• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Utility maximization and duality

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Utility maximization and duality"

Copied!
36
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

JOHANNES LEITNER

JOHANNES.LEITNER@UNI-KONSTANZ.DE

CENTER OF FINANCE AND ECONOMETRICS (COFE)

UNIVERSITY OF KONSTANZ

Abstract. Inanarbitragefreeincompletemarketweconsiderthe

problemofmaximizingterminalisoelasticutility. Therelationship

betweentheoptimalportfolio,theoptimalmartingalemeasure in

thedualproblemandtheoptimalvaluefunctionoftheproblemis

describedbyanBSDE.Foratotally unhedgeable pricefor instan-

taneousrisk,isoelasticutilityofterminalwealthcanbemaximized

usingaportfolioconsisting of thelocally risk-freebond andalo-

cally eÆcient fund only. Inamarkovianmarketmodel wend a

non-linearPDEforthelogarithmofthevaluefunction. Fromthe

solutionwecanconstructtheoptimalportfolioandthesolutionof

thedual problem.

Keywords: Utility,OptimalPortfolios,DualityTheory.

AMS91Classications: 90A09,90A10

JELClassications: G11

IwouldliketothankProfessorM.Kohlmannforhissuggestionsandsupport. I

amalsothankfultoProfessorM.SchweizerandProfessorS.Tang.

(2)

Introduction

We study the problem of maximizing expected isoelastic utility of

terminalwealth inanincomplete continuous time marketwith contin-

uouspriceprocess. Theisoelasticutilityofexponentp6=0;1isdened

asu (p)

(x):=sgn(1 p) jxj

p

p

andforp=0byu (0)

(x):=ln(jxj). The two

cases p < 1 and p > 1 are very dierent in there economic interpre-

tation, but can be treated to some extend by the same mathematical

methods. Solving theoptimizationproblemforp<1isaplausibleap-

proachtondportfoliosofoptimalexpectedgrowth. Thereareseveral

papers on this topic: See, e.g. Merton (1990), Pliska (1986), He and

Pearson (1991), Karatzas, Lehoczky, Shreve and Xu (1991), Karatzas

and Shreve (1999),Kramkov and Schachermayer (1999).

For p = 2 the problem is related to the mean-variance hedging

problem,see Gourieroux, Laurent and Pham (1998),(GLP98), Pham,

Rheinlander and Schweizer (1998) and Laurentand Pham (1999).

The theory of stochastic duality, which goes back to Bismut (1973,

1975), is the central tool for solving these problems. This theory al-

lows to formulate an optimization problem over a set of martingale

measures, beingdualtothe originaloptimizationproblemoveraset of

self-nancing hedging-strategies. Under quite general conditions, the

solution of one of the problems can be transformed into a solution of

the corresponding dual problem.

Anotherimportantapproach,istotrytosolvetheoptimizationprob-

lemlocally,i.e. by so-calledmyopic strategies whichmaximizeinsome

sensetheexpectedgrowthrateoftheportfolioateveryinstantoftime.

In some important cases these strategies turn out to be globally op-

timal too. See, e.g., Mossin (1968), Leland (1972), Aase (1984, 1986,

1987, 1988), Foldes (1991), Goll and Kallsen (2000). This approach

isrelated tothe risk-sensitive stochastic controlapproach, see Bielecki

and Pliska (1999,2000).

We consider an arbitrage-free (ina sense to be specied later) con-

tinuous time market model with unrestricted trading. We use the

modern equivalent martingale measure approach, see Harrison and

Pliska (1981), Delbaen and Schachermayer (1994). After some techni-

calpreparations inSection 1and specication of the model inSection

2, we formulate the optimization problem and its corresponding dual

Problem in Section 3. We show a representation property (formula

(3.8)), relating the terminal value V opt

T

of a portfolio to a martingale

Research supported by the Center of Finance and Econometrics, ProjectMathe-

maticalFinance.

(3)

measure Z opt

T

, to be suÆcient for the optimality of V opt

T

for the utility

maximizationproblemandthe optimalityof Z opt

T

forthe dualproblem.

Theoptimalvaluesofthetwoproblemarerelatedbyasimpleformula.

In Section 4 weintroduce the notion of a totally unhedgeable price for

instantaneous risk. In this situation we can explicitlysolve the utility

optimizationproblem. TheoptimalportfolioisalocallyeÆcientportfo-

lio,anotionweintroduceinSection5. InSection6wegiveanexistence

result for the solutions of the two optimization problems. In Section

7 we derive abackward stochastic dierentialequation, (BSDE), such

thatfromthesolutiontheoptimalportfolio,theoptimalvaluefunction

and the solutionof the dualoptimization problemcan beconstructed.

See Yong and Zhou (1999) for an introduction to BSDEs. In Section

8 we consider a markovian market model. We transform the BSDE

into a non-linear PDE for the logarithm of the value function. From

the partial derivatives of the solution, we can construct under addi-

tional assumptions the optimal portfolio and the solution of the dual

optimization problem.

1. Self-financing Hedging Strategies

Let a ltered probability space

1

:= (;F;(F

s )

s0

;P), satisfying

theusualconditionsbegiven. ForsimplicityweassumeF

0

tobetrivial

up to sets of measure 0 with respect to P and F

1

= F

1

:=F. For

an adapted process X set X

0

:=X

0 , X

t

:=lim

h&0 X

t h

for t >0 if

thelimitexists anddenethe processesX :=(X

t )

0t<1

andX :=

X X if X

t

exists for allt >0. The components of X are denoted

as X i

; 1 id. Fora process X and a map :!

R

+

, denote the

stopped process attime by X

. Wewilloftenrestrict asemimartin-

gale X on

1

to an interval [t;T]; 0 t T < 1, resp. to [t;1).

Therefore we introduce the following ltered probability space (again

satisfying the usual conditions),

[t;T]

:=

;F

T

;

F [t;T]

s

s0

;P

jF

T

for all 0 t T 1, t <1, where F [t;T]

s

:=F

t_s^T

for 0 s <1.

The process X [t;T]

s

:=X

t_s^T

isthen a semimartingaleon

[t;T]

. How-

ever, on[t;T] we oftenwrite X insteadof X [t;T]

. Set

T :=

[0;T] .

For q >1 dene L q

(

[t;T]

), respectively L q

t (

[t;T]

), asthe set of F

T -

measurablerandomvariablesX,suchthatE[X]<1a.s.,respectively

E

t

[X] < 1 a.s., where E

t

[] :=E[jF

t

] denotes the generalized condi-

tional expectation. Denote the conditional variance by Var

t

(). The

stochastic exponential of a semimartingale X is denoted as E(X) and

we set E(X):=E(1 X). Asa generalreferences wecite Jacod and

(4)

Shiryaev (1987), (J&S 87), and Jacod (1979). Denote the set of pre-

dictableprocesses which are locallyintegrable, resp. locally Riemann-

Stieltjes integrable, with respect to a local martingale M, resp. with

respectto aprocessA ofnitevariation,byL 1

l oc

(M),resp. by L 1

l oc (A).

If the semimartingale X admits a decomposition X = X

0

+A+M,

where M is a local martingale and A is a process of nite variation

then L 1

l oc

(X):=L 1

l oc

(M)\L 1

l oc (A).

We can now dene the market model: Let S = (S

t )

0t<1

be a R d

-

valued semimartingale. M := (

1

;S) = ((;F;(F

s )

s0

;P);S) is a

model for a market, where S describesthe price processes of d assets.

We will often consider such a market on an interval [t;T]; 0 t <

T < 1. This is equivalent to work with the following market model

M

[t;T]

denedbyM

[t;T]

:=

[t;T]

;S [t;T]

. Set M

T

:=M

[0;T]

. Wewant

to model the economic activity of investing money into a portfolio of

assetsand changingthenumberof assetsheldovertimeaccording toa

certainhedgingstrategy. Thisisachieved withthefollowingdenition:

Denition 1.1. AhedgingstrategyinthemarketMisaH 2L 1

l oc (S).

