• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Market and Firm – Two Sides of a Coin

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Market and Firm – Two Sides of a Coin"

Copied!
13
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Market and Firm – Two Sides of a Coin

1

Carsten Holtmann and Dirk Neumann University of Karlsruhe carsten.holtmann@iw.uni-karlsruhe.de

dirk.neumann@iw.uni-karlsruhe.de

Abstract

Electronic markets are not just evolving they are designed. As such providing elec- tronic trading venues is an entrepreneurial activity. The institutional approach fol- lowed here introduces a market operator as an economic player. As the entrepre- neur charges fees for his service of operating an electronic market, the transaction cost savings incurred by information technology are essentially fully shifted to the market participants. As such the momentum predicted by the Electronic Market Hypothesis is limited in practice. The paper addresses this gap by deriving a con- ceptual framework, which reconciles the classical view on electronic markets with the entrepreneurial view.

1 Introduction

„Although economists claim to study the working of the market, in modern economic theory the market itself has an even more shadowy role than the firm. […]

In the modern textbook, the analysis deals with the determination of market prices, but discussion of the market itself has entirely disappeared”

[Coase 1988]

In their famous Electronic Market Hypothesis (EMH) Malone, Yates et al. predicted that coor- dination in general will shift from hierarchical to market coordination as information technology is more extensively used [Malone et al. 1987]. The reason for this shift stems from the overall reduction of transaction costs. Interestingly enough, this shift has empirically not yet been ob- served. Obviously, markets work better in theory than in practice. One reason is that in theory electronic markets are frequently reduced to resource allocation mechanisms. In this case, the contorting effects induced by the market operator, that acts as an economic player in a socio- economic system are by assumption neglected.

1 This material is based upon work supported by the Alexander-von-Humboldt foundation, the Federal Ministry of Education and Research, and the Social Sciences and Humanities Research Council of Can- ada.

(2)

From a more practical point of view, an electronic market is not merely an abstract allo- cation mechanism, but rather the provision of facilities for resource allocation by an entrepre- neur. The provision of these facilities constitutes a service, which is basically the entrepreneur’s product.2 The provision of those trading services comprises the choice of an attractive business segment, which hallmarks the firm’s basic problem: which services to produce and in what quantities [Spulber 1999]. But what makes a business segment attractive? Attractiveness mainly stems from the potential agents who may want to enter the business segment. Apparently, the problem for whom particular goods are produced becomes an important factor of success. Fur- thermore, the notion of the problem how and to which costs to produce is important. The pro- duction costs of the entrepreneur have to be compensated by fees charged for the trading ser- vices. The price for the trading service marks the amount of the (explicit) transaction costs each market participant has to face. The question to which price the services are sold completes the set of relevant problems the operator has to solve.

Electronic trading systems reduce the production costs an entrepreneur faces when pro- viding the resource allocation facility to others. But, only if those cost savings are passed over to the market participants, their transaction costs decrease.

The potential extent of declines in the market participants’ transaction costs is marked through technology advancement. The realized extent depends on the market operator’s deci- sion to hand over cost reductions. This decision is typically influenced by the industry structure and the competition he faces.

Hence, the momentum of the EMH is limited due to the impact of a (profit-oriented) market operator. The traditional view on markets as resource allocation mechanisms needs amendments to work for electronic markets.

Accordingly, this paper provides two major extension of the microeconomic system framework (see chapter 2), namely

(i) the inclusion of the market operator as an actor on the market for market ser- vices, and,

(ii) the introduction of the infrastructure and the business structure of electronic markets, which comprise the production technology as well as the relevant as- pects of the market operator’s business model.

First, we start with some methodological considerations about frameworks. Subsequently, we present the microeconomic system framework in brief, which will be the starting point for our extensions. These extensions presents an industry and a firm view on markets by introducing a profit-oriented market operator. Having pointed at the similarities to ordinary service providers, the challenges of Market Engineering and their peculiarities are illustrated. The paper concludes with summary and further research.

2 Methodological Issues

Before the microeconomic system framework is presented, it is useful to discuss the notion of a economic framework in distinction to economic models. This more methodological debate high- lights the properties a good framework must provide and how it can be used.

