• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Dynamical systems forced by shot noise as a new paradigm in the interest rate modeling

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Dynamical systems forced by shot noise as a new paradigm in the interest rate modeling"

Copied!
42
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

SFB 649 Discussion Paper 2010-037

Dynamical systems

forced by shot noise as a new paradigm in the interest rate modeling

Alexander L. Baranovski*

* WestLB AG

This research was supported by the Deutsche

Forschungsgemeinschaft through the SFB 649 "Economic Risk".

http://sfb649.wiwi.hu-berlin.de ISSN 1860-5664

S FB

6 4 9

E C O N O M I C

R I S K

B E R L I N

(2)

Dynamical systems forced by shot noise as a new paradigm in the interest rate modeling

Alexander L. Baranovski (WestLB AG)

Abstract. In this paper we give a generalized model of the interest rates term structure including Nelson-Siegel and Svensson structure. For that we introduce a continuous m- factor exponential-polynomial form of forward interest rates and demonstrate its considerably better performance in a fitting of the zero-coupon curves in comparison with the well known Nelson-Siegel and Svensson ones. In the sequel we transform the model into a dynamic model for interest rates by designing a switching dynamical system of the considerably reduced dimension n < m generating the forward rate curves in form a càdlàg function. A system is described by n-th order linear differential equation driven by a stochastic or chaotic shot noise. From fitted forward rates we specify the parameters of the switching system and discuss perspectives of our models to produce term-structure forecasts at both short and long horizons.

Keywords: forward interest rates, shot noise processes, switching dynamical systems, chaotic Brownian subordination, chaotic maps

JEL classification: C13, C20 and C22

Disclaimer: The ideas presented below reflect the personal view of the author and are not necessarily identical to the official methodology used at WestLB AG

Acknowledgements: The partial financial support from the Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft via SFB 649 “Ökonomisches Risiko” is gratefully acknowledged

1. Exponential-polynomial models of interest rates

We introduce an exponential-polynomial term structure model of interest rates by

=

= +

=

1

1 0

0( , ), ( , ) ( ) exp( )

) , (

l

i

i i

l f t Z f t Z t t

c Z t

f ϕ γ (1)

(3)

where z c cpl l Z Rm

l ∈ ⊂

={ ,..., , ,..., } : 1(1) ( 1) 1 1

1 γ γ , t > 0 denotes time to maturity T,

=

= pi

k k i k

i t c t

1 1 )

) (

ϕ ( are polynomials of degree pi −1 with coefficients ck(i) ; k =1,...,pi (pi

{

1,2,3,...

}

) and γi are positive real numbers. The total number of parameters in (1) is m p l

l

i i +

=

= 1

1

.

We note that the widely used Nelson-Siegel (N-S) [Nelson 1987] and Svensson (SV) [Svensson 1994] families of f(t) can be easily derived from (1). Assuming l =2 and

1 =2

p , p2 =1, i.e. dimensionality m=4, (1) leads to N-S forward rate curve

fNS(t)=(c1(1)+c2(1)t)⋅exp(−γ1t)+c2 (2) as well as the SV curve is given by

3 2 )

2 ( 1 1 )

1 ( 2 ) 1 (

1 ) exp( ) exp( )

( )

(t c c t t c t c

fSV = + ⋅ −γ + ⋅ −γ + (3)

with l=3, p1 =2 and p2 =1, p3 =1 i.e. m = 6.

Another special case of (1) is a curve of the exponentials mixture underpi =1,∀i, i.e.

( ) ∑

( )

=

+

=

1

1

exp

l

i

l i i

EXP t c t c

f γ (4)

We show that a performance of a new term structure (1) in a fitting of the yields is considerably higher of the well known Nelson-Siegel and Svensson ones. By other words a today’s choice of the parameters in (1) is to be not limited by the state space

R4

Z ⊂ as for the N-S curve or ZR6 in the Svensson model, i.e. ZRn,n≥6. The corresponding term structure of the bond prices will be then given by

( )



−

=

t f x Z dx

Z t B

0

, exp

: ) ,

( at ZRn

2. ODE for the interest rate models

We establish that dynamics of the interest rates f (t) in a model (1) follows a n-th order ODE

(4)

where 1

1

1

+

=

= l

i

pi

n , pi is the multiplicity of the root γi, i =1,...,l of the corresponding characteristic polynomial

=

+

=

1

1

) (

n

i

i n i n

D γ γn β γ (6)

The coefficients of the ODE are given by the Vieta formula

<

<

<

= − ⋅ ⋅

n

i i i

i i i j j

n

j

... j

~

~

~

2 1

2

1 ...