The corresponding value process V H

of H is dened as V H

:= HS.

The gains process of H is dened as the semimartingaleG H

:=HS.

H is called self-nancing if V H

= V H

0 +G

H

, i.e. H

t S

t

= H

0 S

0 +

R

t

0 H

s dS

s

;8t0. Denote thespaceofallself-nancinghedgingstrate-

gies in Mby SF(M).

Note that for H 2SF(M), we have H [t;T]

2SF(M

[t;T]

). The idea

of a self-nancing hedging strategy is that the changes over time of

thecorrespondingvalue processaresolelycausedbythechangesofthe

value ofthe assetsheldintheportfolioandnot bywithdrawing money

fromor adding money tothe portfolio.

Denition 1.2. A semimartingaleB such that B and B are strictly

positiveiscalledanumeraireforthemarketM. Themarketdiscounted

withrespecttoB isthendened asM B

:=

1

;S B

,whereS B

:=

S

.

(5)

For 0 t T < 1, the market restricted to the interval [t;T] is

dened asM B

[t;T]

:= M B

[t;T]

=

[t;T]

; S B

[t;T]

.

Note that for a numeraire B, B 1

is a numeraire too and S B

is a

semimartingale.

Usually there is in addition to the market M a numeraire B given

and the market

M := (

1

;

S);

S := (S;B) is considered. Often B

is the price process of a locally risk-free bond. If the numeraire is

traded, i.e. the value process of a portfolio in M, one can try to

extend ahedgingstrategyinMtoaself-nancing hedgingstrategyin

M. Dene the discounted market

M B

=(

1

;(S B

;1)). The ideaisto

extend H toaself-nancing hedgingstrategy

H =(H;

^

H)2SF(

M B

)

by dening the process

^

H :=H

0 S

B

0

+HS B

HS B

andthen toshow

that

H is a self-nancing hedging strategy in

M too, see Geman, El

Karui and Rochet (1995) and Goll and Kallsen (2000). (Note that

HS B

HS B

=(HS B

) +(HS B

) HS B

=(HS B

) +HS B

HS B

=(H S B

) HS

B

ispredictable, hence

H aswell.)

Proposition 1.3. Let B be a numeraire for the market M. Then

SF(M B

)=SF(M) holds.

Proof. Let H 2 SF(M B

). Set V B

= HS B

. First, we have to show

H 2 L 1

l oc

(S). Since S = S B

B =S

0 +S

B

B +B S B

+[S B

;B] this

followsifweshowthatH 2L 1

l oc (S

B

B)\L 1

l oc

(B S B

)\L 1

l oc ([S

B

;B]).

Note that HS B

= H(S B

S B

) = V B

(H S B

) = V B

0

+H

S B

(H S B

) = V B

0

+(H S B

) = V B

, which is locally bounded.

Since[S B

B;S B

B]=(S B

S B

)[B;B]and H(S B

S B

)H =(V B

) 2

is locally integrable with respect to [B;B], we nd H 2 L 1

(S B

B).

(6)

That H 2L 1

l oc

(B S B

)\L 1

l oc ([S

B

;B]) iseasy tosee. We calculate

HS = H(S B

B)=H(S B

B+B S B

+[S B

;B])

= (HS B

)B+(B H)S B

+[HS B

;B]

= V B

B+B (H S B

)+[V B

;B]

= V B

B V

B

0 B

0

=HS B

B H

0 S

B

0 B

0

= HS H

0 S

0 :

This implies SF(M B

) SF(M). Now observe that (M B

) B

1

= M,

since B 1

is anumeraire. This impliesthe reverse inclusion.

There is an alternative way to construct self-nancing hedgingstrate-

gies:

Lemma 1.4. Let H 2 SF(M) be such that V H

6= 0 and V H

6= 0

almost surely. Set

~

H :=

H

V H

. Then

~

H2L 1

l oc (S),

~

HS =1 and

V H

=V H

0 +V

H

(

~

HS)=V H

0 E(

~

HS);

(1.1)

holds. Conversely, let

~

H 2 L 1

l oc

(S) with

~

HS = 1 be given and set

H := v

0 E(

~

H S)

~

H for a F

0

-measurable random variable v

0

. Then

H 2 SF(M) and V H

= v

0 E(

~

HS). We call

~

H a generator for the

self-nancing strategy H and dene V (

~

H)

:=V H

.

Proof. Since V H

1

islocallybounded wehave

~

H 2L 1

l oc

(S). Wehave

V H

V H

0

=G H

=HS=(V H

~

H)S =V H

(

~

HS). Thesecondidentity

(7)

Dolean-DadeSDEdeningthestochasticexponential,seeJ&S87,I.4f.

Conversely, we calculate

HS = v

0 E(

~

HS)

~

HS =v

0 E(

~

HS) (

~

HS +

~

HS)

= v

0 E(

~

HS) (1+(

~

HS))

= v

0

E(

~

HS) +E(

~

HS) (

~

HS)

= v

0

E(

~

HS) + E(

~

HS) (

~

HS)

= v

0

E(

~

HS) + E(

~

HS) 1

= v

0 E(

~

HS)=v

0 +v

0 E(

~

HS) (

~

HS)

= v

0 +v

0 E(

~

HS)

~

HS=V H

0 +G

H

:

2. Arbitrage-free Markets

Sofarwedid not worryaboutarbitrage. Weconsider inthissection

themarket

M:=(

1

;

S),where

S :=(S;B)isR d

R-valuedandB is

a numeraire, with B

0

=1, which we assume to be uniformlybounded

and uniformly bounded away from 0 on nite intervals. For 0 t

T 1;t < 1, denote the set of uniformly integrable, resp. local

martingales, living on

[t;T] by L

u

(

[t;T]

), resp. by L(

[t;T]

). Dene

the followingsets of localmartingale measures:

D(

M

[t;T] ):=

Z 2L(

[t;T] )jZ1

[0;t]

=1;Z 0;(S B

) [t;T]

Z 2L(

[t;T] ) ; (2.1)

D(

M

[t;T] ):=

Z 2L(

[t;T] )jZ1

[0;t]

=1;Z >0;(S B

) [t;T]

Z 2L(

[t;T] ) ; (2.2)

D abs

(

M

[t;T] ):=

Z 2

D(

M

[t;T]

)jZ uniformlyintegrablemartingale ; (2.3)

(8)

and

D e

(

M

[t;T]

):=

Z 2D(

M

[t;T]

)jZ uniformlyintegrable martingale : (2.4)

Wewillwork with the following No-Arbitragecondition:

D e

(

M

T

)6=;; 8T <1:

(2.5)

This condition isknown tobeequivalenttothe NFLVR-condition,see

Delbaen and Schachermayer (1994). It implies that

D e

(

M

[t;T]

)6=;; 80t T <1:

(2.6)

We will often work with the following sets of equivalent, resp. abso-

lutelycontinuous, localmartingalemeasures, for q >1:

D q

(

M

[0;T]

):=

Z 2D(

M

[0;T] )jZ

T 2L

q

(

[0;T] ) ; (2.7)

D q

t (

M

[t;T]

):=

Z

t_

Z

t

jZ 2D q

(

M

[0;T] )

; (2.8)

D q

(

M

[0;T] ):=

Z 2D abs

(

M

[0;T]

)jZ

T 2L

q

(

[0;T] ) ; (2.9)

D q

t (

M

[t;T] ):=

Z

t_

Z

t jZ 2

D q

(

M

[0;T] );Z

t

>0

: (2.10)

Note that Z 2 D q

t (

M

[t;T]

) implies Z

T 2 L

p

t (

[t;T]

). For q < 1 set

D q

t (

M

[t;T]

) := D(

M

[t;T] ) and

D q

(

M

[t;T] ) :=

D q

t (

M

[t;T] ) :=

D(

M

[t;T] ).