Generally, there are many ways to build theory that advances both knowledge and prac- tice. On a broad level, literature identifies two feasible approaches, models and frameworks [Porter 1991].

2 Throughout the paper the terms product and service are regarded as synonyms.

(3)

Models, on the one hand, usually make use of mathematical formalism. For tractability reasons the models impose more or less strict restrictions. This abstraction confines the degree of complexity of the real world problem and thus isolated specific effects. Accordingly, restrict- ing the model to some key variables whose interactions are examined in depth provides clear conclusions. These conclusions are, however, very sensitive to the underlying assumptions and the applied equilibrium concept. Porter thus concludes, that “the normative significance of each model depends on the fit between its assumptions and reality” [Porter 1991]. The sensitiveness does not diminish the value of models, taking into account that the real value of models lies in developing intuition [Mcafee/Mcmillan 1996].

Frameworks, on the other hand, seek to capture much of the complexity of the real world by encompassing several variables. Note, that a framework identifies and structures the relevant variables. Furthermore, it also reveals the interactions between the variables. As such, the theory inherent in a framework is contained by the choice of the variables, their organization, their in- teractions and finally the relationship among the variables. Unlike models, frameworks often cannot decisively determine all the interactions among the variables. Sometimes frameworks are offended because their inherent complexity makes it pretty difficult to falsify the stated argu- ments. Nonetheless, frameworks grant the researcher a comprehensive overview over the prob- lem domain, the concepts, i.e. the variables, and their relationship.

Frameworks and models are not necessarily contradicting each other. Rather are these ap- proaches complementary: Models, on the one hand, can explore the concise interaction among a limited number of variables taken out of the framework. By using formal logic, even subtle ef- fects can be isolated and studied. Frameworks, on the other hand, present a more comprehensive view on the problem domain and hence demonstrate which important variables were omitted in the various models. As such, frameworks incite the development of formal models.

The benefit of frameworks in general is threefold:

● Identification of the key parameters

It is supposed to explain, either graphically or in narrative form, the main things to be studied – the key parameters, constructs or variables – and the presumed interaction among them [Miles/Huberman 1994].

● Clarification of the chain of causality

The framework clarifies the chain of causality between the parameters, constructs or vari- ables.

● Comprehensive Overview

The framework is supposed to present a comprehensive overview about the various the- ory streams of the studied field. The depiction of the sometimes contradicting views in literature may help to recognize the nature of the effects and the underlying assumptions.

More accentuated, the framework ideally provides the comprehensive range of the field, such that it allows connecting the sub-problems with the entire topic.

3 Electronic Market Framework

The view presented here is motivated by Coase. Identifying markets and hierarchies to be alter- native (extreme) coordination mechanisms in 1937 [Coase 1937], he perceives in 1988: „[…]

the provision of markets is an entrepreneurial activity […]” [Coase 1988]. The electronic mar- ket is conceived to be the product (or service) of a firm called market operator. In this under- standing market and firm are two sides of the same coin.

(4)

The microeconomic system framework (see Figure 1) appears to be a good starting point for detailed analysis of electronic markets since it provides a comprehensive, generic descrip- tion of any conceivable resource allocation process. This basic framework developed by Mechanism Design theorists Smith illustrates that any resource allocation process relies on a very few well accepted concepts: At heart, it distinguishes between the economic environment and the institution which together form the microeconomic system [Smith 1982, Smith 2002]3.

The environment determines demand and supply situation for a set of resources, which is exogenously given. Within the boundaries of the institutional rules the participating agents for- mulate their needs in terms of an order language the institution provides. Subsequently, the in- stitution also determines the outcome of the market process, which basically means the concrete assignment of the resources. Individual behavior is hence affected by the institution, which de- limits personal actions and the information and incentive structure of the system. How exactly the agents behave is subject to a behavior theory, e.g. utility maximization. The choice and transfer rule determine the outcomes, i.e. resource allocation and the corresponding payments.

Subsequently, the performance of the system is calculated by evaluating the outcomes with re- spect to the environment.