) 1

( γ γ γ

β (7)

with γ1~2~ =...=γ~pi1, ~ 1 ~ 2 ~ 2

2 1 1

1 γ ... γ γ

γp+ = p+ = = p+p = and so on.

Example (Nelson-Siegel).

Recall that the Nelson-Siegel model corresponds to the case l =2 and p1 =2. Then 3

1 +1=

= p

n , γ1~2~1 and γ3~2 =0. It follows that

( )

( )

0 )

1 ( : ) 3 (

) 1 ( : ) 2 (

2 )

1 ( : ) 1 (

~ 3

~ 2

~ 1 3 0

2 1

~ 3

~ 2

~ 3

~ 1

~ 2

~ 1 2 1

1

~ 3

~ 2

~ 1 1 2

=

=

=

= +

+

=

=

= + +

=

=

γ γ γ β

γ γ γ γ γ γ γ β

γ γ

γ γ β

j j j

Thus, the corresponding differential equation is 0 2 1 ′′+ 12 ′=

′′−

f f

f γ γ .

It is easy to check that the Nelson-Siegel curve f(t)=c1+(c2 +c3t)⋅exp(−γ1t)

is a general solution of the ODE as a combination of the two obvious particular solutions of r′=0 and r′′−2γ1r′+γ12r =0, such that

2 1 1

1

) 0 ( ) 0 ( ) 2 0

( γ γ

f f f

c ′′

′ + +

= , 2

1 1

2

) 0 ( ) 0 2 (

γ γ

f

c f ′′

′ −

= ,

1 3

) 0 ) (

0

( γ

f f

c ′′

′ −

= . (8)

Example (Svensson).

By analogy to the previous example the SV curve follows a 4th order ODE in the form

(5)

( )IV

(

2 1 2

) (

12 2 1 2

)

12 2 0 f − γ +γ f′′′+ γ + γ γ f′′−γ γ f′=

Generally ODE (5) can be presented in a matrix form

( )

, 0

d t T

d tf=F γf ≤ ≤ (9)

where f =









−1 1 0

fn

f f

M ,









= γl

γ γ M

2 1

γ , F =

( ) ( ) ( )

0 1 1

0 1 0 0

0 0 1 0 0

0 0 1 0

0 0 1

β β βn

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

− − − 

γ γ γ

L L

M O O O M

L L L L L

L L L

and

( )

t t f d f d i

i

i ≡ .

Eq. (9) has a vector solution f

( )

t =eF( )γtf

( )

0 .

Define by

( )

tτ f

(

t Zτ

)

r , := , (10)

the instantaneous forward rate at time t for date τ and by

(

τ

)

r

( )

t τ f

(

Zτ

)

r 0, limt , 0,

0 =

= (11)

the short rates, where stochastic process Zτ with values in ZRm contains two groups of processes {c1(1)

( )

τ ,...,c(pll11)

( )

τ } and {γ1

( )

τ ,...,γl1

( )

τ } such that the processes

( )

τ

j

ci depend on the stochastic processes {γ1

( )

τ ,...,γl1

( )

τ } and the short rates (initial conditions) as shown by (8) for a Nelson-Siegel term structure.

Taking into account (9), (10) the evolution of the forward rates on the date τ is given by

d

( )

d tr= F γτr (12)

(6)

Assuming Zτis given τ – evolution of r (t, τ) can be described by two different ways.

First one presents τ – evolution of r (t, τ) as a train of curves (12) for dates τ = 1, 2,…

in a form (see Fig. 1)

( )

i

( )

, 0

i

d t i T t

d tr=F γτ ⋅ +r

ξδ − ⋅ ≤ ≤ ∞ or equivalently

( ) ( )

d t T

d tr=F γτ ⋅ +r ξτδ − ⋅τ , (13) where +1



= T

τ t is a counting process ( t denotes the floor function ( largest integer smaller or equal to t ) and

(

0, 1

) (

T,

)

τ = τ+τ

ξ f Z f Z . (14)

We call the vector ξi as the stochastic amplitude of the impulse perturbation, which acts on system (13) at times t = τT, τ = 1,2,3, …. such that

(

τ ⋅T +0,τ

)

=r

(

τ⋅T −0,τ

)

τ

r .