ForZ 2D q

t (

M

[t;T]

)andt t 0

T 0

T,wehave Z

[t 0

;T 0

]

Z

t 0

2D q

t 0

(

M

[t 0

;T 0

] ).

Note also that D q

0 (

M

[0;T]

) = D(

M

[0;T]

), since F

0

was assumed to be

trivial.

p willalways denote a real number dierentfrom 1. We dene q:=

p

p 1

, such that forp6=0;1,p 1

+q 1

=1 holds, but forp=0 wehave

q=0.

Let B SF(

M

[t;T]

). We call a H 2 B an B-arbitrage, if V H

0

= 0,

V H

T

0 and V H

T

6= 0 almost surely. If there exists no B-arbitrage,

then B is called arbitrage-free. In all probabilistictheories of nancial

markets allowingto tradeat aninnitely large number of instances of

time one has to exclude certain self-nancing hedging strategies, e.g.

doublingstrategies, inorder to avoidarbitrage opportunities. We will

dene several arbitrage-free subsets of SF(

M ):

(9)

1. For p > 1 and D q

t (

M

[t;T]

) 6= ;, (see Delbaen and Schachermayer

(1996), (DS96)):

SF p

(

M

[t;T] ) :=

H2SF(

M

[t;T]

)jV H

T 2L

p

(

[t;T] );

V H

B [t;T]

Z 2L u

(

[t;T]

);8Z 2D q

(

M

[t;T]

)

; (2.11)

resp.

SF p

t (

M

[t;T] ) :=

H2SF(

M

[t;T]

)jV H

T 2L

p

t (

[t;T] );

V H

B [t;T]

Z 2L u

(

[t;T]

);8Z 2D q

t (

M

[t;T]

)

: (2.12)

Notethat

SF p

t (

M

[t;T] ) =

H 2SF(

M

[t;T] )jV

H

T 2L

p

t (

[t;T] );

V H

B [t;T]

Z 2L u

(

[t;T]

);8Z 2

D q

t (

M

[t;T] )

; (2.13)

since for Z 2

D q

t (

M

[t;T]

)we can nd a

Z 2

D q

(

M

[0;T]

) with Z =

Zt_

Z

t

and for Z 0

2 D q

(

M

[0;T]

), we have

~

Z :=

Z+Z 0

2

2 D q

(

M

[0;T]

),

which implies

^

Z :=

~

Z

t_

~

Zt 2 D

q

t (

M

[t;T]

) and for H 2 SF p

t (

M

[t;T] )

that V

H

B [t;T]

Z = V

H

B [t;T]

((

Z

t +Z

0

t )

^

Z Z

0

t_

Z 0

t

) is a uniformlyintegrable

martingale.

2. Forp<1

SF p

(

M

[t;T]

):=SF p

t (

M

[t;T] ):=

H 2SF(

M

[t;T] )jV

H

0 : (2.14)

3. Forp>1 and

S 2S p

l oc (

[t;T] )

G p

(

M

[t;T]

):=

H 2SF(

M

[t;T]

)jV H

2S p

(

[t;T] ) ; (2.15)

where S p

(

[t;T]

) denotes the space of L p

-integrable semimartin-

gales,seeDelbaen,Monat,Schachermayer, SchweizerandStricker

(1997)(DMSSS97)forthecasep=2and GranditsandKrawczyk

(1998), (GK98),for the general case p>1.

Lemma 2.1. For p > 1 assume D q

t (

M

[t;T]

) 6= ; and

S to be contin-

uous. Then G p

(

M

[t;T]

) SF p

t (

M

[t;T]

). In particular G p

(

M

[t;T] ) is

arbitrage-free.

(10)

Proof. For H 2 G p

(

M

[t;T] ) set

n

:= inf n

s0

V

H

s

B

s

n

o

, H n

:= H

on [0;

n ) and

0;

V H

n

B

n

2 R d

R on [

n

;T]. Then H n

2 SF p

t (

M

[t;T] ),

since

V

H n

B [t;T]

n. It follows E h

V H

n

T

B

T Z

T jF

s i

= V

H n

s

B

s Z

s

for all t

s T and all Z 2 D q

t (

M

[t;T] ). V

H n

s

converges almost surely to V H

s

and

V

H n

T

B

T Z

T

sup

tsT (

V H

s )

B

T

Z

T

2 L

1

(

[t;T]

), since sup

tsT V

H

s

2

L p

(

[t;T]

)byDoob'smaximalinequality,hencewendE h

V H

T

B

T Z

T jF

s i

=

V H

s

Bs Z

s

for alltsT.

Dene for F

t

-measurable v

A p

v (

M

[t;T] ):=

V H

T

B

T

H 2SF p

(

M

[t;T] );

V H

t

B

t

=v

; (2.16)

and

G p

v (

M

[t;T] ):=

V H

T

B

T

H2G p

(

M

[t;T] );

V H

t

B

t

=v

: (2.17)

For p > 1 and D q

(

M

[t;T]

) 6= ;, SF p

(

M

[t;T]

) has an important prop-

erty: A p

1 (M

[t;T]

)isknowntobeclosed,if S

B

[t;T]

islocallyinL p

(

[t;T] )

in the sense, that there exists a sequence U

n

;n 2 N of localizing

stopping times increasing to innity such that for each n, the fam-

ily fS [t;T]

j stoppingtime; U

n

g is bounded in L p

(

[t;T]

), see DS96.

This condition certainly holds if

S is continuous. To work with the

spaces G p

(

M

[t;T]

)isinsome sense morenatural,since itsdenition in-

volvesonlytheobjectiveprobabilitymeasureP andnoequivalentmar-

tingale measures. Furthermore G p

(

M

[t;T]

) is stable under stopping, a

desirablepropertyfromaneconomicpointofview. However, thisspace

has in generalweaker properties than SF p

(

M

[t;T]

),see DMSSS97 and

GK98.

WewilloftenworkwithacontinuouspriceprocessS,resp.

S. Inthis

caseL 1

l oc

(S)=L 2

l oc

(S)holds. Thepriceprocessadmitsarepresentation

S =S

0

++M;

(2.18)

where =( i

)

1id

is predictable, is a predictable, increasing, con-

tinuous,locallyintegrableprocesssuchthatislocallyintegrablewith

respectto . Furthermore,thereexistsasymmetricnon-negativedd-

matrix-valued predictable process C = (C ij

) , locally integrable

(11)

withrespect to ,suchthat[S i

;S j

]=[M i

;M j

]=< M i

;M j

>=C ij

.

can bechosen such that B =E(r ) for a predictableprocess r.

In the continuous case, D e

(

M

[0;T]

) 6= ; implies = rS C, d -

almost surely for a predictable process 2 L 2

l oc

(M) and every Z 2

D e

(

M

[t;T]

) is of the form Z = E

t

( M + N) T

, where N is a not

necessarilycontinuouslocalmartingaleorthogonaltoM with[M;N]=

0, see Ansel and Stricker(1992).

3. Optimal Portfolios

Consider the problem of maximizing expected utility from termi-

nal wealth. We follow a stochastic duality approach, which goes back

to Bismut (1973, 1975), see also Karatzas, Lehoczky, Shreve and Xu

(1991), (KLSX91), and Karatzas and Shreve (1999), Kramkov and

Schachermayer(1999) and Schachermayer (2000)for general results.

We have already dened the so-called isoelastic utility functions

u (p)

;p 6= 1, with constant index of relative risk-aversion, see Pratt

(1964) and Arrow (1976). For optimization multiplication of the util-

ity functionwith a constant factor oradding a constant has no eect.