Economic Environment (agent preferences, cost, resources, knowledge)

Institution

(language of market, rules of communication and of contract, procedural stucture) Agent Behavior

(based on dispersed private information given the institution) Outcomes

(allocations, prices)

Performance (efficiency, pricevolatility)

Fig. 1: Microeconomic System Framework [Smith 2002]

In order to generalize this framework in a way that it can also capture electronic markets, two major extensions are necessary, which will be presented in the following.

3.1 Extension 1

Electronic markets are operated by (profit-maximizing) firms rather than a benevolent, ficti- tious mechanism.

In the microeconomic system framework the resource allocation process is defined by a mechanism. Basically, a mechanism is a mathematical function, which takes the strategies of the agents as inputs and renders the allocation and corresponding payments as outputs [Jackson 2002]. This mathematical formulation can be interpreted as follows. The resource allocation process is regulated by a benevolent auctioneer. The trading rules are common knowledge, so the only thing agents have to do is to submit their strategy schedule. Since the allocation is free of charge the fictitious auctioneer maximizes the utility of the society.

In electronic markets the assumption of a benevolent, fictitious auctioneer is no longer maintainable. Instead a firm called market operator is supposed to assume the responsibilities of the fictitious auctioneer. Unlike the auctioneer, the market operator controls the market process for profit reasons or at least for cost recovery. In addition, the market operator also undertakes other entrepreneurial tasks, i.e., investments in the infrastructure [Di Noia 1999].

3 Extending the work of Hurwicz [1973].

(5)

The basic chain of causalities of microeconomic system framework, however, still holds even in this adapted setting. Surely, the concepts need some amendments to cope with the var- ied set of assumptions. The amended framework is illustrated in Figure 2 where the left panel depicts extension 1 and the right extension 2.

The economic environment does not only comprise factors that determine demand and supply, it also contains factors that determine the behavior of the market operator. Suppose the market operator is partly owned by a group of investors. Their interests and demands (the cor- porate governance) affect the business policy of the market operator. Accordingly, the economic environment is redefined as basic conditions and refers to all factors that are outside the control of the market operator. The term market operator disguises the fact that the firm is an institution as well. Contracts among the interested groups of the firm basically constitute the firm. Those institutional rights affect the conduct of the firm. The managers conduct their entrepreneurial activities based upon their contracts. Analogous to industrial firms, market operators are ex- posed to competition. Accordingly, the operators are forced to offer the best service portfolio to the lowest possible fees if they want to remain active in the fierce competition [Porter 1980, Di Noia 1999].

In summary, beside the institution firm the decisions of the management are also depend- ent on the competitors in the market for markets. Taking institutions and competitors together yields the market structure. Conduct of the firm denotes all entrepreneurial activities of the eco- nomic actor (advertisement, research and development, etc.). The outcome of those activities is measured by the firm’s profit or other more specific measures (e.g. return on investment, return on capital employed, etc.) and is interpreted as its performance.

The extension of the microeconomic system to electronic markets describes the shift from a resource allocation view to an industry view. The industry view depicted in the left panel of Figure 2 sketches the market structure-conduct-performance framework known from industrial organization [Mason 1939, Bain 1968].

3.2 Extension 2

The product of an electronic market is the provision and the enforcement of institutional rules.

These rules not only comprise microstructure rules but also those concerning the infrastructure and business structure.

The service a market operator provides pertains to the design of the institutional rules.

The microstructure simply denotes the trading rules. As electronic markets are basically infor- mation systems designing electronic markets is consequently also a software engineering task.

The electronic market must be embedded in a balanced business structure; since the electronic market is the product a market operator wants to earn money with. This product mainly embod- ies a resource allocation process extended by business and infrastructure restrictions. Assuming that the operator can specify the transaction product, i.e., the resource that is to be allocated, it is not any more a full subset of the economic environment. The reason is straightforward: taking into consideration that the market operator can actively design via standardization the transac- tion product, it is not any more completely exogenously given.

In the sequel the trading services a market operator produces will be illustrated in greater detail. The three main questions what to provide, how to provide and how much to charge guide this illustration. Each question refers to a special perspective concerning the market structure, namely, microstructure, infrastructure, and business structure. These perspectives reflecting

(6)

various theory streams correspond to different views on the phenomenon electronic market. As such each perspective give rise to different sets of parameters of the market structure. The de- piction of all these structural parameters is neither possible today, nor will it be possible in the future. However, dividing the whole structure into disjunctive subsets may help to overcome the restrictions of a single theory stream. Firstly, partial-analyses in the isolated perspectives are still possible and valuable as they develop intuition. Secondly, total-analyses based on the elec- tronic market framework can help to come up with better and thus more practical predictions.