Thus r is a cadlag function, i.e. a right continuous function r

(

τT +0,τ

)

r

(

τT,τ

)

,

defined on Rn and has a left limit.

Between kicks iT and (i +1)T a state vector is governed by the homogeneous system of linear differential equations (12) at τ = i+1.

Fig. 1 illustrates the system (13) with a jump ξ1f

(

0,Z2

)

f

(

T,Z1

)

at t = T

0 5 10 15 20 t

0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 rHtL

Fig.1 Train of the two first curves with T = 10 years.

(7)

The solution to (13) is explicitly given by

( )( ( ) )

( )

 

 ×

 

 ⋅∑

=

= =

1

1

1 exp i

i j i j

T t

F T F

e

r γ ξ

τ τ

τ γτ

where we denote ξ0r

( )

0 .

The second approach is based on a simple idea to express a random variable f

(

t,Zτ

)

by f

(

t,Zτfixed

)

+ζ

( )

t in the interval 0≤tT . By other words we assume that

dynamics of the interest rates r (t, τ) can be modelled by

, 0 ,

dr= F rdt+dζ ≤ ≤t T ∀τ (15) where F is a n x n matrix with the constant coefficients βi βi

(

γfixed

)

for any τ . The model (15) generates a predicted term structure, whose exponential-polynomial shape depends on the model parameters and the initial short rate. One can show that (15) is more general and includes a class of equilibrium models such as Vasicek, CIR, lognormal models.

3. Approach I – demonstrating example: from estimating the yield curve to its dynamic modelling

First we empirically estimate processZτ. For that we are going to fit the default-free yield spreads, downloaded from the Reuters database. The observable time period is 23.02. 2006 – 14.01. 2008, i.e. contains q = 478 dates. In framework of the above exponential-polynomial approach we introduce a term structure model of yields curves by

( )

=

t

dx Z x t f Z t Y

0

1 , : ) ,

( (16)

(16) can be easily done in a closed form. For this we need the relation [Prudnikov 1981]

(8)

( )

!1, 0,1,2,...,

0

= +

= +

t xkeγxdx Mk t eγt γkk k where

( )

0

(

!

)

! 1, <0

= − +

= γ

γi

i k k

k i

t i k t k

M .

Substituting the model (1) into (16) leads to

( )

( )

( )

=

=

 

 −

+

− +

= l li kpi ki k k k t M t c

c Z t

Y 1 11 1 1 1!

) ,

( γ (17)

We introduce a minimization criterion as:

( ) ( ( ) ( ) )

i Z

i

i Y t Z

N1 s , 2 min

=

τ τ

τ

ρ (18)

where

{

si

( )

τ , i=1,2,...,Nτ

}

are quotes of the yields on the base dateτ . The cost function ρ

( )

τ is to be minimized by the appropriate choice of the m p l

l

i i +

=

= 1

1

parameters of the state space Z. It is clear that in the fitting problem the following restriction

( )

Z p l

( {

N q

} )

m

l

i

i min , 1,..., dim

1

1

=

≤ +

=

=

=

τ τ (19)

is to be provided.

Given the number l of the parameters γl, i=1,...,l and distribution of their multiplicitiespl,i=1,...,l such that the condition (19) holds the nonlinear regression technique for the least squares criterion (18) leads to the minimum of the cost function with the optimal parameters c cpl l Z Rm

l , ,..., }∈ ⊂ ,...,

{ 1(1) ( 1) 1 1

1 γ γ .

We extend the criterion (7) by

( )

pl

p l q

q 1 ,min1,...,

1 →

=

τ=

τ ρ

ρ (20)

with the obvious restrictions for the parameters

{

1,2,3,...

}

, ,

, p1 pZ+ =

l K l . (21)

We note that (20) according to a law of large numbers/ Birkhoff ergodic theorem approaches the mean of the stochastic/ chaotic cost function withq→∞.