Wechoose tonormalizethe utility functionsuch that jU (p)

(1)j=1 for

allp6=0;1and dene for p<1;p6=0

U (p)

(x):=sgn(p)x p

; 8x0;

(3.1)

U (p)

(x)= 1 for x<0 and

U (0)

(x):=ln(x); 8x>0;

(3.2)

U (0)

(x)= 1 for x0. Forp>1 set

U (p)

(x):= jxj p

; 8x2R;

(3.3)

Wehave for p<1;p6=0

dU (p)

dx

(x)=jpjx p 1

; 8x>0;

(3.4)

and

dU (0)

dx

(x)= 1

x

; 8x>0;

(3.5)

and set dU

(p)

dx

(0):=1for p<1.

We want to solve the following optimization problem for xed 0

tT <1and p6=1:

V(p;t;T;B):=esssup H2B

H

S=1 E

t

U (p)

V H

T

(3.6)

(12)

where B 2 fSF p

t (

M

[t;T] );fSF

p

(

M

[t;T] );G

p

(

M

[t;T]

)g for p > 1, resp.

B=SF p

t (

M

[t;T]

) for p<1, and the dual problem

W

(q;t;T;C):=essinf

Z2C E

t

U (q)

B

t Z

T

B

T

; (3.7)

where C 2 fD q

t (

M

[t;T] );

D q

t (

M

[t;T]

)g. ( U (q)

equals the convex dual

to U (p)

up toa constant factor, see Rockafellar (1970)). See Karatzas

and Shreve (1999)forthe denitionofesssup andessinf. IfforH 2B

withV H

0

=1andV(p;t;T;B)=E

t

U (p)

V H

T

,thenwesayV H

solves

Problem (3.6) forB. Iffor Z 2C, W

(q;t;T;C)=E

t h

U (q)

BtZ

T

B

T i

,

then we say Z solves the dual Problem (3.7) for C. For the moment

we are interested in the Problem (3.6) for B = SF p

t (

M

[t;T]

) and set

V(p;t;T) := V(p;t;T;SF p

t (

M

[t;T]

)). For p > 1, we set W

(q;t;T) :=

W

(q;t;T;

D q

t (

M

[t;T]

)),respectivelyfor p<1,we deneW

(q;t;T):=

W

(q;t;T;D q

t (

M

[t;T]

)). (It will turn out later, that W

(q;t;T) =

W

(q;t;T;

D q

t (M

[t;T]

))for p>1and for p<1if V(p;0;T)<1.)

Thefollowingpropositionshows thecloserelationbetween thesetwo

problems and gives the key idea how to handle the incompleteness of

the market.

Proposition 3.1. Assume that there exists an H 2SF p

t (

M

[t;T] ) with

V H

T

0andaZ

opt;q;t;T

2

D

t (

M

[t;T]

)suchthatforsomeF

t

-measurable

random variable c>0

Z

opt;q;t;T

T

=cB

T

sgn(1 p) dU

(p)

dx V

H

T

; (3.8)

andsuchthat V

H

B [t;T]

Z

opt;q;t;T

isauniformlyintegrablemartingale. Then

V opt;p;t;T

:=

V H

V H

0

solves Problem (3.6) for SF p

t (

M

[t;T]

) and Z

opt;q;t;T

solves for p > 1, resp. p < 1, the dual Problem (3.7) for

D

t (

M

[t;T] ),

resp. for D

t (

M

[t;T] ) and

D

t (

M

[t;T]

). There exists at most one such

opt;p;t;T opt;q;t;T

(13)

corresponding optimal values satisfy

jV(p;t;T)j p

1

jW

(q;t;T)j q

1

=1:

(3.9)

Proof. Notethatforp<1(3.8)impliesV H

T

>0. ForH 2SF p

t (

M

[t;T] )

with V H

0

=1and since U (p)

is concave we have

U (p)

V H

T

U (p)

V opt;p;t;T

T

+ dU

(p)

dx

V opt;p;t;T

T

(V H

T V

opt;p;t;T

T

):

(3.10)

Taking conditionalexpectations we nd

E

t

U (p)

V H

T

E

t

"

U (p)

V opt;p;t;T

T

+Z

opt;q;t;T V

H

T V

opt;p;t;T

T

sgn (1 p)cB

T

#

E

t h

U (p)

V opt;p;t;T

T

i

;

since E

t h

V H

T

B

T Z

opt;q;t;T i

V

H

t

Bt

= V

opt;p;t;T

t

Bt

for p < 1, respectively since

Z

opt;q;t;T

2

D q

t (

M

[t;T]

) for p>1. LetQ2

D q

t (

M

[t;T]

)and calculate

U (q)

dQ

T

dP

T

B

T B

1

t

!

= U

(q) 0

@ Z

opt;q;t;T

T

+

dQ

T

dP

T Z

opt;q;t;T

T

B

T B

1

t

1

A

U

(q) Z

opt;q;t;T

T

B

T B

1

t

!

dU (q)

dx B

t Z

opt;q;t;T

T

B

T B

1

t

!

dQ

T

dP

T Z

opt;q;t;T

T

B

T B

1

t

= U

(q) Z

opt;q;t;T

T

B

T B

1

t

!

sgn(1 p)k V

opt;p;t;T

T

B

T

dQ

T

dP

T Z

opt;q;t;T

T

;

for some F

t

-measurable random variable k > 0. Taking conditional

expectations wend

E

t

"

U (q)

B

t Z

opt;q;t;T

T

B

T

!#

E

t

"

U (q)

B

t dQ

T

dP

T

B

T

!#

; (3.11)

(14)

since E

t h

V opt;p;t;T

T

B

T dQ

T

dP

T i

V

opt;p;t;T

t

B

t

for p < 1, resp. since for p > 1

Z

opt;q;t;T

2

D q

t (

M

[t;T]

). Theuniquenessofthepair(V opt;p;t;T

T

;Z

opt;q;t;T

T

)

follows from the strict concavity of U (p)

. Since V

opt;p;t;T

B [t;T]

Z

opt;q;t;T

is a

uniformlyintegrable martingale, itis determined by V

opt;p;t;T

T

B

T Z

opt;q;t;T

T

.

LetH 0

2SF p

t (

M

[t;T]

) with V H

0

0

=1and Z 0

2D

t (

M

[t;T]

) such that

Z 0

T

=c 0

B

T

sgn (1 p) dU

(p)

dx

V H

0

T

; (3.12)

holds for a F

t

-measurable random variable c 0

> 0. Then V opt;p;t;T

T

=

V H

0

T , Z

opt;q;t;T

T

= Z 0

T and

V opt;p;t;T

B [t;T]

Z

opt;q;t;T

= V

H 0

B [t;T]

Z 0

. Assume that

there exists a t s T with A := fV H

0

s

> V opt;p;t;T

s

g 6= ;. In

this case we can change the self-nancing hedging strategy H 0

on

A [s;T] to a H 00

2 SF p

t (

M

[t;T]

) such that V H

0 0

T

V

opt;p;t;T

T

and

V H

00

T

> V opt;p;t;T

T

on A. From this we conclude the uniqueness of the

pair (V opt;p;t;T

;Z

opt;q;t;T

). Forp6=0wend

U (p)

(V opt;p;t;T

T

) = sgn (q)

V opt;p;t;T

T

p

= sgn (q)

V opt;p;t;T

T

p 1

V opt;p;t;T

T

= Z

opt;p;t;T

T

cp sgn(1 p) V

opt;p;t;T

T

B

T

;

hence

V(p;t;T)=E

t h

U (p)

(V opt;p;t;T

T

) i

=

1

cp sgn(1 p)B : (3.13)

(15)

Forq 6=0 we nd

U (q)

B

t Z

opt;p;t;T

T

B

T

!

= sgn (p)B q

t Z

opt;p;t;T

T

B

T

!

q

= sgn (p)B q

t Z

opt;p;t;T

T

B

T

!

q 1

Z

opt;p;t;T

T

B

T

= sgn (p)B q

t

cjpj V opt;p;t;T

T

p 1

1

p 1 Z

opt;p;t;T

T

B

T

= sgn (p)B q

t (cjpj)

1

p 1

Z

opt;p;t;T

T

V opt;p;t;T

T

B

T

;

hence

W

(q;t;T)=E

t

"

U (q)

B

t Z

opt;p;t;T

T

B

T

!#

=sgn (p)(B

t cjpj)

1

p 1

: (3.14)

(3.13) and (3.14) together imply(3.9).