Once markets are conceived in their totality, theory and practice will not diverge any more.

What to provide – Microstructure

The microstructure perspective is concerned with the definition of the institution specifying the trading protocol.

Ever since the establishment of a separate discipline, Economics has been dealing with markets.

However, traditional theory abstracts from the specific market mechanism. Most of its models assume perfect information, which basically means that participants have all available informa- tion. Long before the Nobel price winners Stiglitz, Akerlof and Spence had started working on asymmetric information, Hayek already emphasized that the market process can communicate dispersed information which allows a better resource allocation [Hayek 1945]. The classical metaphor of the “Walrasian Auctioneer” assuming perfect information is inadequate to explic- itly explain the precise functioning of a market. New approaches therefore address these short- comings by incorporating aspects such as the working of institutions concerning risk and infor- mation allocation.

Institutions in general can be conceived as “humanly devised constraints imposed on human interaction” [North 1987]. These constraints can be either formal or informal. Formal constraints denote strict norms, codes, laws or similar rules, whereas informal constraints are (more or less) self-imposed codes of conduct. Both types of constraints govern the interaction among the humans that deal with each other in an institutional setting.

Stated differently, the institutions expose the property rights an agent is granted in the in- teraction process. Property rights pertain in this context to the communication process and not as usual to commodities. This rather unfamiliar view is easy to understand if the right to speak, the right to demand the resource, or the right to demand transfer payments are conceived as pri- vate property. Those private properties are defined and constituted by the institution [Smith 1982].

Institutions are frequently specified as consisting of four kinds of rules [Smith 1982, Wur- man/Wellman/Walsh 1998, Parkes 2001, Jackson 2002]:

● Language – the way offers can be specified

● Choice Rule – determining who gets what

● Transfer Rule – determining who pays what

● Adjustment Rules – determining the flow of the market process

Although not explicitly stated, alternative approaches characterizing institutional rules pretty much identify somewhat similar rules [Ostrom 1998, Gomber 2000, Ströbel/Weinhardt 2003].

As previously mentioned the design of the institutional rules defines the service of the market operator. Nonetheless, those rules must also be implemented in an adequate infrastruc- ture to make the service provision possible.

(7)

How to provide - Infrastructure

The infrastructure is concerned with the production technology the operator uses. In electronic markets this is primarily a question of how to use information technology.

Firstly, existing trading rules (microstructure) can be purely translated into an information system. The first electronic stock exchanges, for example, just implemented the rules of the ex- isting floor exchanges. The arguments for this electronification usually comprise efficiency as- pects: Trading processes can be performed faster and at lower costs. Furthermore, electronic markets do not require participants to be located at a certain floor to participate in the market, remote membership is possible. The potential regional range of the market becomes almost unlimited.

Secondly, information systems can also be used to design new markets, as IT facilitates the establishment of more complex trading methods that have desirable properties. In contrast to electronification, this is often referred to as electronization. For example mechanisms that allo- cate a product to the participant who values it most (economic efficiency) do exist in theory.

With the help of information technology such complex auctions, in this case the Generalized Vickrey Auction [Varian 1995, Ausubel/Milgrom 2002], can be practically computed. In this respect, the area of computational Mechanism Design aims at developing mechanisms that em- body desirable economic properties (e.g. strategy proofness, efficiency, revenue maximization) without incurring their disadvantages (e.g. computational tractability, information requirements) [Nisan/Ronen 2001, Bichler et al. 2002, Conitzer/Sandholm 2002].

The choice of the production technology is clearly a software engineering activity. But it naturally comprises hardware aspects, too. Security and integration issues also play a pivotal role in the operation of the electronic market. Operating targets in the choice for the best pro- duction technology also comprehend issues such as standardization, flexibility, and interopera- bility with other systems, e.g., markets or ERP (enterprise resource planning) systems. The bet- ter the market is integrated with the firms’ and customers’ information system landscape, the greater are the efficiency gains that can be achieved.