The problem (18)-(21) for euro swap rates has the following twofold solution

(9)

1) l =5, pl =1, pi =3,i=1,...,l−1 and { 1(1),..., ( 1), 1,..., 1} 17

1 Z R

c

c pl l

l γ γ ∈ ⊂ (m =17,

τ =60,∀τ

N ) for a “laminar” period of the observed yields quotes on the bond market:

(

355

)

07 . 07 . 17 ) 1 ( 06 . 02 .

23 τ = − τ =

2) l =5, pl =1, pl1=1,pi =3,i=1,...,l−2 and { 1(1),..., ( 1), 1,..., 1} 15

1 Z R

c

c pl l

l γ γ ∈ ⊂

(m=15) for a “turbulence” period 18.07.07

(

τ =356

)

14.01.08(τ =478) .

The above calculated m+l+1 parameters specify a general term structure model of interest rates by the exponential-quadratic curves (1) ( pl =3 ) as well as a general term structure model of yields by the exponential-cubic curves (17).

Fig. 2 demonstrates a performance of the general model for the Euro swap rates by comparison of its cost function (18) with the cost functions of the conventional Nelson-Siegel and Svensson models and exponential model (4) with l = 6.

0 100 200 300 400 tdays

0.005 0.010 0.015 0.020 0.025 cost functionrHtL

Fig. 2 Comparison of the cost functions for the observable time period: 23.02. 2006 – 14.01. 2008. N-S is a green curve, SV is a black, the exponential is a blue, and the general model is a red curve.

Moreover the ratios 00074 9 . 0

00653394 .

0 ≈

=

GEN NS

ρ

ρ , 6

00074 . 0

00419495 .

0 ≈

=

GEN SV

ρ

ρ and 5

00074 . 0

0039557 .

0 ≈

=

GEN EXP

ρ

ρ (22)

quantify the performance of the general model with the derived optimal exponential-

(10)

with l = 6, respectively.

The mean of the cost function (20) for the exponential model (4) has a local minimum at l = 6 in value ρEXP =0.0039 and at l =5 in value ρGEN =0.00074 for a general model as shown in Fig. 3.

0 1 2 3 4 5 6 l-1

0.001 0.002 0.003 0.004 0.005 0.006 0.007

rHlL

Fig. 3. The means of the cost functions: blue curve – exponential and red one – general model

Fig. 4 collects all base curves fitted to the available data on the date 25.03.08 .

0%

1%

2%

3%

4%

5%

6%

7%

8%

9%

1 34 67 100 133 166 199 232 265 298 331 364 397 430 463 496 529 562 595

Maturity in months

%

GOVCHF GOVEUR GOVGBP GOVJPY GOVUSD GOVRUB SWAPCHF SWAPEUR SWAPGBP SWAPJPY SWAPUSD

Fig. 4 Fitted zero curves on the spot date 25.03.08

Repeating a fitting procedure to the another date, let’s say τ +1 = 26.03.08, we get a similar set of the base curves (16) which can be described by the system (13), where the impulse perturbation ξτ (14) is to be predetermined.

As an example we design a dynamical system for N-S instantaneous forward rate curve

( ) ( ( ) ( ) )

exp( ) )

,

(t c1 c2 c3 t t

r τ = τ + τ + τ ⋅ −γτ described by the following low-dimensional ODE

(11)

(

t T

)

r r

r′′′−2γτ ′′+γτ2 ′=ξτδ −τ⋅ (23) where

(

1

)

2

(

1

)

1

( )

( 2

( )

3

( )

) exp( )

1 c c c c T T

c τ

τ τ τ τ τ τ γ

ξ = + + + − − + ⋅ − . (24)

according to (10) and (14).

From the output of the above fitting procedure we retrieve the time series

( ) ( ) ( )

{

c1τ ,c2 τ ,c3 τ ,γττ =1,2,K,q=478

}

for the observable time period.

Applying (24) we immediately get time series of stochastic perturbation.

Let us introduce the k-th order increments for both processes ξττ by

τ τ

τ ξ ξ

ξ k k

k =∆ −∆

+1 +1 (25)

τ τ

τ γ γ

γ k k

k =∆ −∆

+1 +1 , (26)

where ∆0 ≡1, k = 0, 1, 2, ….

