• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

The equivalence of mini-max theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in asymmetric three-players zero-sum game with two groups

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "The equivalence of mini-max theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in asymmetric three-players zero-sum game with two groups"

Copied!
11
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Munich Personal RePEc Archive

The equivalence of mini-max theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in

asymmetric three-players zero-sum game with two groups

Satoh, Atsuhiro and Tanaka, Yasuhito

9 June 2018

(2)

The equivalence of mini-max theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in

asymmetric three-players zero-sum game with two groups*

Atsuhiro Satoh

Faculty of Economics, Hokkai-Gakuen University, Toyohira-ku, Sapporo, Hokkaido, 062-8605, Japan,

and

Yasuhito Tanaka

Faculty of Economics, Doshisha University, Kamigyo-ku, Kyoto, 602-8580, Japan.

Abstract

We consider the relation between Sion’s minimax theorem for a continuous func- tion and a Nash equilibrium in an asymmetric three-players zero-sum game with two groups. Two players are in Group A, and they have the same payoff function and strategy space. One player, Player C, is in Group C. Then,

1. The existence of a Nash equilibrium, which is symmetric in Group A, implies Sion’s minimax theorem for pairs of a player in Group A and Player C with symmetry in Group A.

2. Sion’s minimax theorem for pairs of a player in Group A and Player C with sym- metry in Group A implies the existence of a Nash equilibrium which is symmet- ric in Group A.

Thus, they are equivalent.

Keywords: three-players zero-sum game, two groups, Nash equilibrium, Sion’s minimax theorem

JEL Classification: C72

*This work was supported by Japan Society for the Promotion of Science KAKENHI Grant Number 15K03481 and 18K01594.

atsatoh@hgu.jp

yasuhito@mail.doshisha.ac.jp

(3)

1 Introduction

We consider the relation between Sion’s minimax theorem for a continuous function and existence of a Nash equilibrium in an asymmetric three-players zero-sum game with two groups1. Two players are in one group (Group A), and they have the same payoff function and strategy space, and so their equilibrium strategies, maximin strategies and minimax strategies are the same. One player, Player C, is in the other group (Group C). We will show the following results.

1. The existence of a Nash equilibrium, which is symmetric in Group A, implies Sion’s minimax theorem for pairs of a player in Group A and Player C with symmetry in Group A.

2. Sion’s minimax theorem for pairs of a player in Group A and Player C with symmetry in Group A implies the existence of a Nash equilibrium which is symmetric in Group A.

Thus, they are equivalent.

An example of such a game is a relative profit maximization game in a Cournot oligopoly.

Suppose that there are three firms, A, B and C in an oligopolistic industry. Let ̄𝜋𝐴, 𝐵̄𝜋 and

̄𝜋𝐶be the absolute profits of the firms. Then, their relative profits are

𝜋𝐴 = ̄𝜋𝐴− 12( ̄𝜋𝐵 + ̄𝜋𝐶), 𝜋𝐵 = ̄𝜋𝐵 − 12( ̄𝜋𝐴+ ̄𝜋𝐶), 𝜋𝐶 = ̄𝜋𝐶− 12( ̄𝜋𝐵 + ̄𝜋𝐶).

We see

𝜋𝐴+ 𝜋𝐵+ 𝜋𝐶= ̄𝜋𝐴+ ̄𝜋𝐵+ ̄𝜋𝐶− ( ̄𝜋𝐴+ ̄𝜋𝐵+ ̄𝜋𝐶) = 0.

Thus, the relative profit maximization game in a Cournot oligopoly is a zero-sum game2. If the oligopoly is fully asymmetric because the demand function is not symmetric (in a case of differentiated goods) or firms have different cost functions (in both homogeneous and differentiated goods cases), maximin strategies and minimax strategies of firms do not correspond to Nash equilibrium strategies. However, if the oligopoly is symmetric for two firms in one group (Group A) in the sense that demand function is symmetric and two firms have the same cost function, the maximin strategies for those firms with the corresponding minimax strategy of the firm in the other group (Group C) constitute a Nash equilibrium which is symmetric in Group A. In Appendix we present an example of a three-firms relative profit maximizing oligopoly.