Overall, detailed studies how exactly the infrastructure affects the behavior of the market participants are currently missing. Only general results measuring the user adoption of informa- tion systems are available, but need adjustment to market settings [Chau 2001]. Nonetheless, in- frastructure design is not only a software engineering but also a Market Engineering activity.

How much to charge – Business Structure

The business structure is primarily concerned with the cost and revenue aspects of the service provision. Both depend on the overall strategy as well as the corporate governance of the firm.

Non-profit and for-profit organizations mark extreme points.

Traditional non-electronic markets such as floor stock exchanges were often established as non-profit organizations (registered associations). Interest groups co-operated in building an institution that typically minimized their trading fees to reduce the coordination costs. As a con- sequence of this registered association, all members together were responsible for the compa- nies’ decisions and strategies, and also, for the market structure. This shared responsibility re- sults in an institution that is characterized by balanced interests of the members [Hansmann 1996, Di Noia 1999].

In recent years registered associations have increasingly lost in importance as operators of markets [Domowitz/Steil 1999, Lee 2000]. Many stock exchanges have, for instance, been al- tered from registered associations to private firms [Di Noia 1998], new players have been

(8)

founded as private firms. No longer similar interests of members but heterogeneous interests of shareholders and customers have to be regarded, when the strategy of the market’s operator shifts from cost recovery to profit-maximization. Special problems appear between customers with and without ownership of the market, as the latter may have the power to prey the former.

Therefore, the challenge in the business design lies in the sound balancing of shareholders and non-shareholder interests. Especially the fee structure can be a very smooth setscrew to tune participants’ behavior by conceding privileges to selected groups or activities (e.g. liquidity provision).

Economics Environment (e.g., interests and demands of

market participants, legal environment...) Micro-

structure

Business- structure Infra-

structure Behavior of market participants

Outcome

Performance of theoperator/ theindustry

Transaction Product Trading Services

Performance of themarekt Competitors

Structure Conduct Outcome

Extension I: The market operator as an entrepreneur within an inductry

Extension 2: The market as the product of an entrepreneur

Basic Conditions (e.g., interests and demands of

share- and stakeholders, legal environment...) Market Operator

Market Structure

Figure 2: Electronic Market Framework

Figure 2 summarizes the extensions of the traditional resource allocation mechanism frame- work. Principally, the key parameters Environment, Institution, Behavior, Outcome, and Per- formance and their chain of causality remain relevant, albeit the parameters need refinement and specification:

● In the industry perspective this leads to a description, which resembles the Structure- Conduct-Performance Theory. This is not really a surprising finding, as markets are explicitly treated as firms.

● If the firm market operator is closer observed, it becomes obvious, that the provision of market services is its primary product. As such the microstructure defines the ser- vice, the infrastructure offers the medium for its provision, and the business structure primarily determines the revenue sources.

Apparently, the similarities between the market operator and any other typical service providers allow applying several theory streams of Economics and Management Science. Nonetheless, comprehensive amendments have to be performed, as the service definition, the center of the Market Engineering task, is very cumbersome, as the following section will demonstrate.

(9)

4 The Design of the Market as a Product

Market design is a highly complex task, even in its traditional understanding as microstructure design [Neumann et al. 2002]. Firstly, there is no perfect mechanism in a sense that there is no mechanism that attains an excellent market performance independent of the underlying envi- ronment, viz. the traded goods [Wellman/Wurman 1998]. Secondly, market mechanisms favor one group on the expense of others [O' Hara 1997]. Thirdly, details matter [Ockenfels/Roth 2002]. Only slight changes in the rules can totally sway the behavior of the agents. Fourthly, the design space is amazingly huge, making design a challenging and time consuming task [Wurman/Wellman/Walsh 1998].

In a Market Engineering – understood as the process of consciously designing all of the three perspectives [Weinhardt/Holtmann/Neumann 2003] – sense, the definition of the market operator’s product is even more complex as it requires not only designing the parameters of the microstructure but of all of the three structure perspectives. Gluing all three structural elements together can result in a closed, sound concept that is likely to be successful in the competition.