We are now able to do an elementary statistical analysis of both processes ξττ.

Table 1 contains the histograms of the processes and Table 2 collects the histograms of the increments.

Histogram of γτ Histogram of ξτ

2 4 6 8 10

0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140

-0.015 -0.01 -0.005 0

0 10 20 30 40 50 60

Table 1.

(12)

Histograms of the increments ∆kγτ, k =1,10 Histograms of the increments ∆kξτ,k =1,10

-4 -2 0 2 4

0 50 100 150

-0.004 -0.002 0 0.002 0.004

0 50 100 150

-400 -200 0 200 400

0 20 40 60 80 100 120

-1 0 1 2

0 50 100 150

Table 2.

We note that the both processes are diffusion processes characterized by symmetrical bell-like but not-Gaussian distributions of their increments. A χ2 Pearson’s test with the confidence level 0.95 rejects a hypothesis of the independence of the increments for both forced signal

ξτ and γτ.

The means of ∆kγτand ∆kξτ,∀k ≥1 are zeros. The sample variances σ2kγ2kξ grow exponentially with the order k as shown in Fig. in a log scale

(13)

10 20 30 40 k

-10 0 20 30 40 50 ln@s2_Dg&xHkLD

Fig.5. Red line islnσ2kξ, black line is lnσ2kγ

A distance between the above two lines does not remain constant with k but grows slowly with rate ln 2 0.00594878

2

k k

k

dk d

ξ γ

σ

σ . It means that a variance of the ∆kγτ grows a bit quicker

than a variance of ∆kξτ,∀k≥1. The sample autocorrelation functions

( ) ( )

,...

2 , 1 , 0 ,

1 2 1

=

− ∆

= −

=

+

j

j k j q

C

j k q

j k

k k

k

τ

τ τ γ

γ σ γ γ

(27)

( ) ( )

,..

2 , 1 , 0 ,

1 2 1

=

− ∆

= −

=

+

j

j k j q

C

j k q

j k

k k

k

τ

τ τ ξ

ξ σ ξ ξ

(28)

are presented in Table 3.

(14)

Autocorrelations of ∆kγτ, k =1,10, 20 Autocorrelations of ∆kξτ, k =1,10, 20

10 20 30 40 t

-0.5 0.5 1.0 acf_xHtL

10 20 30 40 t

-1.0 -0.5 0.5 1.0 acf_xHtL

Table 3.

To estimate a mutual correlation of ξτ and γτ and their increments we introduce the Pearson product-moment correlation coefficient [Norman L. Johnson 1995]

(

,

)

; 0,1,...; 0,1,...

1 1 1

=

=

− ∆

= −

=

+

j k

j k k q

j R

j k q

j k

k k

k

τ

τ τ ξ

γσ ξ γ

σ (29)

depicted in Figures 6 – 8.

Fig. 6 . Geometric interpretation of the matrix R of dimension 40x40

(15)

-0.8 -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8

1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 41 43 45 47 49 51 53 55 57 59 61

R(j,0) R(j,1) R(j,10) R(j,20)

Fig. 7 The Pearson’s correlation coefficient at j = 0,1,…,60; k = 0, 1, 10, 20

-0.8 -0.6 -0.4 -0.2 0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8

1 3 5 7 9 11 13 15 17 19 21 23 25 27 29 31 33 35 37 39 41 43 45 47 49 51 53 55 57 59 61

R(0,k) R(1,k) R(10,k) R(20,k)

Fig. 8 The Pearson’s correlation coefficient at j = 0,1,10,20; k = 0, 1, …, 60

(16)

4. Approach II – forcing signal as a shot noise

We note that applying Vieta formula (7) at j = n the coefficient β0 is equal to zero since 0

l =

γ . It implies that a general solution of the ODE (5) is a combination of the obvious solution of f′=0 and the particular solution η(t) of

0 ... 1

) 3 ( 2 ) 2 ( 1 ) 1

( + f + f + + f =

f n βn n βn n β (30)

i.e. f = ≡ +r η c.

We are specifically interested in the behaviour of the system (30) with a shot noise as a chaotic/stochastic perturbation, i.e.