Wecall(V opt;p;t;T

;Z

opt;q;t;T

)theoptimalpairforthemarket

M

[t;T]

with

respecttooptimizationinSF p

t (

M

[t;T]

). Wehavethefollowingstability

property for optimalpairs:

Proposition 3.2. If the pair (V opt;p;t;T

;Z

opt;q;t;T

) admits a represen-

tation (3.8) with V opt;p;t;T

=V H

for a H 2SF p

t (

M

[t;T]

) with V H

0

=1

andZ

opt;q;t;T

2D q

t (

M

[t;T]

),thentheoptimalpairforthemarket

M

[t 0

;T]

exists and is given by

V opt;p;t

0

;T

;Z opt;q;t

0

;T

= V

opt;p;t;T

t 0

_

V opt;p;t;T

t 0

; Z

opt;q;t;T

t 0

_

Z

opt;q;t;T

t 0

!

: (3.15)

Proof. Noterst,thatbyJ&S87,LemmaIII.3.6,wehaveZ

opt;q;t;T

>0.

ForZ 2

D q

t 0

(

M

[t 0

;T]

) set A:=

E

t 0

[Z q

T ]<E

t 0

Z opt;q;t;T

T

Z opt;q;t;T

t 0

q

. Dene

~

Z :=Z

opt;q;t;T

on[t;t 0

)[A c

[t 0

;T],and

~

Z :=Z

opt;q;t;T

0

Z onA[t 0

;T].

(16)

Wecalculate

E

t h

~

Z q

T i

= E

t h

E

t 0

h

~

Z q

T ii

= E

t h

1

A

Z

opt;q;t;T

t 0

q

E

t 0

[Z q

T ]+1

A c

E

t 0

h

Z

opt;q;t;T

T

q ii

E

t h

E

t 0

h

Z

opt;q;t;T

T

q ii

=E

t h

Z

opt;q;t;T

T

q i

;

hence

~

Z 2

D q

t (

M

[t;T] ),

~

Z

T

= Z

opt;q;t;T

T

and A = ; and we conclude

Z opt;q;t

0

;T

= Z

opt;q;t;T

t 0

_

Z opt;q;t;T

t 0

. By assumption we have V

opt;p;t;T

T

B

T Z

opt;q;t;T

T

> 0

and since V

opt;p;t;T

B [t;T]

Z

opt;q;t;T

is a non-negative supermartingale we have

V opt;p;t;T

>0. Hence V

opt;p;t;T

T

V opt;p;t;T

t 0

2L p

t 0

(

[t 0

;T]

)and V

opt;p;t;T

t 0

_

V opt;p;t;T

t 0

Z is auniformly

integrablemartingale for allZ 2D q

t 0 (

M

[t 0

;T]

). Since

Z opt;q;t

0

;T

T

=c

t 0

B

T

sgn(1 p) dU

(p)

dx V

opt;p;t;T

T

V opt;p;t;T

t 0

!

; (3.16)

where

c

t 0

:=

c dU

(p)

dx

V opt;p;t;T

t 0

Z

opt;q;t;T

t 0

; (3.17)

we can apply Proposition 3.1.

Lemma 3.3. For p >1, H 2 SF 0

t (

M

[t;T]

) with V H

0

=1, Z

opt;q;t;T

2

D

t (

M

[t;T]

)andassume(V H

;Z

opt;q;t;T

)toadmitarepresentation(3.8).

If V H

T

2 L p+

t (

[t;T]

), (or equivalently Z

opt;q;t;T

T

2 L q+

t (

[t;T]

)), for

some >0, then H 2SF p

t (

M

[t;T]

) and (V H

;Z

opt;q;t;T

) is the optimal

pair for the market

M

[t 0

;T] .

(17)

Proof. Observe that V

H

T

B

T Z

T 2 L

1+ ~

t (

[t;T]

) for some ~> 0 for all Z 2

D q

t (

M

[t;T]

). Hence V

H

T

B

T

Z is a uniformly integrable martingale. Now

apply Proposition 3.1.

In the next two sections we look at an example and postpone an

existence result for the optimalpair (V opt;p;t;T

;Z

opt;q;t;T

) untilSection

6.

4. Totally Unhedgeable Price for Instantaneous Risk

Assume

S to be continuous such that we have a representation

(2.18). In this section we seek a suÆcient condition ensuring certain

self-nancing hedging strategies to be optimal for problem 3.6. See

Karatzas andShreve(1999),Example6.7.4forasimilarresultand the

notionof totally unhedgeablecoeÆcients. This notiondescribes amar-

ketmodelwhere the uncertainty in the coeÆcients dening the model

is ina certainsense orthogonal tothe uncertainty of the localmartin-

gale M driving the price process, such that we can not hedge against

this risk. Set :=

p

C2L 2

l oc ( ).

Denition 4.1. For 0t T <1, [t;T]

is called the instantaneous

price for risk process, or instantaneous Sharpe-ratio process, for the

market

M

[t;T] .

Denition 4.2. For 0 t T < 1, let an F

t

-measurable random

variable c > 0 and a not necessarily continuous local martingale N

orthogonal to M, (or equivalently with [N;M] = 0), be given such

that

1.

E

t

pr q

2

2

=cE

t (N)

T : (4.1)

(18)

2. Forp<1,E

t

(qM +N) T

isa uniformlyintegrablemartingale.

Wethencalltheinstantaneousprice forrisk [t;T]

inthemarket

M

[t;T]

totally p-unhedgeable. resp. strongly totally p-unhedgeableif E

t (N)

T

is

a uniformlyintegrablemartingale.

Remark 4.3. Forp =0 we have q = 0 and we nd a unique represen-

tation (4.1) with c= 1, N = 0 for any 0 t T < 1, thus [t;T]

is

totally 0-unhedgeable in

M

[t;T]

. For p =0, the optimization problem

(3.6)isalsoknown asmaximizingthe Kelly-criterion,see Kelly(1956),

Breiman (1960) and Karatzas and Shreve (1999). For general results

see Aase (1986) and Golland Kallsen (2000).

Lemma 4.4. If [t;T]

is totally p-unhedgeable in

M

[t;T]

, then [t

0

;T]

is

totally p-unhedgeable in

M

[t 0

;T]

for allt t 0

T.

Proof. For t t 0

T set c 0

:= cE

t

pr q

2

2

+N

t 0

. This

gives us a representation (4.1) and for p < 1, E

t 0

(qM +N) T

is a

uniformlyintegrable martingale.

Proposition 4.5. Assume [t;T]

to be totally p-unhedgeable in

M

[t;T]

witharepresentation(4.1),thentheoptimalpairforthemarket

M

[t 0

;T]

for tt 0

T is givenby

V opt;p;t

0

;T

;Z opt;q;t

0

;T

= V

(H p

)

t 0

_

V (H

p

)

0

;E

t

0(M +N) T

!