Contradictions between the design areas can, on the contrary, result in the overall failure of a market. Consequently, it is the interdependencies among the design areas that are critical factors to success.

All those three perspectives influence the behavior of the market participants. Suppose the following example: The participants will change their bidding behavior if no longer open but sealed bids (microstructure) are allowed, or, if face-to-face interaction is replaced with com- puter front-ends (infrastructure), or if transaction fees are increased (business structure).

The complexity of Market Engineering tremendously rises as the perspectives are closely intertwined. For example the renown C2C auction system eBay provides a proxy bidding pro- cedure which resembles a Vickrey Auction [Ockenfels/Roth 2002]. This electronic market gives rise for a phenomenon called sniping. Snipping basically denotes late bidding behavior of the participants. In traditional non-electronic auctions sniping was not a factor; once electronic me- dia is introduced the behavior swayed. Sniping, however, leads to distortionary effects. From a microstructure perspective it decreases the information feedback of the mechanisms and turns the last minutes of the auction from an open bidding process into a closed. From an infrastruc- ture perspective, sniping is undesired, because of the high amount of communication within the short period right before the end of the auction. Service providers cannot store their products and have therefore to align their capacities to peak loads. This is, however, from a business and infrastructure point of view highly undesirable, as it would require high-performance infrastruc- tures, which may be extremely expensive.

If the operator will mend the defected auction, he has to remedy the distortionary effect of the change in the infrastructure by a change in the trading rules. In the eBay example changing the stopping rule can prohibit sniping. Amazon offers a completely equal auction as eBay but the stopping rule. The institution states a soft stopping rule: Whenever a new bid is placed, the auction time is automatically prolonged. As a result bidding behavior is much more evenly dis- tributed over time [Ockenfels/Roth 2002]. If the engineer will adjust the defected auction, he can also remove the disturbing incentives by altering the business rules. For example the stock exchange EURONEXT charges a higher fee for each order entered during the two minutes preceding market close. This makes late bidding more costly which may outweigh the incentive to do so.

(10)

This example may demonstrate the complexity of the design task and hence creates a challenge for future research.

5 Conclusion

The present paper extends the traditional understanding of an electronic market. Instead of per- ceiving the market as a coordination mechanism, the market is defined as a product of a firm, which acts within the industry of market operators. The provision and enforcement of institu- tional rules for resource allocation is thus an entrepreneurial activity. Accordingly, we suggest adding two more perspectives to the analysis of electronic markets. This inclusion entails that three interdependent sets of rules, each representing a different perspective, constitute the insti- tution electronic market. Institutional rules ranging form the market microstructure over their realization by the means of information technology to the pricing affect the strategic behavior of the participants in the market and, consequently, the market outcome. The traditional under- standing of market performance thus also needs refining in a way that it can capture all three perspectives, not only the market microstructure.

The integration of the different perspectives into a conceptual framework aims at provid- ing a comprehensive overview that illustrates the key variables and their interdependencies. As such it can help to formulate more realistic models, which eventually may result in better pre- dictions. Consequently, the true potentials of electronic markets become more obvious if mar- kets are not assumed to be merely virtual mechanisms but products of economic entities.

Hitherto, scientific literature conceiving markets as firms is still in its infancy. Accord- ingly a deep pool of related research papers is missing [Schwartz 1995, Di Noia 1999, Lee 2000]. Nonetheless, the interpretation of markets as a firm’s product may strengthen the appli- cation of (general) business administration literature on electronic markets. Where applicable, it has to be adjusted to the special aspects of market operators.

Electronic markets are not only evolving they are also designed. However, currently there is no coherent design tool available that accounts for all three perspectives. Accordingly, further research has to be done in the development of appropriate design tools. Communication can be the key factor connecting all three perspectives. This reflects Hayek’s classical view on markets as communication system, the information technology view as inter-organizational information system and the business view as revenue source. By the emphasis on communication, it is pos- sible to retain the classical resource allocation framework as the basis for the electronic market framework. A resource allocation system is nothing more than a communication process, which is governed, monitored and enforced by institutional rules [Smith 2002]. Communication and its restrictions can obviously be captured by a communication model.

