrium problem, where

hl, =

~ A ( p , o ) + w a ( p . ~ )

=

H * ( ~ , G ) ~ ( p ) where

p =

row vector of commodity prices o

=

row vector of primary input prices

A @ )

=

price dependent square matrix of input-output coefficients a(p.ES)

=

a price dependent rectangular matrix of primary input-

output coefficients

h =

a n endogenously determined multiplicative factor

A t any given s e t of positive primary input prices E, a s e t of prices of com- modities and chosen A- a n d a - m a t r i c e s can be endogenously determined.

This is a special fixed point problem.

hp =

H(p); with H(p >0) r 0; and H(p) assumed continuous i n (12)

p

and homogeneous.

For this problem, t h e following theorem is applicable.

THEOREX

(cf. Nikaido, 1968, pp. 105-151; a proof is given on p. 152.):

Assume t h e following conditions hold

(a) H(p)

=

( H i ( p ) ) is de6ned for all non-negative

p

in

c,

with its

values being also on non-negative vectors in

e,

H ( p ) r 0.

(b)

~ ( p )

is continuous as a mapping

H: RT

-,

Rt,

except possibly a t

p =

0.

(c)

~ ( p )

is positively homogeneous of order m , 1 r rn r 0 in the sense t h a t H ( a p ) for

a

r 0,

p

r 0.

(19)

Let A = [ A ( H ( p ) = A p for some p E

Pn],

where

Pn =

l p l p

S O ,

5

pi

=

l j is t h e standard simplex.

a =l

Then,

A

contains a maximum which i s denoted by A(H). Further- more, if m

=

1, A(H) is t h e greatest among all t h e eigenvalues of

M.

A-1 can be interpreted a s t h e profitability of the economy.

When an equilibrium price vector p * has been determined t h e relevant choice of technique has also been solved. a n d an equilibrium implied structure of production can be determined

z =

A(p

*,o)z +

f ; (13)

subject to p f

=

oa(p *,G). The theory of interdependent firms with sub- stitution between all input commodities thus shows t h e existence of a general equilibrium with a simultaneous determination of techniques of production, production and price structures.

6.

THE FOREST

SECTOR

IN THE

FRAMEWORK

OF INPUT OUTPUT

ANALYSIS It is of great importance for a consistent analysis of t h e forest sec- tor t o determine how each one of t h e users of t h e forest products would react to a changing input price structure. The analysis in the foregoing sections would indicate t h a t m y price change would lead t o changing demand for all forest products. This is, however, a highly unlikely event in any real situation, even if t h e theory suggests such a result. A few sectoral outputs like electrical energy and transportation services e n t e r every sector of production a s inputs. As a contrast, o t h e r outputs like wood or paper products e n t e r only a few sectors of production a s inputs.

(20)

In these sectors of production (e.g., construction or printing and publish- ing) only a limited number of o t h e r inputs a r e used and a r e available for an adaptation in t h e form of substitution.

7. INPUT-OUTPUT ANALYSIS, PFtODUCTION THEORY AND DUALITY

Demand for inputs is derived in the foregoing sections with assump- tions of profit maximization and the existence of a mathematically well- behaved production function. Although profit maximization is a reason- able assumption a t the level of firms, constrained cost minimization is an alternative a n d probably better assumption a t t h e level of plants within corporations. Constrained cost minimization has certain advan- tages from a general theoretical point of view, as first demonstrated by Shephard (1953), a n d for econometric studies, a s first demonstrated by Nerlove (1965). As a simple example, we first derive t h e factor demand equations if t h e demand for output is given, the production function is of Cobb-Douglas type and cost of production of this predetermined output is minimized.

In t h i s example. the amount of capital and energy is assumed to be given by longer t e r m arrangements. Only t h r e e input flows into t h e plant, say, chemicals, paper a n d labor, a r e assumed to be freely variable in the time period of analysis. The output q could be newspapers. The problem i s thus:

minimize Cost z

o l v l +

0 2 v 2

+

w3u3 I vl

subject t o

a

vf 'v;~v? =

@

-

Projected Demand

(21)

al + aZ +

a,

=

s

=

economies of scale elasticity

The corresponding Lagrange optimization problem is given by t h e follow- ing expression:

minimize

L =

oi vi

-

A(a n u i a

'-q);

IvJl i i

with t h e following conditions of an optimum

Substituting factor demands as functions of prices (17) into t h e demand constraints (18). we arrive a t t h e factor demand equations

where ci

= al[aafla;za>]-l's. If

t h e r e a r e constant r e t u r n s t o scale t h e input-output coefficient

a,

E v i / q a r e price dependent only:

l n a l

=

lnc l - ( l - a l ) l n o l

+

a$noZ

+

aglnw3 etc.

