• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Financial price fluctuations in a stock market model with many interacting agents

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Financial price fluctuations in a stock market model with many interacting agents"

Copied!
37
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

with many interacting agents

Ulrich Horst

Institut furMathematik

Humboldt-Universitatzu Berlin

Unter den Linden 6

D-10099Berlin

13th June 2001

Abstract

We consider anancial market model with alarge numberof in-

teracting agents. Investors are heterogeneous in their expectations

about the future evolution of an asset price process. Their current

expectation is based on the previous statesof their \neighbors" and

onarandomsignalaboutthe\moodofthemarket". Weanalyzethe

asymptoticsofbothaggregatebehaviourandassetprices. Wegivesuf-

cientconditionsforthedistributionofequilibriumpricestoconverge

toauniqueequilibrium, and provideamicroeconomicfoundation for

theuseofdiusionmodelsintheanalysisofnancialpriceuctuations.

Key Words: behavioral nance, diusion models, stochastic dierence

equations, interactingMarkovchains

AMS 2000 subject classication: 60K35,60J20, 60F05, 91B28

ThepresentpaperisbasedonmyPh.D.thesis. IamgratefultomysupervisorHans

Follmerfor numeroussuggestions and for many motivatinginputs. Thanks are dueto

PeterBank,DirkBecherer,PeterLeukert,AlexanderSchied,andChing-TangWuforin-

numerableandfruitfuldiscussions. FinancialsupportofDeutscheForschungsgemeinschaft

(SFB373,\QuanticationandSimulationofEconomicProcesses",Humboldt-Universitat

zuBerlin)isgratefullyacknowledged.

(2)

Inmathematical nance,the priceprocess of ariskyassert is usuallymod-

eledasthetrajectoryofastochasticprocessonsomeunderlyingprobability

space(;F;P). SuchaprobabilisticapproachwasrstinitiatedbyBachelier

(1900), who introducedBrownian motion asa model forprice uctuations

ontheParisstockexchange. Aspricesshouldstaypositive,geometricBrow-

nianmotionisnowwidelyusedasthebasicreferencemodelintheanalysis

of nancial price uctuations. Kreps (1982) showed that such a diusion

model can be justied asthe rational expectation equilibrium ina market

with highly rational agents who all believe in this kind of price dynamics,

and who instantaneously and rationally discount all available information

into thepresentprice. Fromthistheoreticalpoint ofviewlargeand sudden

priceuctuationsreectrationalchangesinthevaluationofanassetrather

thanirrationalshiftsinthesentiment of investors.

Traders, bycontrast,oftenconsidernancialmarketsasbeingmuchless

rational. Many practitioners believe that technical trading is possible,and

thatherd eects unrelatedto economic fundamentalscan cause bubblesor

crashes. In particular,they aretypicallyawareof thefact thatasset prices

maybedrivenbysuddenshiftsinthe\moodofthemarket". Inviewofsuch

market realities, it seems natural to regard priceprocesses asthe result of

aninteractionbetweenmanyagentswithboundedrationality. Inparticular,

oneshouldadmitimitationandcontagioneectsintheformationofagents'

expectations. When the set A of agents involved inthe formation of stock

prices becomes large, such an approach allows to bring in techniques from

the theory of interacting Markov processes or from Markov random eld

theory. An early attempt into this direction has been made by Follmer

(1974) whoconsidersa static modelof endogenouspreference formation.

In thispaperwe providea uniedprobabilisticframework formodeling

nancial markets where the demand for a risky asset results from the in-

teractionofa largenumberof traders. Followinganapproach suggestedby

Follmerand Schweizer (1993),we are goingto view the stockpriceprocess

asasequence of temporarypriceequilibria. We assumethat theexcess de-

mandof agent a2A inperiodtdependsonhis current individualstate x a

t

reecting, forexample, his expectation aboutthe future evolution of stock

prices. Suchadistinctionbetweendierenttypesofagentshasbeenamajor

(3)

conomic models; see, e.g. Brock and Hommes (1997), Kirman (1998), Lux

(1998) orLuxand Marchesi(1999). Fora givenconguration ofindividual

statesx=(x a

)