The demand for a coherent modeling of the integrated view can presumably be satisfied by communication modeling approaches provided by the discipline of computer science. Tools such as AUML, i.e. agent-oriented UML [Bauer/Müller/Odell 2001], appear to be promising to adequately model markets in their totality.

To make the statement “the market is a marvel” [Hayek in Williamson 1985] come true for electronic markets, too, it needs to overcome the perception of the electronic market as a mystery.

(11)

References

Ausubel, Larry; Milgrom, Paul R. (2002): Package Bidding: Vickrey vs Ascending Auctions, in: Revue Economique 53(3), 2002, pp. 391-402.

Bain, Joe (1968): Industrial Organization, New York, John Wiley & Sons, 1968.

Bauer, Bernhard; Müller, Jörg P.; Odell, James (2001): Agent UML: A Formalism for Specify- ing Multiagent Interaction, in: Ciancarini, P.; Wooldridge, M. [Eds.], Agent-Oriented Soft- ware Engineering, pp. 91-103, Springer, 2001.

Bichler, Martin; Kalagnanam, Jayant; Lee, Ho Soo; Lee, Juhnyoung (2002): Winner Determina- tion Algorithms for Electronic Auctions: A Framework Design, in: Bauknecht, K.; Tjoa, A.

M.; Quirchmayr, G. [Eds.], EC-Web, pp. 37-46, Springer, 2002.

Chau, P.Y.K. (2001): Influence of Computer Attitude and Self-Efficacy on IT Usage Behavior, in: Journal of End User Computing 13(1), 2001, pp. 26-33.

Coase, Ronald H. (1937): The Nature of the Firm, in: Economica N.S. 4 (November), 1937, pp.

386-405.

Coase, Ronald H. (1988): The Firm, the Market and the Law, Chicago, University of Chicago Press, 1988.

Conitzer, Vincent; Sandholm, Tuomas (2002): Complexity of Mechanism Design, in: 18th Con- ference on Uncertainty in Artificial Intelligence (UAI), Edmonton, Canada.

Di Noia, Carmine (1998): Customer Controlled Firms: The Case of Stock Exchanges. Working Paper 02/1998, Wharton School of Business. Philadelphia, PA.

Di Noia, Carmine (1999): The Stock-Exchange Industry: Network Effects, Implicit Mergers, and Corporate Governance. Rome, CONSOB - Commissione Nazionale per le Societa e la Borsa, No. 33.

Domowitz, Ian ; Steil, Benn (1999): Automation, Trading Costs, and the Structure of the Trad- ing Services Industry, in: Brookings-Wharton Papers on Financial Services, 1999, pp. 33-92.

Gomber, Peter (2000): Elektronische Handelssysteme - Innovative Konzepte und Technologien, Heidelberg, Physica-Verlag, 2000.

Hansmann, Henry (1996): The Ownership of Enterprise, London, The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, 1996.

Hayek, Friedrich (1945): The Use of Knowledge in Society, in: American Economic Review 35(4), 1945, pp. 519-530.

Hurwicz, Leonid (1973): The Design of Mechanisms for Resource Allocation, in: American Economic Review 63(2), 1973, pp. 1-30.

Jackson, Matthew O. (2002): Mechanism Theory, in: Encyclopedia of Life Support Systems, UNESCO-Online, 2002.

Lee, Ruben (2000): What is an Exchange? The Automation, Management, and Regulation of Financial Markets, New York, Oxford University Press, 2000.

(12)

Malone, Thomas W.; Yates, Joanne; Scott, Michael; Benjamin, Robert J. (1987): Electronic Markets and Electronic Hierarchies, in: Communications of the ACM 30(6), 1987, pp. 484- 494.

Mason, Edward S. (1939): Price and Production Policies of Large-Scale Enterprise, in: Ameri- can Economic Review 29, 1939, pp. 61-74.

McAfee, Preston R.; McMillan, John (1996): Analyzing the airwave Auction, in: Journal of Economic Perspectives 10(1), 1996, pp. 159-175.

Miles, Matthew B.; Huberman, Michael A. (1994): Qualitative Data Analysis. A Source Book of New Methods, Beverly Hills, Sage, 1994.