1In Satoh and Tanaka (2018a) we have analyzed a similar problem in a symmetric zero-sum game in which all players are identical.

2About relative profit maximization under imperfect competition please see Matsumura, Matsushima and Cato (2013), Satoh and Tanaka (2013), Satoh and Tanaka (2014a), Satoh and Tanaka (2014b), Tanaka (2013a), Tanaka (2013b) and Vega-Redondo (1997)

(4)

2 The model and Sion’s minimax theorem

Consider a three-players zero-sum game with two groups. There are three players, A, B and C. The strategic variables for Players A, B and C are, respectively,𝑠𝐴,𝑠𝐵,𝑠𝐶, and (𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) ∈ 𝑆𝐴×𝑆𝐵×𝑆𝐶. 𝑆𝐴,𝑆𝐵and𝑆𝐶are convex and compact sets in linear topological spaces. The payoff function of each player is 𝑢𝑖(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶), 𝑖 = 𝐴, 𝐵, 𝐶. They are real valued functions on𝑆𝐴× 𝑆𝐵× 𝑆𝐶. We assume

𝑢𝐴,𝑢𝐵 and𝑢𝐶are continuous on𝑆𝐴× 𝑆𝐵 × 𝑆𝐶, quasi-concave on𝑆𝑖for each 𝑠𝑗 ∈ 𝑆𝑗, 𝑗 ≠ 𝑖, and quasi-convex on𝑆𝑗for𝑗 ≠ 𝑖for each𝑠𝑖 ∈ 𝑆𝑖, 𝑖 = 𝐴, 𝐵, 𝐶.

Three players are partitioned into two groups. Group A and Group C. Group A includes Player A and Player B, and Group C includes only Player C. In Group A two players are symmetric, that is, they have the same payoff function, and𝑆𝐴 = 𝑆𝐵. Thus, their equilib- rium strategies, maximin strategies and minimax strategies are the same.

Since the game is a zero-sum game, we have

𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) + 𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) + 𝑢𝐶(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 0, (1) for given(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶).

Sion’s minimax theorem (Sion (1958), Komiya (1988), Kindler (2005)) for a continuous function is stated as follows.

Lemma 1. Let𝑋 and 𝑌be non-void convex and compact subsets of two linear topological spaces, and let𝑓 ∶ 𝑋 × 𝑌 → ℝbe a function that is continuous and quasi-concave in the first variable and continuous and quasi-convex in the second variable. Then

max𝑥∈𝑋 min

𝑦∈𝑌𝑓(𝑥, 𝑦) =min

𝑦∈𝑌max

𝑥∈𝑋 𝑓(𝑥, 𝑦).

We follow the description of this theorem in Kindler (2005).

Let𝑠𝐵 be given. Then,𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶)is a function of𝑠𝐴and𝑠𝐶. We can apply Lemma 1 to such a situation, and get the following equation.

𝑠max𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶). (2) Note that we do not require

𝑠max𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 min

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐶(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 max

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐶(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶),

𝑠max𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵 max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶)given𝑠𝐶.

We assume that arg max𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴min𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶)and arg min𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶max𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) are unique, that is, single-valued. By the maximum theorem they are continuous in𝑠𝐵.

3

(5)

Also, throughout this paper we assume that the maximin strategy and the minimax strat- egy of players in any situation are unique, and the best responses of players in any situation are unique. Similarly, we obtain

𝑠max𝐵∈𝑆𝐵 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶), (3) given𝑠𝐴3.

Let𝑠𝐵 = 𝑠. Consider the following function.

𝑠 → arg max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠, 𝑠𝐶).