( )

( )

, 0

N t

i i

i

d t t t T

d tη=F⋅ +η

Aδ − ≤ ≤ (31)

0 1

2 n

η η η

 

 

 

= 

 

 

η M ,

1 2 1

0 1 0 0

0 0 0

0 0 1 0

0 0 1

n n

β β β

 

 

 

 

= 

 

 

 

− − − 

 

F

L

M O O O L L

L L L L L

.

where tk are successive occurrence or arrival times of δ-impulses,

( )

0 0 1 ... k ...

t = <t < <t < <T

{

k t t

}

t

N( )=max : k ≤ is a counting process.

The impulse perturbation acts on system (31) at times t = tk, k = 1,2,3, …. such that

(

tk +0

)

=

(

tk0

)

+ k

η η A . (32)

In sequel we assume that η is a càdlàg function.

We introduce the positive inter-arrival times Tk such that

=

+ =

=

k

i i k

k

k t T T

t

1

1

Between kicks a state vector is governed by the following homogeneous system of linear

(17)

differential equations

d

dtη= ⋅F η

and the initial condition of the system η0η

(

t0+0

)

defines an evolution of a state vector (Cauchy theorem).

4.1. One-dimensional case

We consider a special case of (31) in a form of one-dimensional ODE:

( )

( )

, 0

N t

i i

i

d A t t t T

d tη=

δ − ≤ ≤ (33)

4.1.1. Response to a Shot Noise. The generalized Wiener process

Integrating Eq. (33) we immediately get a solution

(34)

A plot of the process η is depicted in Fig.

ηk

ηk+1

η

tk tk+1 t Tk

Fig. 9. A solution of Eq. (1)

Thus the process η(t) (Fig. 9) is a rectangular signal with step heights ηk satisfying the relation:

1

k k Ak

η

=

η

+ (35)

Probability density function

( )

( ) ( )

( )

1

(0) 0

N t

k N t

k

t A

η η η

=

=

≡ =

(18)

We first establish that the distribution function of η(t) is

( ( ) ) ( ) ( )

1

k k

k

P η t z P t P η z

=

≤ =

≤ ,

where P tk

( )

=P t

(

k1 ≤ <t tk

)

=P N t

( ( )

=k

)

.

We assume zero mean for the magnitudes Ak . It immediately implies that η(t) is a martingale with a zero mean

( ) ( ( ) ) ( )

0

(

0

) (

|

( ) ) ( ) ( )

E η =E N t E A = A= as E η N t =N t E A (36)

To calculate a variance of η (t) we use a law of total variance

( ) (

|

( ) ) (

|

( ) )

D η =E D η N t +D E η N t  One can show that the conditional variance is

( ( ) ) ( ) ( )

( ) 1

( )

1

| 2 ( ) ( )

N t

A n

D η N t N t D A N t n c n

=

= +

− (37)

where c kA( )=E A A

(

i i k+

)

is the autocorrelation function (acf) and σA2D

( )

A is the variance of the Ak.

Hence, for i.i.d. random or uncorrelated chaotic magnitudes Ak (cA(k)=0) we have

( )

( ) 0

( ) ( ( ) ) ( ( ) )

2

( ) ( )

A t

c n

D η D A E N t D N t E A D A N

= = + = (38)

where

( ) { ( ) } { }

( )

t k

t t

k k k

N H t kP N t k P t t t

E t

>>

≡ =

= =

< is the intensity function.

For correlated random/chaotic Ak we assume that the first moment of the autocorrelation function cA(k) is finite

( )

1 A k

k c k

=

< ∞

(39)

and then the variance is given by

( )

2 k 2 o 1

σ = σ + . (40)

(19)

Let us introduce a new variable

k

k k

k

η

η η

ε σ

= − with E

( )

εk =0 and E

( )

εk2 =1 . It can be shown that εk converges in distribution to the standard normal law, i.e. the central limit theorem holds both with i.i.d.random [Feller] and chaotic magnitudes Ak [Chernov 1995]. In [Baranovski 2003], authors have presented the analytical expressions for the characteristic functions of the chaotic partial sums ηkof the magnitudes Ak generated by PWL onto maps and shown their fast convergence to the limit exp

(

ω2/ 2

)

.

We consider a piecewise constant function Wk

( )

t on t

[ ]

0,1 such that

(41)

where   x is the floor function (it gives the greatest integer less than or equal to x).