With increasing r e t u r n s t o scale input output coefficients would depend on as well a s on prices. The cost function t h a t c a n be derived from a substitution of (19) into (14) is

C t h c

=

c1+c2+c3.

Shephard (1953) demonstrated t h a t under t h e behavioral a s s u m p tion made here, t h e minimized cost function and t h e production func- tion a r e related by a property of duality.

(22)

Shephard's

THEOREM:

If ~ ( q , u ) =

min toTv:f ( v ) 2 q j

v

and that if f is continuous from above and t h a t C ( q , o ) is differentiable with respect to input prices a t t h e point q ,w , then

v(q * . w * )

= vp

c(q * . o * ) :

where v(q * , o * ) is the vector of costs minimizing input flows needed t o produce t h e output flow

q *,

given t h e input prices o*.

As an example, we can use Shephard's theorem on cost equation (21):

with c l defined as before.

I t

is thus possible to develop a model of price and scale-dependent input demand either f r o m p m d u c t i o n or

from

c o s t functions postulated a t the plant level. Shephard's theorem indicates

t h a t is is in most cases easier t o commence from cost functions.

8. C05F F'UNCl'IONS

AND INTER16EDIATE

DEXAND

FOR FDREST

PRODUCTS The generalized Leontief cost function was introduced by Diewert (1971) as a suitable second order approximation of a general input cost function. This cost function c a n be written as

with

C

=

minimized total cost

(23)

g

=

output

o

=

vector of input prices

=

twl j t

=

time period

F ( q

, t ) =

scale and technology function

bkl

=

coefficient of substitutability between input k and input I

A possible specification of ~ ( g , t ) would be ~ ( q

, t ) =

q 1 l s e 4 . Some experiments in estimating

a

have indicated that the model is well behaved with

a

close to 0.5 (Frenger, 1982).

If

we apply Shephard's Theorem, the input demand functions are

Only if bU

=

0 for all k f l and s = l would the fixed input-output coefficients be warranted. Partial price elasticities, Ekl can be defined as

with dkl

=

Kronecker constant.

EU

can be used as one measure of the substitutability of two inputs, if t h e same level of production ( q *) is to be maintained.

The shadow (or dual) elasticity of substitution bU was introduced by McFadden (see Frenger 1983) and is defined as

i.e., the elasticity of the cost minimizing ratio of inputs t o a change in their relative price when cost, output and other prices are held constant.

(24)

Such elasticities have been measured for two forest product using sec- tors

-

Manufacture of Wood and Wood Products and Printing and Publish- ing by P . Frenger (1983). The results a r e shown in Table 2.

The elasticities of substitution a r e generally high for t h e inputs sub- stitutable in t h e s h o r t run, and s h o r t and long run elasticities a r e close t o each other in t h e Frenger study. On basis of this study, i t s e e m s rea- sonable t o expect intra-material m b s t i t u t i o n elasticities t o be high in comparison with capital labor substitution elasticities

-

a n assumption a t variance with t h e approach chosen i n t h e so-called MSG-models (Johansen 1959, Bergman 1980, and Zalai 1980).

TABLE 2. Shadow elasticities of substitution 1975 of input demand equations 1969-1980 in Norway.

Input pairs

Manufact. of wood and Printing a n d

wood products publishing

Material

-

Energy Material

-

Labor Material

-

Capital Energy

-

Capital

Labor

-

Capital Energy

-

Labor

(25)

0. AN ECONOMEI'IUC SWDY OF

INTERMEDIATE DEMAND

Our study is based on the duality approach t o input demand analysis. In t h e study, we use t h e approach t o estimate demand func- tions for t h e following forest sector products:

1. Raw material from forestry except primary processed lumber and timber

2. Lumber and Timber 3. Veneer and Plywood

4. Other fabricated wood materials 5 Pulp

6. Newsprint and paper stocks 7. Paper products

The data again are collected from input-output statistics for Canada 1961-1979, provided by Satistics Canada a n d by t h e Comparative Economic Analysis Aoject of IIASk

The basic idea behind this stage of t h e study is to test the substitu- tion hypothesis as econometrically specifled by the Generalized Leontief Cost Function and t h e associated input demand functions derivable by the use of Shephard's theorem.