Since𝑢𝐴is continuous,𝑆𝐴and𝑆𝐶are compact and𝑆𝐴 = 𝑆𝐵, this function is also contin- uous. Thus, there exists a fixed point. Denote it by .̃𝑠 ̃𝑠satisfies

arg max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶) = ̃𝑠.

From (2) ̃𝑠satisfies

𝑠max𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶). (4) From symmetry for Players A and B, ̃𝑠also satisfies

arg max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐵( ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = ̃𝑠,

and max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐵( ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐵( ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶).

3 The main results

Consider a Nash equilibrium of a three-players zero-sum game. Let𝑠𝐴,𝑠𝐵,𝑠𝐶 be the values of𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶which, respectively, maximize𝑢𝐴given𝑠𝐵and𝑠𝐶, maximize𝑢𝐵given𝑠𝐴and 𝑠𝐶, maximize𝑢𝐶given𝑠𝐴and𝑠𝐵in𝑆𝐴× 𝑆𝐵× 𝑆𝐶. Then,

𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) ≥ 𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶)for all𝑠𝐴 ∈ 𝑆𝐴, 𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) ≥ 𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶)for all𝑠𝐵 ∈ 𝑆𝐵, and 𝑢𝐶(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) ≥ 𝑢𝐶(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶)for all𝑠𝐶 ∈ 𝑆𝐶.

3We do not require

𝑠max𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 min

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐶(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵max

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐶(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶),

𝑠max𝐵∈𝑆𝐵 min

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶).

(6)

They mean

arg max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 𝑠𝐴, arg max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 𝑠𝐵,

and arg max

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐶(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 𝑠𝐶, .

We assume that the Nash equilibrium is symmetric in Group A, that is, it is symmetric for Player A and Player B. Then,𝑠𝐵 = 𝑠𝐴, and𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶). Also we have

𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶).

Since the game is zero-sum,

𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) + 𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 2𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 2𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = −𝑢𝐶(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶).

Thus,

arg min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) =arg max

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐶(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 𝑠𝐶,

and arg min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) =arg max

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐶(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 𝑠𝐶. They imply

𝑠min𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶),

and min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶).

First we show the following theorem.

Theorem 1. The existence of a Nash equilibrium, which is symmetric in Group A, implies Sion’s minimax theorem for pairs of a player in Group A and Player C with symmetry in Group A.

Proof. 1. Let(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶)be a Nash equilibrium of a three-players zero-sum game. This means

𝑠min𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) ≤ max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) (5a)

= min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) ≤ max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶), for Player A.

𝑠min𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) ≤ max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) (5b)

= min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) ≤ max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶), 5

(7)

for Player B.

On the other hand, since

𝑠min𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) ≤ 𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶), we have

𝑠max𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) ≤ max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶).

This inequality holds for any𝑠𝐶. Thus,

𝑠max𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) ≤ min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶).

With (5a), we obtain

𝑠max𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶). (6a) Similarly, for Player B we can show

𝑠max𝐵∈𝑆𝐵 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶). (6b) (5a), (5b), (6a) and (6b) imply

𝑠max𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶),

𝑠min𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶),

𝑠max𝐵∈𝑆𝐵 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶),

𝑠min𝑐∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶).

From min

𝑠𝑐∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) ≤ 𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶),

and max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶), we have

arg max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) =arg max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 𝑠𝐴. Also, from

𝑠max𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) ≥ 𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶),

(8)

and min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶), we get

arg min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) =arg min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 𝑠𝐶. Similarly, we can show

arg max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) =arg max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 𝑠𝐵 = 𝑠𝐴,

and arg min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = arg min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = 𝑠𝐶. Therefore,

arg max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) =arg max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶),

and arg min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) =arg min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐵(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶).

Next we show the following theorem.

Theorem 2. Sion’s minimax theorem with symmetry in Group A implies the existence of a Nash equilibrium which is symmetric in Group A.