Then for any k

{ }

Wk induces a measure on the space of continuous functions on [0,1] . According to the invariance principle this measure converges weakly, as k→ ∞, to the Wiener process W [Chernov 1995 ] Fig. 10 depicts examples of functions

{ }

Wk for different k when the magnitudes Ak are chaotic variables generated by a tent map on [-1,1]:

1 1 2 , 1, 2,...

n n

A+ = − A n= (42)

Fig. 10 Three realizations of the process W for k =100,300 and 10000 (red, green and blue

0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1

t -2

-1.5 -1 -0.5 0 0.5 1

WkHtL

( ) ( ) ( ) [ ]

1

1 , 0,1 , 0,1,...,

kt k t

L i

i

W t A t k L

D A L D A L

η   

=

= =

∈ =

(20)

The weak invariance principle known also as the functional central limit theorem provides an approximation deterministic dynamical systems by a Brownian motion on large space and time scales.

Thus the distribution of η(t) tends to the Gaussian law with the mean (36) and variance (38).

This confirms the diffusion character of η(t). It follows that the Eq. (33) can be used for stochastic and chaotic modeling of the Wiener process.

Example 1. Valuation of the European call option.

The underlying asset of the European option is assumed to grow at the constant risk-free rate r perturbed by a stochastic/chaotic marked point process η(t). Thus an asset price is modeled as (43) Properties:

1) Markov property: the next asset price (S+dS) depends solely on today’s price 2) The next value for S is higher than the old by an amount

3) Variance of dS is

We want to price a call option, i.e.

(

,

)

r t

( )

r t

( ( ) ) ( )

|

( )

k

C t K =e− ⋅ E SK +=e− ⋅

P N t =kE SK + N t =k, (44) where K is a strike price. We calculate a conditional expectation

( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ( ) )

( ) (

( )

( ) ) ( )

( )

0

0

0

0

, |

ln

k ln

k

r t t

x x k

K K

K

C t K E S K N t k x K P S x N t k

x K P S e x N t k x K P x r t

S

x dx

x K p r t

S x

η

η

η

+ +

⋅ +

 

=  − = = − ∂ ≤ = =

   

− ⋅ ∂ ≤ = = − ⋅ ∂  ≤  − ⋅ =

   

− ⋅   − ⋅ 

∫ ∫

% %

%

(45)

where 2 2

( )

2 , r r D A

T σ σ

= − =

% .

( ) (

2

)

2

( ) (

2

( )

2

)

2

( )

2

( ) ( )

D dS =E dSE dS =E S dη =S D dη =S D A dH t dS rdt d

S = + η

( )

(

( )

0)

E dS =rSdt as E dη =

(21)

A pdf of ηk can be found via its characteristic function. We note that

( ) ( )

1

k , ,

k

p k

p

E i A

ψη ω ω ω ω ω

=

 

=  = Θ

K (46)

where

( ) ( )

1 2 1 1

1 1

X

( , ,..., ) exp k exp k ( ,..., ) ...

k k i i i i A k k

i i

E i A i x p x x dx dx

= =

 

Θ ω ω ω =  ⋅∑ω = ⋅∑ω ⋅ ⋅

 

∫ ∫

L (47)

is a k-dimensional characteristic function of a sequence

{

A1,K,Ak

}

having a joint pdf

(

k

)

A x x x

p 1, 2,K .

For a case of i.i.d. random values Ak (46) simplifies to

( )

ω

( )

ω

ψη k

k1 (48)

where 1( )ω eiωxpA( )x dx

Χ

Θ =

is the characteristic function of the distribution of Ak .

Here we focus on a special case of (46) when the magnitudes Ak are generated by a chaotic mapping

(

1

)

= k

k A

A ϕ (49)

in an interval X.

A joint pdf does not factorize in this case and calculates as

1

( )

1 2 1 1 1

1

( , ,..., ) ( ) ( ( ))

k

i

A k A i

i

p x x x p x δ x ϕ x

+

=

= ⋅

, (50)

where pA (x) is the invariant density of the map ϕ .

The goal equation (46) simplifies for piece-wise linear onto maps

( )

x

{

i

( )

x a x b xi i, J ii, 1, 2,...,m

ϕ = ϕ = + ∈ = (51)

such that ∀i: :ϕ JiX =

(

0,1

)

.