a2A

,thelawofagent a'snewstate dependsbothon thecur-

rent states(x b

)

b2N(a)

oftheagents inhissocialneighborhood N(a) andon

theaverage expectation in thewhole population, i.e., on the \mood of the

market". The mood of the market is described by the empirical distribu-

tion of individualagents' states or, more completely, by theempirical eld

R (x) associated with the conguration x. We consider a situation where

an individual agent has complete information about the actions chosen by

agentsinhisreferencegroup,butonlyhasincompleteinformationaboutthe

average action throughout the entire population. Individual trader do not

knowR (x) forsure,butonlyobserve arandom signal,e.g.,a stock market

index,whose distributiondependson R (x).

Inournancialmarketmodel,therandomevolutionof themood ofthe

market is the only component aecting the formation of temporary price

equilibria. The microscopic process fx

t g

t2N

which describes thestochastic

evolution of all the individualstates generates via the macroscopic process

fR (x

t )g

t2N

an endogenous random environment f%~

t g

t2N

for the evolution

of theassetprice process. Thedynamics of thestock priceprocess fp

t g

t2N

obeys a recursiverelationof theform

p

t+1

=F(%~

t+1

;p

t

) (t2N) : (1)

Ouraimisto stateconditionswhichensurethatthestockpricesbehave

asymptotically in a stable manner. To this end, we shall rst analyze the

long runbehaviour of the macroscopic process fR (x

t )g

t2N

which describes

thedynamicsofaggregatebehaviour. Usingresultsabouttheasymptoticbe-

haviour oflocally andgloballyinteractingMarkov chainsprovidedinHorst

(2000),weshowthat, inthelimitofaninnitesetA oftraders,thedynam-

icson thelevelof aggregate behaviour can be describedbyaMarkovchain

associated witha suitablerandomsystemwith completeconnections. This

allows us to state conditions on the behaviour of individual agents which

guarantee that themood ofthemarket settles down inthelong run. More

precisely,weplaceaquantitativeboundoftheeectsofsocialinteractionin

oureconomy, and show thatthe macroscopic processconverges inlawto a

uniqueequilibriumdistributioniftheinteractionbetweendierentagentsis

(4)

evolvesina stationary randomenvironment.

Inthesecondpartofthispaperwestudytheasymptoticsoftheinduced

equilibrium price process. In a rst step, we analyze an ergodic reference

model,i.e.,weassumethatthedrivingsequencef%~

t g

t2N

isstationaryander-

godic. Economically,thisamountsto asituationwherethemoodisalready

in equilibrium. We show that the asset price process becomes asymptot-

ically stationary if the destabilizing eects of the random environment on

thedynamicsofthepriceprocessisonaveragenottoostrong. Nonetheless,

thepriceuctuationsinournancialmarketmodelmay be highlyvolatile.

Thisfeaturemaybeinterpretedasthetemporaryoccurrenceofbubblesand

crashesina nancialmarketmodel whoseoverallbehaviouris ergodic.

From an economic point of view, however, such a stationarity assump-

tion on the driving sequence might be rather restrictive. Instead, it seems

more natural to investigate the asymptotic behaviour of asset prices un-

der the assumption the at the mood is out of equilibrium, i.e., under the

assumptionthattherandomenvironmentfortheevolution ofthepricepro-

cessisspeciedbyanon-stationarystochasticprocess. However, giventhat

themacroscopicprocesssettlesdowninthelongrun,itis desirabletohave

suÆcientconditionswhichensurethatassetpricesaredrivenintoastation-

ary regime. Assuming a simple log-linear structure for the excess demand

functionsleadsto a classof log-linearpriceprocessesof theform

logp

t+1

=f(~%

t+1 )logp

t +g(~%

t+1

) (t2N): (2)

Underasuitablemean-contraction conditionon thepricedynamicsfp

t g

t2N

speciedby (2) we show that stock prices converge to a stationary regime

ifthe mood of the market itself settles down inthe long run. Armed with

these resultsone could now try to analyze thestructure of theequilibrium

distribution,and toestimate, forexample,theasymptoticvariance ofstock

prices. Such an empirical analysis, however, is beyond the scope of this

paper,and isleft forfuture research.