Proof. Let ̃𝑠be a value of𝑠𝐵 such that

̃𝑠 =arg max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶).

Then, we have

𝑠max𝐴∈𝑆𝐴 min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶). (7) Since

𝑢𝐴( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶) ≤ max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶),

and min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶), we get

arg min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶) =arg min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶). (8) Since the game is zero-sum,

𝑢𝐴( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶) + 𝑢𝐵( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶) = 2𝑢𝐴( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶) = −𝑢𝐶( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶).

7

(9)

Therefore,

arg min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶) =arg max

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐶( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶).

Let 𝐶̂𝑠 =arg min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶) =arg max

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐶( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶). (9) Then, from (7) and (8)

𝑠min𝐶∈𝑆𝐶 max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶) = max

𝑠𝐴∈𝑆𝐴𝑢𝐴(𝑠𝐴, ̃𝑠, ̂𝑠𝐶) = min

𝑠𝐶∈𝑆𝐶𝑢𝐴( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐶) = 𝑢𝐴( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, ̂𝑠𝐶). (10) Similarly, we can show

𝑠max𝐵∈𝑆𝐵𝑢𝐵( ̃𝑠, 𝑠𝐵, ̂𝑠𝐶) = 𝑢𝐵( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, ̂𝑠𝐶). (11) (9), (10) and (11) mean that(𝑠𝐴, 𝑠𝐵, 𝑠𝐶) = ( ̃𝑠, ̃𝑠, ̂𝑠𝐶)is a Nash equilibrium which is sym- metric in Group A.

4 Concluding Remark

In this paper we have examined the relation between Sion’s minimax theorem for a con- tinuous function and a Nash equilibrium in an asymmetric three-players zero-sum game with two groups. We want to extend this result to more general multi-players zero-sum game4.

Appendix: Example of relative profit maximizing three-firms oligopoly

Consider a three-players game. Suppose that the payoff functions of players are

𝜋𝐴 = (𝑎−𝑥𝐴−𝑥𝐵−𝑥𝐶)𝑥𝐴−𝑐𝐴𝑥𝐴−12[(𝑎−𝑥𝐵−𝑥𝐴−𝑥𝐶)𝑥𝐵−𝑐𝐵𝑥𝐵+(𝑎−𝑥𝐶−𝑥𝐵−𝑥𝐴)𝑥𝐶−𝑐𝐶𝑥𝐶], 𝜋𝐵 = (𝑎−𝑥𝐵−𝑥𝐴−𝑥𝐶)𝑥𝐵−𝑐𝐵𝑥𝐵−12[(𝑎−𝑥𝐴−𝑥𝐵−𝑥𝐶)𝑥𝐴−𝑐𝐴𝑥𝐴+(𝑎−𝑥𝐶−𝑥𝐵−𝑥𝐴)𝑥𝐶−𝑐𝐶𝑥𝐶], and

𝜋𝐶 = (𝑎−𝑥𝐶−𝑥𝐵−𝑥𝐴)𝑥𝐶−𝑐𝐶𝑥𝐶−12[(𝑎−𝑥𝐴−𝑥𝐵−𝑥𝐶)𝑥𝐴−𝑐𝐴𝑥𝐴+(𝑎−𝑥𝐵−𝑥𝐴−𝑥𝐶)𝑥𝐵−𝑐𝐵𝑥𝐵].

This is a model of relative profit maximization in a three firms Cournot oligopoly with con- stant marginal costs and zero fixed cost producing a homogeneous good.𝑥𝑖’s,𝑖 = 𝐴, 𝐵, 𝐶, are the outputs of the firms. The conditions for maximization of𝜋𝑖, 𝑖 = 𝐴, 𝐵, 𝐶, are

𝜕𝜋𝐴

𝜕𝑥𝐴 = 𝑎 − 2𝑥𝐴− (𝑥𝐵 + 𝑥𝐶) − 𝑐𝐴+ 12(𝑥𝐵+ 𝑥𝐶) = 0,

4Satoh and Tanaka (2018b) is an ealier version of such a research.