We collect their main probabilistic properties:

• The invariant density is uniform with 1

A=2 and variance 2 1

A 12 σ =

• The autocorrelation function is

(22)

A property (39)-(40) can be easily illustrated with the exponentially decaying acf.

We next substitute the acf (52) into (37) and get

( )

( )

2 2 2

2

1 2 1

1 1

k

k

A A

r r

k r

r r

ση = σ −σ

+ −

This confirms (39) at large k as rk0.

The characteristic function can be also calculated analytically. Substituting (50) into (47) for the inner integral we have

( )

1 1 1 1

1

1

1 2

( 1) 1 ( 1)

2 1 1 1 1 1 1

1 1 ( )

( 2) 2

1

(

3 2

1

( ( )) ... ( ( )) ( ( ( ))

1 ( ) ... ( )

1 ( ( )) ...

l l

l l

l l

k m

i v x k i v x i

k i l

l J i x z

m i v z b

a k

k

l l

x b

m i v

a k

k

l l

e x x x x dx e x x dx

e x z x z dz

a

e x x x

a

ϕ

δ ϕ δ ϕ δ ϕ ϕ

δ δ ϕ

δ ϕ δ ϕ

+

= =

Χ =

⋅ ⋅

= Χ

⋅ ⋅

=

⋅ − ⋅ ⋅ − = ⋅ −

= ⋅ ⋅ − ⋅ ⋅ −

= ⋅ ⋅ − ⋅ ⋅ −

∑ ∏

∫ ∫

∑ ∫

∑ (

2)( ) .x2

)

Hence the following recurrence equation can be obtained

1 1

1 1 2 3

1

( ,..., ) 1 ( , ,..., )

l l

m i b

a

k k k k

l l l

a e a

ω ω

ω ω − ⋅ ⋅ ω ω ω

=

Θ =

⋅ ⋅Θ +

the solution of which is

1 1

1

1 2 1

1 1 1 1

1 1

, ,..., 1 1 1

1 1

( ,..., ) ,

p

k k

n ip

n p n l n il

k n p

k i b k

m k

a

k k n k

i i i n i n p n i

e a

a

ω

ω ω ω ω

= = =

− ⋅

= = = =

 

 

Θ = ⋅ Θ  ⋅ + 

 

∑ ∏ ∑ ∏

(53)

where

1 1

0

( ) ( ) 1

i

i x i x

A

e p x dx e dx e i

ω

ω ω

ω Χ ω

Θ =

=

= − is the characteristic function of the uniform distribution. Setting ω12 =K=ωk =ω in (53) and substituting the result into (46) we first get a characteristic function and then a required pdf of ηk by use an inverse Fourier transform. In [Baranovski 2003] authors have shown a fast convergence of the characteristic function Θk( ,..., )ω ω of the cumulative sum

1 k

k p

p

η A

=

=

to

( )

2 2

cos exp

2 ω ση

η ω − 

 , which is the characteristic function of a normal distribution with the mean η and variance ση2.

For example, a tent map on the unit interval has the following characteristic function [Baranovski 2003]

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

The mean temperature rise given in the IPCC TAR to 2100 is shown for comparison (IPCC, 2001); it is lower than the PAGE09 mean result because of the lower, 2.5 degC,

The performance of these optimized interest-rate rules is then evaluated across alternative, potentially competing models with regard to their ability to stabilize inflation and

By the same way, Figures 5 to 8 report the impulse responses of domestic macroeconomic variables this time in the second specification to a positive standard deviation disturbance

The costs are normally pooled by nature (OAP – Education), which can be divided into intermediate and final objectives, that is intermediate and final activities. The Breakdown

Besides, by imposing the market balance to be equal to the sum of the balances demanded by investors, the mean return and the volatility of the market portfolio are expressed as the

Si un individuo A consume un determinado resultado productivo, y la unidad de servicio de dicho resultado coincide con su unidad de consumo, no quedarían unidades de

The group observed that the Register covers the bulk of the global arms trade in the seven categories of conventional arms, since almost all significant suppliers and recipients

Now money is non-neutral, and an increase in β still implies a smaller inflation bias (and, thus, a lower benefit from cooperating for both the government and the union), but