Neumann, Dirk; Holtmann, Carsten; Weltzien, Henning; Lattemann, Christoph; Weinhardt, Christof (2002): Towards A Generic E-Market Design, in: Monteiro, J.; Swatman, P. M. C.;

Tavares, L. V. [Eds.], Towards the Knowledge Society: e-Commerce, e-Business and e- Government, pp. 289-305, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 2002.

Nisan, Noam; Ronen, Amir (2001): Algorithmic Mechanism Design, in: Games and Economic Behavior 35, 2001, pp. 166-196.

North, Douglass C. (1987): Institutions, Transaction Costs and Productivity in the Long Run, in:

Economic Inquiry 25(3), 1987, pp. 419-428.

O' Hara, Maureen (1997): Market Microstructure Theory, Malden, MA, Blackwell Publishers Inc., 1997.

Ockenfels, Axel; Roth, Alvin E. (2002): Last-Minute Bidding and the Rules for Ending Second- Price Auctions: Evidence from eBay and Amazon on the Internet, in: American Economic Review 92(4), 2002, pp. 1093-1103.

Ostrom, Elinor (1998): The Institutional Analysis and Development Approach, in: Kilgour, D.

M. [Ed.], Designing Institutions for Environmental and Resource Management, pp. 68-90, Edward Elgar, 1998.

Parkes, David C. (2001): Iterative Combinatorial Auctions: Achieving Economic and Computa- tional Efficiency, Philadelphia, 2001.

Porter, Michael (1980): Competitive Strategy, New York, Porter, 1980.

Porter, Michael (1991): Towards a Dynamic Theory of Strategy, in: Strategic Management Journal 12, 1991, pp. 95-117.

Schwartz, Robert A. (1995): Global Equity Markets: Technological, Competitive, and Regula- tory Challenges, Chicago et al., Leonard N. Stern School of Business, 1995.

Smith, Vernon (1982): Microeconomic Systems as an Experimental Science, in: American Eco- nomic Review 72(5), 1982, pp. 923-955.

Smith, Vernon (2002): Markets, Institutions and Experiments, in: Nadel, L. [Eds.], Encyclope- dia of Cognitive Science, Nature Publishing Group, 2002.

(13)

Spulber, Daniel, F. (1999): Market Microstructure: Intermediaries and the Theory of the Firm, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1999.

Ströbel, Michael; Weinhardt, Christof (2003): The Montreal Taxonomy for Electronic Negotia- tions, in: Journal of Group Decision and Negotiation 12(2), 2003, pp. 143-164.

Varian, Hal R. (1995): Economics Mechanism Design for Computerized Agents, in: USENIX Workshop on Electronic Commerce, New York.

Weinhardt, Christof; Holtmann, Carsten; Neumann, Dirk (2003): Market-Engineering, forthco- ming in: Wirtschaftsinformatik 45(6), 2003.

Wellman, Michael P.; Wurman, Pete (1998): Market-aware Agents for a Multiagent World, in:

Robotics and Autonomous Systems 24, 1998, pp. 115-125.

Williamson, Oliver E. (1985): The Economic Institution of Capitalism, New York, The Free Press, 1985.

Wurman, Pete; Wellman, Michael P.; Walsh, William E. (1998): A Parametrization of the Auc- tion Design Space, in: Games and Economic Behavior 35(1-2), 1998, pp. 271-303.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

West University from Timisoara (Romania), Faculty of Economics and Business Administration, Finance Department.. 1

The reached level of development of the capital market in Croatia is the result and the consequence of the openness of Croatian economy, but it is also, partly, the result of

компоненты, что и теория предприятия (см. Остальные компоненты описания теории требуют специального рассмотрения. В качестве примера следствий из данной

компоненты, что и теория предприятия (см. Остальные компоненты описания теории требуют специального рассмотрения. В качестве примера следствий из данной

b) Collaborative R&D projects are consistently more likely to occur in the US than in Europe. However, in-house projects are a significant majority of the drug R&D

Moreover, the data analysis intends to identify the benefits of the use of ICTs and mass media within the planning processes in order to understand if regional governments use

Further, self-concept beliefs were found to moderate the discrepancy between trait and state emotions such that positive emotions were overestimated in students with

The included articles in this dissertation shed light on these questions by examining the impact of different types of system design (e.g., social