(10)

𝜕𝜋𝐵

𝜕𝑥𝐵 = 𝑎 − 2𝑥𝐵 − (𝑥𝐴+ 𝑥𝐶) − 𝑐𝐵 + 12(𝑥𝐴+ 𝑥𝐶) = 0,

and 𝜕𝜋𝐶

𝜕𝑥𝐶 = 𝑎 − 2𝑥𝐶− (𝑥𝐵 + 𝑥𝐴) − 𝑐𝐶+ 12(𝑥𝐵+ 𝑥𝐴) = 0.

The Nash equilibrium strategies are 𝑥𝐴 = 3𝑎 − 5𝑐𝐴+ 𝑐𝐵+ 𝑐𝐶

9 , 𝑥𝐵 = 3𝑎 − 5𝑐𝐵 + 𝑐𝐴+ 𝑐𝐶

9 , 𝑥𝐶 = 3𝑎 − 5𝑐𝐶+ 𝑐𝐵 + 𝑐𝐴

9 . (12)

Next consider maximin and minimax strategies about Player A and Player C. The con- dition for minimization of𝜋𝐴with respect to𝑥𝐶is𝜕𝜋𝜕𝑥𝐴

𝐶 = 0. Denote𝑥𝐶which satisfies this condition by𝑥𝐶(𝑥𝐴, 𝑥𝐵), and substitute it into𝜋𝐴. Then, the condition for maximization of𝜋𝐴with respect to𝑥𝐴given𝑥𝐶(𝑥𝐴, 𝑥𝐵)and𝑥𝐵 is

𝜕𝜋𝐴

𝜕𝑥𝐴 + 𝜕𝜋𝜕𝑥𝐶𝐴

𝜕𝑥𝐶

𝜕𝑥𝐴 = 0.

It is denoted by arg max𝑥𝐴min𝑥𝐶𝜋𝐴. The condition for maximization of𝜋𝐴 with respect to𝑥𝐴is 𝜕𝜋𝜕𝑥𝐴

𝐴 = 0. Denote𝑥𝐴which satisfies this condition by𝑥𝐴(𝑥𝐵, 𝑥𝐶), and substitute it into𝜋𝐴. Then, the condition for minimization of𝜋𝐴with respect to𝑥𝐶given𝑥𝐴(𝑥𝐵, 𝑥𝐶)

is 𝜕𝜋𝐴

𝜕𝑥𝐶 + 𝜕𝜋𝜕𝑥𝐴𝐴

𝜕𝑥𝐴

𝜕𝑥𝐶 = 0.

It is denoted by arg min𝑥𝐶max𝑥𝐴𝜋𝐴. In our example we obtain arg max

𝑥𝐴 min

𝑥𝐶 𝜋𝐴 = 3𝑎 − 4𝑐𝐴+ 𝑐𝐶

9 , arg min

𝑥𝐶 max

𝑥𝐴 𝜋𝐴 = 6𝑎 − 9𝑥𝐵− 2𝑐𝐴− 4𝑐𝐶

9 .

Similarly, we get the following results.

arg max

𝑥𝐵 min

𝑥𝐶 𝜋𝐵 = 3𝑎 − 4𝑐𝐵 + 𝑐𝐶

9 , arg min

𝑥𝐶 max

𝑥𝐵 𝜋𝐵 = 6𝑎 − 9𝑥𝐴− 2𝑐𝐵 − 4𝑐𝐶

9 .

If𝑐𝐴 ≠ 𝑐𝐵, arg max𝑥𝐴min𝑥𝐶𝜋𝐴 ≠arg max𝑥𝐵min𝑥𝐶𝜋𝐵, and they are not equal to the Nash equilibrium strategies for Players A and B. However, if𝑐𝐵 = 𝑐𝐴, we have

arg max

𝑥𝐴 min

𝑥𝐶 𝜋𝐴 =arg max

𝑥𝐵 min

𝑥𝐶 𝜋𝐵,

and those strategies and the Nash equilibrium strategies for Players A and B are equal.