In our nal section we study a diusion approximation of the discrete-

time price process fp

t g

t2N

. Under simplifying assumption on excess de-

mand functions of the agents, the sequence of temporary price equilibria

can be approximated in law by a diusion process fP

t g

t0

in continuous

time. Thisresult providesanothermicroeconomicfoundation fortheuse of

(5)

ofthemarketisalreadyinequilibrium,i.e.,iftheassetpriceprocessevolves

in a stationary and ergodic random environment, then we nd ourselves

in the setting analyzed in Follmer and Schweizer (1993), who obtained a

continuous-time model from a sequence of suitably specied discrete-time

processes evolving in an exogenously given random environment; see also

Follmer (1994). Proving a functional central limit theorem for stochastic

processes evolving in a non-stationary random environment, we are able

to extend the Follmer-Schweizer model by (i) analyzing a situation were

thedrivingsequence isderived endogenously,and (ii)byreplacingthesta-

tionarityassumptionon themoodofthemarketbyanasymptoticstability

condition. WeshowthatthediusionlimitfP

t g

t0

convergestoastationary

process whoseinvariant distributioncan begiven inclosedform.

Therest of thispaperisorganized asfollows. InSection2weintroduce

ournancial market model. In Sections 3 and 4 we describe the dynamics

of individualand aggregate behaviour,respectively. Section 5analyzes the

asymptoticbehaviour ofthe discrete-time assetprice process. In Section 6

we passto a diusionlimitincontinuoustime. Section7 concludes.

2 The Microeconomic Model

Letus describea temporary equilibriummodel forthe priceevolution of a

speculative asset. We consider a nancial market model with a countably

innite set A of economic agents trading a single risky asset. In reaction

to a proposed stock price p in period t, each agent a 2 A forms an excess

demand z a

t

(p). Individual excess demand at time t is to be thought of as

thedierencebetweenindividualdemandandindividualinitialendowment

in period t. The actual stock price p

t

at date t will be determined by the

equilibriumconditionof zero total excess demand,and sothepriceprocess

willbegivenbyasequenceoftemporarypriceequilibriafp

t g

t2N

. Weassume

thattheexcess demand ofan individualagent a2A takes theform

z a

t

(p)=z(p;p a

t

): (3)

Here, p a

t

denotes an individual reference level of an agent a at date t, e.g.,

his price expectation for the following period t+1. We shall assume that

agentsareheterogeneousintheirindividualreferencelevels. Moreprecisely,

(6)

at any given date t 2 N, the value p

t

depends on the present individual

state x a

t

of agent a2A, on thepreviousequilibriumpricep

t 1

,and on the

proposedpricep. Thus,it takes theform

p a

t

(p)=g(x a

t

;p

t 1

;p) (4)

forsome measurablefunctiong:CR 2

!R. Here

C:=fc

1

;:::;c

N g

isa xedset of individualstates.

Example2.1 (\Fundamentalists and Chartists") Let us consider a nan-

cial market model where the individual excess demand function takes the

log-linear form

z(p;p a

t

)=logp a

t

logp (5)

asin Follmer and Schweizer (1993). We putC=f 1;0;+1g and consider

a model with optimistic (x a

t

= +1) and pessimistic (x a

t

= 1) information

traders (\fundamentalists") andwith chartists (x a

t

=0).

We assume that a fundamentalist's subjective perception logL+x a

t of

the current value of the assetuctuates aroundsome long run fundamental

value logL. Independent of the proposed price, his expectation is based on

the idea that the nextpricewill movecloser to hisactual benchmark forthe

fair value of the stock. Moreprecisely, his reference level takes the form

logp a

t

=logp

t 1 +c

f

(logL+x a

t

logp

t 1

) (c

f

>0): (6)

The chartist, on the other hand, takes the proposed price as a serious

signal about the future evolution of the security price and replaces L in (6)

by p. Thus,his priceexpectation takes the form

logp a

t

=logp

t 1 +c

c

(logp logp

t 1

) (c

c

>0): (7)

In equilibrium, i.e., for p = p

t

, a chartist forecasts the future evolution of

the asset price process from past observations.