If

t h e hypothesis can be sustained, it forms t h e basis for specification of market demand functions, with a determination of the mmimal number of substitute prices to be included beside t h e own-price in such market demand functions.

Time series from 1961 t o 1978, collected from input-output statistics for Canada, a r e used t o estimate demand for forest products in four

(26)

different u s e r industries. Demand for sawnwood and panels a r e estimated for t h e construction a n d furniture industries. Demand for paper products a r e estimated for the printing and publishing industries a n d a s e c t o r which we call "the office sector." This means t h a t we con- c e n t r a t e this presentation to a limited subset of the seven products men- tioned above.

The econometric specification of t h e model is obtained as shown above by taking the derivatives of t h e s i m p l i f i e d Diewert cost function with r e s p e c t to t h e respective input prices

C ( y , p )

=

y

x

bij(pipj)Oa5 with t h e constraint bij

=

bji

i j

Dividing through by y , we obtain the normalized demand for the i t h pro- d u c t as a function of the input prices:

This m e a n s t h a t for each user s e c t o r t h e r e i s a system of demand equa- tions, i.e., one demand equation for each input.

The methods used to estimate those equations is Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) a n d Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SURE). Both methods yield unbiased a n d consistent estimates, but SURE is more efficient since we a r e dealing with systems of equations. The symmetric constraint, bij

=

b j i , also implies t h a t SURE is more accurate because one cannot easily incorporate t h e constraint when using OLS. A problem when using SURE is the short t i m e series. This means t h a t we have t o

(27)

choose a minimum of inputs because otherwise we will r u n out of degrees of freedom.

If

we, for example, use six inputs, t h e wood product included, the number of parameters to be estimated is 21 and our sam- ple consists of 10 observations only, which means t h a t we have insufficient degrees of freedom. Therefore, we have tried to aggregate inputs in a suitable way.

The results of t h e estimation are presented in Table 3, 4, 5, and 6 for each sector respectively. Cross-price and own-price elasticities are cal- culated for three different years, 1961. 1970, and 1970.

A positive value of the parameter indicates substitute for wood and a minus sign indicates a complementary relationship. The conclusion is that the estimated elasticities seem t o be reasonable in size and sign except for the printing and publishing sectors. Another conclusion is t h a t labor seems to be a complement to wood in t h e wood using sectors and substitute t o paper in paper using sectors.

(28)

TdBLE 3. Parameter estimates, construction sector, SURE.

Wood Services Cement Labor Wood

Services Cement

Labor 0.376***

(22.2) Cross-price elasticities Services Cement Labor versus wood

1960 0.50 0.053 -0.17

1970 0.60 0.062 -0.22

1978 0.48 0.050 -0.14

Own-price Elasticities Wood

1961 1970 1978

Significant a t the 10% probability level

**

Significant at the 5% probability level

***

Significant at the 1% probability level

TABLE 4. Parameter estimates, furpi ture sector (SURE).

Wood 0th.Mat. Labor

Wood Oth.Mat

labor

Cross-price elasticities 0th.Mat. Labor versus wood

Own-price elasticities Wood

1961 -0.68

1970 -0.75

Signidcant a t the 5% probability level

**

Signidcant at the 1% probability l w e l

(29)

TABLE 5. Parameter estimates, office sector, OLS.

Paper 0th.Mat. Labor

Paper R'

=

0.73

Cross-price e l a s t i c i t i e s 0th.Mat. Labor v e r s u s Paper

Own-price elasticities Paper

1961 1970 1978

-

***

Significant at the 1% probability level.

TABLE 6. Parameter estimates, printings and publishing, O L S . ~

Paper Services Labor

Paper 0.61*** 0.77

***

0.34***

(9.75) (8.0) (9.3)

R~

=

0.86

D-W =

2.17

This sector is only estimated for the period 1961-1974.