; (4.2)

(19)

where H p

:=

p 1

; 1

S

p 1

B

[t;T]

generates the value process

V (H

p

)

:=E

t

r

2

p 1

+

p 1 M

T

: (4.3)

Furthermore, for p6=0

V(p;t 0

;T)= sgn (q) E

t 0

h

E

t 0

pr q

2

2

T i

E

t 0[E

t 0(N)

T ]

; (4.4)

resp. if [t;T]

is strongly totally p-unhedgeable in

M

[t;T] ,

V(p;t 0

;T)= sgn (q)E

t 0

E

t 0

pr q

2

2

T

; (4.5)

and

W

(p;t 0

;T)=sgn(p)(V(p;t 0

;T)) 1

1 p

: (4.6)

Proof. Forp6=0calculate

dU (p)

dx

V (H

p

)

T

= p sgn(q) V (H

p

)

T

p 1

= p sgn(q)E

t

r

2

p 1

+

p 1 M

p 1

T

= p sgn(q)E

t

(p 1)r q

2

2

+M

T

=

sgn (p 1)jpjcB

t

B

E

t

(M +N)

T

;

(20)

resp. for p=0

dU (0)

dx

V (H

p

)

T

= V

(H p

)

T

1

= E

t

r+ 2

M

1

T

= E

t

( r+M)

T

= B

t

B

T E

t

(M)

T

;

and nd a representation (3.8),since E

t

(M +N)

T

>0. Set

Z

opt;q;t;T

:=E

t

(M +N) T

: (4.7)

V (H

p

)

B [t;T]

Z

opt;q;t;T

= 1

B

t E

t

2

p 1 +

p 1 M

T

E

t

(M +N) T

= 1

B

t E

t

(qM +N) T

;

which is a uniformly integrable martingale on [t;T] for p < 1 by as-

sumption. Forp>1and >1 observe

V (H

p

)

T

p

= E

t

r

2

p 1

+

p 1 M

p

T

= E

t

pr q

2

+

2

2

2

p 2

p

(p 1) 2

+qM

T

= E

t

pr q

2

2

p(2 ) 1

p 1

+qM

T

= E

t

pr q

2

2

(1 q( 1))

+qM

T

;

hencewendV (H

p

)

T

2L p+ ~

t (

[t;T]

)forsome~>0,since(1 q( 1))>0

for close to1. By Lemma 3.3we nd (V (H

p

)

) T

;E(M +N) T

to

(21)

be the optimal pair. Forp6=0 we calculate

U (p)

V (H

p

)

T

= sgn (q)

V (H

p

)

T

p

= sgn (q)E

t

r

2

p 1

+

p 1 M

p

T

= sgn (q)E

t

pr q

2

2

+qM

T

= sgn (q)cE

t

(qM +N)

T :

Since E

t

(qM +N) T

is auniformlyintegrablemartingale wend

E

t h

U (p)

V (H

p

)

T i

= sgn (q)c = sgn (q) E

t h

E

t

pr q

2

2

T i

E

t [E

t (N)

T ]

: (4.8)

The lastequation follows from(3.9).

Inthenextsectionwegiveaninterpretationoftheportfoliosgenerated

by H p

.

5. Locally Efficient Portfolios

From Lemma 1.4 and = rS C, d -a.s., we immediately nd

V (

^

H)

:=E

t

(H S) T

=E

t

((r HC)+HM) T

for a process

^

H =

H;

1 HS

B

2L 1

l oc

(S). From Cauchy-Schwarz inequality it follows that

jHCj

p

C p

HCH = p

HCH. We have

[V (

^

H)

;V (

^

H)

]=

V (

^

H)

2

HCH

[t;T]

:

Weinterpret p

HCH asameasurefortherelativeinstantaneousriskof

the portfoliogeneratedby

^

H and

^

H=r HC asameasure for the

instantaneouslyexpectedrelativereturnrate. For 6=0and p

HCH6=

0, we nd for the instantaneous Sharpe-ratio

^

H r

p

HCH

= HC

p

HCH

of in-

stantaneouslyexpected relative excess returnover the instantaneously

risk-free return rate and relative instantaneous risk, HC

p

HCH

and HC

p

HCH

=i H2k+Ker(C)forapredictable,strictly negative,

process k 2 L 2

l oc

(), resp.

HC

p

HCH

= i H 2 k+Ker (C) for a

predictable, strictly positive, process k 2L 2

l oc

(). We call these hedg-

(22)

the caseof atotallyp-unhedgeableprice forriskthe optimalportfolios

generated by H p

are locally eÆcient. See Markowitz (1952, 1987) and

Sharpe (1964, 2000).

Dene the following quantities for p6=0;1:

R (p;t;T)

:=

1

p

dln(V(p;t;T))

dT

; (5.1)

R (p)

:= lim

T!1 1

pT

ln(V(p;0;T)) (5.2)

and

R (0;t;T)

:=

dV(0;t;T)

dT (5.3)

R (0)

:= lim

T!1 1

T

V(0;0;T):

(5.4)

Under some regularity conditions, these quantities exist. By Theorem

4.5we nd immediately

Proposition 5.1. Under the assumptions,

t

= t and pr q

2

2 con-

stant for p6=0;1, resp. r+

2

2

constant forp=0, we have

V(p;t;T) = exp pr q

2

2

(T t)

; (5.5)

R (p;t;T)

= R

(p)

=r+

2

2(1 p)

; (5.6)

resp.

V(0;t;T) =

r+

2

2

(T t);

(5.7)

R (0;t;T)

= R

(0)

=r+

2

2 : (5.8)

SeeBieleckiandPliska(1999,2000)foraninterpretationofthequan-

tities R (p)

and the risk-sensitive stochastic control approach. R (p;t;T)

can be interpreted as an implied forward growth rate of the expected

utility of wealth under the optimalself-nancing hedging strategy. As

we will see in Section 7, another related quantity is the right one to

look at: We dene

Y(p;t;T):=ln(jV(p;t;T)j): (5.9)

(23)

6. Existence of Optimal Portfolios

Let 0 T < 1 be xed. In this section we will assume

S to be

continuousandD q

(

M

[0;T]

)6=;forp>1,resp. forp<1,D e

(

M

[0;T]

)6=

; and V(p;0;T;SF p

(

M

[0;T]

)) < 1. We assume for simplicity in this

section that B =1. The results can be generalized to the case of a B

such that B and B 1

are uniformlybounded on[0;T].

Theorem 6.1. Under the above assumptions, the optimal pair

(V

opt;p;0;T

;Z

opt;q;0;T

),satisfying(3.8)andZ

opt;q;0;T

2D(

M

[0;T]

),exists

for the market

M

[0;T]

with respect to optimization in SF p

(

M

[0;T] ).

Proof. We rst prove the case p > 1. Since A p

1 (

M

[0;T]

) is closed and

convex andsinceL p

(

[0;T]

)isreexivethereexists anelementV

opt;p;0;T

with minimal norm. As inGLP98, Lemma 4.1 and Theorem 4.1, it is

easily shown that V

opt;p;0;T

0. Since U (p)

is concave we have for all

Y 2A p

0 (

M

[0;T] )

U (p)

V

opt;p;0;T

T

+Y

U (p)

V

opt;p;0;T

T

+ dU

(p)

dx

V

opt;p;0;T

T

Y:

(6.1)

It follows fromthe optimalityof V

opt;p;0;T

T

and since dU

(p)

dx

V

opt;p;0;T

T

2

L q

(

[0;T] ) that

E

B

T dU

(p)

dx

V

opt;p;0;T

T

Y

B

T

=0;

(6.2)

for all Y 2 A p

0 (

M

[0;T]

). From V

opt;p;0;T

T

2 L p

(

[0;T]

) it follows that

dU (p)

V

opt;p;0;T

T

2 L q

(

[0;T]

). Since V

opt;p;0;T

T

2 A p

1 (

M

[0;T]

) we have

(24)

E

V

opt;p;0;T

T

p 1

>0. We thereforend

Z

optp;0;T

:=

E h

dU (p)

dx

V

opt;p;0;T

T

F

i

E h

dU (p)

dx

V

opt;p;0;T

T

i

2

D q

(

M

[0;T] ):

(6.3)

Optimality follows now from Proposition 3.1. It was shown in GK98,

Lemma 4.4, that Z

opt ;q;0;T

2D q

(

M

[0;T] ).