In our model, the dynamics of the price process will be induced by an

underlyingmicroscopicprocess fx

t g

t2N

=f(x a

t )

a2A g

t2N

whichdescribesthe

(7)

t t2N

valuesin thecongurationspace

E :=C A

=fx=(x a

)

a2A :x

a

2Cg:

We shall view E as a compact metric space which is equipped with the

producttopologyand denote byE theproduct--eldonE.

Let usnowconcentrate on the resulting stockpriceprocess fp

t g

t2N . In

a rst step, we considera situation where only nitely many investors are

active on the market. To this end, we x a sequence fA

n g

n2N

of nite

subsetsofA satisfyingA

n

"A asn"1. Ifonlythetraders inA

n

areactive

onthemarket,theequilibriumstockpricep n

t

atdatetisdeterminedbythe

market clearing condition of zero total excess demand, i.e., p n

t

is given by

an implicitsolutionof theequation

X

a2A

n z

a

t (p

n

t

)=0: (8)

In view of (3) and (4), and in terms of per capita excess demand, we can

rewrite(8) as

Z

C z(p

n

t

;g(c;p n

t 1

;p n

t ))%

n

(x

t

)(dc) =0: (9)

Here,

% n

(x

t ):=

1

jA

n j

X

a2A

n Æ

x a

t

()2M(C)

denotestheempiricaldistribution ofthestates assumed bythe traders a2

A

n

inperiodt, and M(C) istheclass of allprobabilitymeasureson C.

For any n 2 N, the implicit equation (9) denes the sequence of tem-

porary equilibrium prices fp n

t g

t2N

in the case of a nite set A

n

of traders

whoare involved intheformationof equilibriumprices. Inorder to extend

the construction of equilibrium prices to the innite system of all agents,

we are going to restrict our state space E to the classE

0

of congurations

x=(x a

)

a2A

2E whichadmit theweak limit

%(x):= lim

n!1

% n

(x):

(8)

E

0 :=

(

x2E:9 lim

n!1 1

jA

n j

X

a2A

n Æ

x a

()2M(C) )

:

Thus, forx2E

0

theempiricaldistribution%(x) associatedwiththecong-

urationx exists. We willcall%(x

t

) themoodof themarketat timet.

Even though we consider an economy with a countably innite set of

agents,itseemsreasonabletoviewthesetofagentswhoaredirectlyinvolved

intheformationoftheequilibriumpriceatdatetasarandomsubsetA

t A

ofrepresentativeagents. By sayingthatA

t

isa setof representative agents

we mean that the empirical distribution %~

t

of the states assumed by the

tradersinA

t

isa randomvariable whoseconditional law

~

Q(%(x

t

);): (10)

isdescribed bya stochastic kernel

~

Qfrom M(C) to M(C).

We are now ready to dene the equilibrium price p

t

at date t. In the

limitof an innite set of agents, p

t

will be given as an implicit solution of

theequation

Z

C z(p

t

;g(c;p

t 1

;p

t ))%~

t

(dc)=0 (11)

which may be viewed as the limiting form of (9). In order to obtain a

uniquely denedstock priceprocess, we impose thefollowing conditionon

theexcess demandfunctionz:

Assumption 2.2 There exists a measurable function F :M(C)R ! R

such that the implicitequation

Z

C z(p

;g(c;p;p

))~% (dc)=0

admits a unique solution p

=F(% ;~ p)for any pair (% ;~ p)2M(C)R.

Example2.3 Let us return to the log-linear demand structure described

by (5) together with (6) and (7). For a given conguration x

t 2 E

0 , the

empirical distribution %~

t

is described by the proportions %~ +

t

;%~

t

and %~ 0

t of

optimistic and pessimistic fundamentalists andof chartists, respectively. In

(9)

pliesthe following linear structure for the evolution of the logarithmic stock

price process:

logp

t+1

=f(~%

t+1 )logp

t +g(%~

t+1

); (12)

where

f(%~

t ):=

1 c

f (%~

+

t

~

%

t ) c

c

~

% 0

t

1 c

c

~

% 0

t

; g(%(x

t )):=

c

f

(logL+%~ +

t

~

%

t )

1 c

c

~

% 0

t

: (13)

In Section 5.2 we will state conditions which guarantee that the sequence

flogp

t g

t2N

convergestoastationary regime ifthemood ofthemarketsettles

down as t ! 1. Observe, however, that for c

c

> 1, the mappings f and

g have a singularity. If the fraction of chartists who are actually involved

in the formation of price equilibria comes close to the critical value %~= 1

c

c ,

thenthe priceprocessbecomeshighly volatile. Aslight changein thecurrent

proportion of chartists mayhave a lasting eecton assetprices.