***

Significant a t the 1% probability level.

(30)

10. CONCLUSIONS AND DIRECI'IONS

FOR

FLTRTHER SrUDIES

Our analysis a n d t h e econometric s t u d y b a s e d on it clearly shows t h a t an i n t e r m e d i a t e demand approach i s t h e only consistent procedure t o be used in d e m a n d analysis for t h e forest sector. This is also observed partially in t h e construction of t h e global t r a d e model, where, e.g., t h e demand for pulp is d e t e r m i n e d within t h e model itself a n d n o t by exo- genous d e m a n d forecasts. The next s t e p t o be t a k e n is t o formulate macro-demand functions i n which t h e u s e of e.g. wood is r e l a t e d to t h e level 0.f c o n s t r u c t i o n a n d f u r n i t u r e o u t p u t a n d t o t h e prices of t h e substi- t u t e and c o m p l e m e n t i n p u t s t o wood in t h e s e sectors. A possible input-output equation would t h e n be, e.g.,:

1

sawnwood i n p u t

1 -

lprice of i - t h i n p u t 10.5

[,I

[ c o n s t r u c t i o n

+ a

f u r n i t u r e o u t p u t ]

-

~ b i ~ w o o d [ price of sawnwood

]

+

' U [ T ]

where

t =

time.

Such a m a c r o approach would avoid t h e n e e d for d a t a from t i m e s e r i e s of 1-0 tables.

(31)

Bergman.

L.

and

A

Por. 1980.

A

Quantitative General Equilibrium Model of the Swedish Economy. WP-80-04. Laxenburg, Austria: Interna- tional Institute for Applied Systems Analysis.

Diewert. W.E. 1971.

An

Application of the Shepard Duality Theorem:

A

Generalized Leontief Production Function. Journal of Political Econ- o m y . 79(3).

Doran, H.E. and D.F. Williams. 1982. The Demand for Domestically Pro- duced Sawntimber:

An

Application of the Diewert Cost Function.

A u s t ~ d i a n . Jounaul of Agricultural Economics, August.

Frenger. P. 1978. Factor Substitution in the Interindustry Model and the use of Inconsistent Aggregation. Chapter V.2. in Fuss and MacFad- den. Reduction E c o n o m i c s : A Dual Approach t o Theory a n d Applica- tiats. Amsterdam: North-Holland. 1978.

Frenger, P. 1983. The Generalized Leontief Cost Function in the Short- and in the Long-Run. Oslo: Central Bureau of Statistics Nonvay.

Henderson,

J.M.

and

R.E.

Quandt. 1980. h r o e c o n o m i c 7Aeory,

A

k l a t h e m a t i c d m u c h . 3rd Edition. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Johansen,

L

1959.

A

h4uLtisectord Q u d y of Economic Q r o w t h Amster- dam: North-Holland.

Nerlove,

M.

1965. B t i m c z t i n n a n d

Identification

of Cobb-Douglas Produc- t i o n A m c t i o n s . Amsterdam: North-Holland.

(32)

Shephard. 1953. Cost and Production finctions, Princeton: Princeton University Press.

Zalai,

E.

1980. A Non-Linear Multisectoral Model for Hungary. WP-80- 148. Laxenburg, Austria: International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

immature gap between the techniques which are currently in practice and potentially available technologies.. The future of forest-based products is threatened by competition

This problem is solved by the program FMPS, a SPERRY-UNIVAC pro- gram for solving large mathematical programming problems. The solu- tion produced by FMPS is printed

A comparis- on of these forecasts with the forecasts of demand for basic wood products until 2020 (Table 2) shows that except for non-coniferous sawnwood, none of

projection of forest-products demand, and will discuss alternative economic scenarios that can be used as input to the model system for projection..

Ecological, environmental, and socio-economic factors are included in this definition (Andersson et al, 1984).. On the one hand, biologically speaking, wood is

The r a t e of production is constrained by wood supply (which is one of the major links between t h e submodels), by final demand for forest products, by labor

It is shown that an intermediate demand approach is preferable to t h e common final demand procedures of forest product demand studies.. Markku Kallio

The objective of the Forest Sector Project a t IIASA is to study long-term development alternatives for the forest sector on a global basis. The emphasis in