Forp<1theresultsofKramkovandSchachermayer(1999),(KS99),

canbeapplied. There,existenceanduniquenessof anoptimalsolution

V

opt;p;0;T

with V

opt;p;0;T

T

> 0 for problem (3.6) is proved. Furthermore,

the existence and uniqueness of a strictly positive process Z opt

, such

that E

Z opt

T

q

= inf

Z2D(

M

[0;T]

) E

h

Z

T

B

T

q i

, and with the following

properties is shown: Z opt

T

= sgn (q)U (p)

(V

opt;p;0;T

T

), V

opt;p;0;T

Z opt

is

a uniformly integrable martingale and for an arbitrary self-nancing

hedgingstrategywithnon-negativevalueprocess V,theprocess VZ opt

is asupermartingale. Wewillshow in the next lemma,that for a con-

tinuous price process Z opt

2D(

M

[0;T] ).

TheworryingfactisofcoursethatZ opt

isingeneralonlyasupermartin-

gale. However,thegivenexample(Example5.1'inKS99),showingthat

Z opt

isingeneralnotalocalmartingale,involvesanon-continuousprice

process. Wedenethe following set ofsemimartingaleslivingon

[0;T]

for 0<1, see KS99:

Y(

M

[0;T] ):=

Y 0jY

0

=1;

V H

B [0;T]

Y is a supermartingale

forall H 2SF 0

(

M

[0;T] )

:

(25)

Lemma 6.2. Assume

S to be continuous and let Y 2Y(

M

[0;T] ) with

Y

T

>0 be given. If there exists a H 0

2SF 0

(

M

[0;T]

) with V H

0

0

=1 and

V H

0

T

>0andsuchthatV H

0

Y isauniformlyintegrablemartingale,then

Y 2D(

M

[0;T] ).

Proof. Since Y is a non-negative supermartingale,we have by J&S87,

Lemma III.3.6, that Y > 0 and Y >0 almost surely and hence Y =

E(Z) for Z :=

1

Y

Y. Since Y is a supermartingale it is a special

semimartingale and therefore Z too. Z admits a representation Z =

A+L,whereA=A T

isapredictableprocessofnitevariation,L=L T

is a local martingale and A

0

= L

0

=0. By J&S87, Theorem III.4.11,

we nd a predictable process K 2 L 2

l oc

(M) and a local martingale

N orthogonal to all components of M, with [M;N] = 0, such that

L=KM +N and the representation Y =E(A+K M+N).

Since V H

0

0 is a local martingale with respect to any equiva-

lent martingale measure, V H

0

T

> 0 implies V H

0

> 0. By Lemma 1.4

there exists a

~

H 0

2 L 2

l oc S

T

such that

~

H 0

; 1

~

H 0

S

B

T

generates V H

0

.

By assumption and since M and

~

H 0

C are continuous, V

H 0

B T

Y =

V (

~

H 0

)

B T

Y = E(

~

H 0

C(K ) +A + (K +

~

H 0

) M + N) T

is a uni-

formly integrable martingale. The Doleon-Dade SDE implies that

V H

0

B T

Y

(

~

H 0

C(K )+A) = V

H 0

B T

Y

V H

0

B T

Y

((K+

~

H 0

)

T

(26)

[0;T], hence constant on [0;T] almost surely, see J&S87, Corollary

I.3.16. We therefore nd E(

~

H 0

C(K ) + A) T

= 1. Now let

H 2L 2

l oc S

T

,set

H := H;

1 HS

B

T

andconsider thediscountedvalue

processV

:=

V (

H)

B T

=E( HC+HM) T

generatedby

H. Wehave

V

Y =E(HC(K )+A+(K+H)M+N) T

=E((H

~

H 0

)C(K )

+(K+H)M+N) T

isasupermartingaleforallH 2L 2

l oc S

T

byas-

sumption. ForH :=K +

~

H 0

wend(V

Y) ((K )C(K ) )=

V

Y (V

Y) ((K+H)M +N) 1 to be a non-decreasing local

supermartingale on [0;T]. Therefore (K )C(K ) = 0, d -a.s.

and from 1 = E(

~

H 0

C(K )+A) T

= E(A) T

we conclude A = 0

and Y =E(M +N) T

2D(

M

[0;T] ).

In DMSSS97, Theorem A-C,(for p=2), and GK98,Theorem 3.1 and

Theorem 4.1, (for p>1), necessary and suÆcient conditions are given

ensuring G p

0 (

M

[0;T]

) to beclosed. These results imply

Proposition 6.3. If G p

0 (

M

[0;T]

) is closed, then

V(p;0;T;SF p

(

M

[0;T]

))=V(p;0;T;G p

(

M

[0;T] ));

(6.4)

and V

opt;p;0;T

can be obtained by a self-nancing hedging strategy in

G p

(

M

[0;T]

). Furthermore, for 0 t T, the optimal pair for the

market

M

[t;T]

is givenby

V

opt;p;0;T

t_

V

opt;p;0;T

t

; Z

opt;q;0;T

t_

Z

opt;q;0;T

t

!

2G p

(

M

[t;T] )D

q

(

M

[t;T] ):

(6.5)

(27)

7. The BSDE Approach

InthissectionwewillputtouseProposition3.1inageneralsetting.

Assumethe existenceofacontinuouslocalmartingaleN orthogonalto

M such that (M;N) has the localmartingale representation property

and [N;N]=

~

C . Since thecase p=0isalready solved (see Remark

4.3) we assume inthis section p6=0;1. Let0tT bexed.

Consider the following formal calculation for the optimal solution

V opt;p;t;T

for a maximizationproblemof terminalutility in the market

M

[t;T]

and anarbitrary attainable Y

B

T 2A

p

0 (M

[t;T] ):

U(V opt;p;t;T

T

+Y)U(V opt;p;t;T

T

)+U 0

(V opt;p;t;T

T

)Y;

(7.1)

implies

E

t

B

T U

0

(V opt;p;t;T

T

) Y

B

T

=0;

(7.2)

sincekY isattainableforallF

t

-measurablerandomvariablesk. Hence

B

T U

0

(V opt;p;t;T

T

)shoulddeneanabsolutelycontinuousmartingalemea-

sure up to normalization. In general this argument breaks down be-

cause of integrability problems. However, for isoelastic utility with

exponent p > 1 this approach works. None the less, we can try the

followingansatz:

c

t B

T U

0

(V opt;p;t;T

T

)=E

t

(M+N)

T

; (7.3)

respectively

ln

c

t B

T U

0

V opt;p;t;T

T

1

E

t

(M+N)

T

=0;

(7.4)

where V opt;p;t;T

=

V (

^

H)

T

for

^

H = H;

1 HS

B

[t;T]

2 L 2

l oc (

S) and 2

L 2

l oc

(N). Ansatz (7.3) leads to a FBSDE. For the isoelastic utility

functions ansatz (7.4) will lead toa BSDE, where (H;) formpart of

the solution. FortsT dene the adapted process

Y p;t;T

s

:=ln

c

t B

s dU

(p)

dx V

opt;p;t;T

s

1

E

t

(M +N)

s

!