Further, when𝑐𝐵 = 𝑐𝐴 and

𝑥𝐴 = 𝑥𝐵 = 3𝑎 − 4𝑐𝐴+ 𝑐𝐶

9 ,

we get

arg min

𝑥𝐶 max

𝑥𝐴 𝜋𝐴 =arg min

𝑥𝐶 max

𝑥𝐵 𝜋𝐵 = 3𝑎 − 5𝑐𝐶+ 2𝑐𝐴

9 .

This is equal to the Nash equilibrium strategy for Player C when𝑐𝐵 = 𝑐𝐴.

9

(11)

References

Kindler, J. (2005), “A simple proof of Sion’s minimax theorem,”American Mathematical Monthly,112, pp. 356-358.

Komiya, H. (1988), “Elementary proof for Sion’s minimax theorem,”Kodai Mathematical Journal,11, pp. 5-7.

Matsumura, T., N. Matsushima and S. Cato (2013) “Competitiveness and R&D competi- tion revisited,”Economic Modelling,31, pp. 541-547.

Satoh, A. and Y. Tanaka (2013) “Relative profit maximization and Bertrand equilibrium with quadratic cost functions,”Economics and Business Letters,2, pp. 134-139, 2013.

Satoh, A. and Y. Tanaka (2014a) “Relative profit maximization and equivalence of Cournot and Bertrand equilibria in asymmetric duopoly,” Economics Bulletin,34, pp. 819-827, 2014.

Satoh, A. and Y. Tanaka (2014b), “Relative profit maximization in asymmetric oligopoly,”

Economics Bulletin,34, pp. 1653-1664.

Satoh, A. and Y. Tanaka (2018a), “Sion’s minimax theorem and Nash equilibrium of sym- metric three-players zero-sum game,” mimeograph.

Satoh, A. and Y. Tanaka (2018b), “On the relation between Sion’s minimax theorem and existence of Nash equilibrium in asymmetric multi-players zero-sum game with only one alien,” mimeograph.

Sion, M. (1958), “On general minimax theorems,”Pacific Journal of Mathematics,8, pp.

171-176.

Tanaka, Y. (2013a) “Equivalence of Cournot and Bertrand equilibria in differentiated duopoly under relative profit maximization with linear demand,”Economics Bulletin, 33, pp. 1479-1486.

Tanaka, Y. (2013b) “Irrelevance of the choice of strategic variables in duopoly under rela- tive profit maximization,”Economics and Business Letters,2, pp. 75-83, 2013.

Vega-Redondo, F. (1997) “The evolution of Walrasian behavior,”, Econometrica, 65, pp.

375-384.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

Working Papers are interim reports on work of the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis and have received only limited review.. Views or opinions

However, for these legal mechanisms to work China must first come to the realization that the South China Sea boundary dispute cannot be solved by military and economic power

• Every r-player normal form game and every graphical game of degree d can be mapped in polynomial time to (a) a 3-player normal form game and (b) a graphical game with degree 3 and

In this work we are going to use the excess demand approach to prove the existence of equilibrium [2, Section 3]: we just impose conditions a function should possess to be the

The game between the kicker and goalkeeper in soccer penalty kicks is a real-world game that can be used to examine the application of the MSNE concept or its accuracy because

Moreover, we characterize the victory domains by means of geometrical condi- tions (it is the discriminating kernel of a closed set).. This characterization is used

We shall prove bellow that, in some cases, there is no satisfying definition of the game for Carath6odory strategies: Either the game does not satisfy the alternative

Even though China has passed the first law targeting money-laundering, the EU keeps criticizing that China’s current market barriers, intellectual property violations, and continuous