: (7.5)

(28)

ApplyingIt^o'sformulaandbythedenitionofthe stochasticexponen-

tialwe nd

Y p;t;T

T

= Y p;t;T

t +

Z

T

t dY

p;t;T

s

= Y p;t;T

t +

Z

T

t

(p 1)H

s C

s H

s

s

~

C

s

s

s C

s

s

2

d

s

+ Z

T

t

((p 1)H

s C

s

s pr

s )d

s

+ Z

T

t (

s

(p 1)H

s )dM

s +

Z

T

t

s dN

s :

BecauseofProposition3.2andtheformulas(3.16)and(3.17)weexpect

Y p;t;T

to be independent of t, hence we arrive at the following BSDE

for tt 0

T:

Y (p;T)

t 0

= Z

T

t 0

(p 1)H

s C

s H

s

s

~

C

s

s

s C

s

s

2

d

s

Z

T

t 0

((p 1)H

s C

s

s pr

s )d

s (7.6)

Z

T

t 0

(

s

(p 1)H

s )dM

s Z

T

t 0

s dN

s :

Conversely, givenan adapted solution(Y (p;T)

;H;)tothe BSDE(7.6)

on [t;T], we can dene a self-nancing hedging strategy in

M

[t;T]

by

using

^

H :=

H;

1 HS

B

[t;T]

(7.7)

asa generator for

V (

^

H)

:=E

t

((r HC)+HM) T

2SF 0

(

M

[t;T]

):

(7.8)

Wealsohave

Z

:=E

t

(M+N) T

2D(

M

[t;T] ):

(7.9)

Lemma 7.1. V (

^

H)

T

and Z

T

satisfy (3.8):

Z

T

= exp

Y (p;T)

t

B jpj B

T

sgn(1 p) dU

(p)

dx

V (

^

H)

T

; (7.10)

(29)

Proof. Observe

1 = exp Z

T

t

(p 1)H

s C

s H

s

s

~

C

s

s

s C

s

s

2

d

s

!

exp Z

T

t

(p 1)H

s C

s

s pr

s d

s

exp

Y (p;T)

t +

Z

T

t

s

(p 1)H

s dM

s +

Z

T

t

s dN

s

;

whichimplies

E

t

(M +N)

T

= exp Z

T

t

(1 p)H

s C

s H

s

2

+(1 p)H

s C

s

s +pr

s d

s

exp

Y (p;T)

t +

Z

T

t

(p 1)H

s dM

s

=

exp Z

T

t r

s H

s C

s

s H

s C

s H

s

2 d

s

p 1

E

t (r )

T exp

Y (p;T)

t

exp Z

T

t H

s dM

s

p 1

= exp

Y (p;T)

t

B

t

B

T E

t

((r HC)+HM) p 1

T

= exp

Y (p;T)

t

B

t jpj

B

T

sgn(1 p) dU

(p)

dx

V (

^

H)

T

:

Proposition 7.2. Assume(Y (p;T)

;(H;))tobeasolutiontotheBSDE

(7.6)on[t;T]. Dene

^

H, resp. V (

^

H)

,Z

by(7.7),resp. (7.8),(7.9). If

for p< 1, E

t

((H +)M+N) T

is a uniformly integrable martin-

gale, respectively if for p>1, V (

^

H)

^

H 2SF p

(

M

[t;T]

), then

V (

^

H)

;Z

(30)

is the optimal pair for the market

M

[t;T]

with respect to optimization

in SF p

t (

M

[t;T]

). Furthermore we have

V(p;t;T)= sgn(q)exp (Y (p;T)

t

)= sgn (q)exp(Y(p;t;T)):

(7.11)

Proof. The rst assertion follows from Proposition 3.1, (7.11) follows

from(3.13).

Conversely, the existence of an optimal pair for the market

M

[t;T] to-

gether with the local martingale representation property of (M;N),

implies the existence of a solution (Y (p;T)

;(H;)) for the BSDE (7.6)

on[t;T] satisfyingthe assumption of Proposition 7.2.

8. Markovian Market Model

As anexample,we willtransforminthis sectionthe BSDE(7.6) for

a (for simplicity time-homogeneous) markovian market model into a

non-linear partial dierentialequation with boundary condition.

Consider the following market model: Assume the existence of a

(m+m 0

)-dimensional Brownian motion W = (W 1

;W 2

) on

1 and

assume F to be generated by W. For simplicity, let ^ = (;

0

) :

R d+d

0

! R d+d

0

and : R d+d

0

! R (d+d

0

)(m+m 0

)

be smooth uniformly

bounded functions with uniformly bounded derivatives of all orders,

such that for all x 2 R d+d

0

,

(x) : R d +d

0

! R d+d

0

is invertible with

uniformlyinxboundedinverse. Furthermore,assume

(x)=C(x)

C 0

(x):R d

R d

0

!R d

R d

0

. Thenthereexists a R d +d

0

-valuedMarkov

process X =(S;S 0

) solving the SDE for x

0 2R

m+m 0

dX

t

=(X^

t

)dt+(X

t )dW

t

; X

0

=x

0 : (8.1)

Denote by M the martingale part of S, and by N the martingale part

of S 0

. Note that M and N are orthogonal. Assume the interest rate

r to be a bounded function of X, and dene B

t

:= exp

R

t

0 r(X

s )ds

for allt 0. Set :=C 1

( rS) and 2

:=C. We nowinterpret

S :=(S;B) asa price process and S 0

as (non-traded)state variables.

Considerthefollowingnon-linearPDEforY :R d

R d

0

[0;1)!R,

(p6=1):

@Y

+L

1 Y +L

2 Y =L

3 Y +L

(p)

Y +q

2

pr;

(31)

with boundary condition Y(s;s 0

;0)=0; 8s;s 0

, where

L

1 :=

d

X

i=1

i

@

@s

i +

1

2 d

X

i;j=1 C

i;j

@ 2

@s

i

@s

j

L

2 :=

d 0

X

i=1

0

i

@

@s 0

i +

1

2 d

0

X

i;j=1 C

0

i;j

@ 2

@s 0

i

@s 0

j

;

and for f 2C 1;1

(R d

R d

0

[0;1)),

L

3 f :=

1

2 d

0

X

i;j=1

@f

@s 0

i C

0

i;j

@f

@s 0

j

L (p)

f :=

1

2(p 1) d

X

i;j=1

@f

@s

i C

i;j

@f

@s

j q

d

X

i;j=1

@f

@s

i C

i;j

j :

Assume Y (p)

2 C 2;2;1

(R d

R d

0

[0;1)) to be a solution of the PDE

(8.2),satisfyingtheboundaryconditionY (p)

(;;0)=0. ApplyingIt^o's

formulato the process Y (p;T)

t

:=Y (p)

(S

t

;S 0

t

;T t) we nd

Y (p;T)

; H opt;p;T

; opt;q;T

:=

Y (p;T)

;

(S

;S 0

)

@Y (p)

@s (S

;S 0

;T )

p 1

;

@Y (p)

@s 0

(S

;S 0

;T )

; (8.2)

tobeasolution forthe BSDE(7.6). Wegive(admittedlyquitestrong

and not easy to check) conditions, ensuring Y (p;T)

;(H;)

to be a

useful solution:

Theorem 8.1. If forp>1, E(M+ opt;q;T

N)

T 2L

q+

(

[0;T]

)for

an>0,resp. ifforp<1;p6=0,E (+H opt;p;T

)M + opt;p;T

N

T

is a uniformly integrable martingale, then for all 0tT

V opt;p;t;T

=E

t

r H

opt;p;T

C

+H opt;p;T

M

T

; (8.3)

and

Z

opt;q;t;T

=E

t

(M+ opt;q;T

N) T

: (8.4)

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

One approach to simultaneously characterize optimal trading strategies and utilities uses the theory of forward-backward stochastic differential equations (FBSDE).. Their results

Given a candidate of the price process, the agents trade with both stock and risk security in order to maximize the expected utility of the wealth at the end of the trading period..

Abstract: To get optimal production and hedging decision with normal random variables, Lien (2008) compares the exponential utility function with its second order approximation..

Dynamic monetary utility functionals, or DMU functionals for short, can be seen as generalizations of the ordinary conditional expectation, the usual functional which is to be

Our method combines two recent advances in the theory of optimal investments: the general duality theory for robust utility maximization and the stochastic control approach to the

For an exponential utility function, we compare the optimal contingent claim in the UBSR-constrained problem with a binding risk constraint to two benchmark cases: the solution to

In his symbouleutic speech “Concerning Concord” (Oratio 23), Aelius Aristides urged the cities of Asia to stop their rivalries (163 C.E.). In Oratio 24, he appeals to the Rhodians

The aim of this chapter is to study the specific quadratic semimartingale BSDE (1.3.1) arising in (unconstrained) power utility maximization concentrating on a market price of risk