GiventhatourAssumption2.2holdstrue,thestockpriceprocessfp

t g

t2N

isdened bytherecursive relation

p

t+1

=F(%~

t+1

;p

t

) (t2N) : (14)

In our setting, the evolution of the empirical distribution of agents' states

istherefore the onlycomponent aecting the formationof temporaryprice

equilibria. The process fx

t g

t2N

generates { via the aggregate quantities

f%(x

t

)g andf~%

t g

t2N

{anendogenousrandomenvironmentfortheevolution

of the stock price process. Our goal is to analyze the long run behaviour

of the asset price process fp

t g

t2N

. To this end, we have to analyze the

asymptotics of thedriving sequence f~%

t g

t2N

. In the next section, we begin

bydescribingthedynamicsofthemicroscopicprocessfx

t g

t2N

. InSection4

we state conditions on the behaviour of individual agents which guarantee

thatthe mood of themarket settlesdown inthelong run. In thiscase the

price process asymptotically evolves in a stationary random environment.

In Section 5 we show that this yields weak convergence of the asset price

process iftheexcess demandfunctionstake thelog-linearform(5).

(10)

Let us now specify the dynamics of the microscopic process fx

t g

t2N . We

assume that, ineach period t, any agent a2A chooses his next state x a

t+1

atrandomaccording tosome probabilitylawwhichdependsonthepresent

congurationofindividualsstatesx

t

=(x a

t )

a2A

. Moreprecisely,theprocess

fx

t g

t2N

willbe describedbya Markovchain,

(x;dy)= Y

a2A

a

(x;dy a

);

on asuitablesubsetof thecongurationspace E=C A

.

The dependence of the probabilitylaw a

on the present conguration

can have both a local and a global component. Local dependence in the

choice of an individual agent a 2 A refers to dependence of a

on some

set of neighbors b 2 N(a). In particular, introducing the notion of local

interaction requires to endow the countable set A with the structure of a

graph,where theagents are thenodesand where interactive linksbetween

certain pairsof agents exist. Since we shallalso admita global component

intheinteraction, we willneedto considerergodicaveragesover thewhole

graph of agents. Therefore, we limit ourselves to the case best understood

so far, where A carriesa lattice structure, and assume that the agents are

located onthed-dimensionalinteger lattice, i.e., A :=Z d

.

The neighborhood orreferencegroup N(a) associatedwithagent a2A

isgiven bytheset

N(a):=fb2A :ja bjl<1g:

Here, jj denotes the Euclidean distance on R d

and l 2 N is a xed \in-

teraction radius". In terms of such peer groups we can model situations

wherethecurrentreference levelp a

t+1

ofagent a,e.g.,hisexpectationabout

thefuture evolution of the stockprice, is inuencedbythe previous states

(x b

t )

b2N(a)

of his neighbors. Note that in our model any agent aects the

next state of just 2 dl

other persons, and so no individualtrader is able to

inuencethemood of thewholemarketinone singleperiod. In thissense,

we considera nancial marketmodel withmany smallinvestors.

In real nancial markets, the behaviour of an individual trader is, of

course,notonlyinuencedbytheactionschosenbytheagents inhis refer-

encegroup,butalso dependsonthecurrentmoodofthemarket,i.e.,onthe

(11)

typicallynothave completeinformationabouttheempiricaldistribution of

individualagents' states ina given period. Instead, itseems reasonable to

assumethattheyonlyhave incompleteinformationabout%(x

t

)inthesense

thattheyreceiveacommonnoisysignals

t

abouttheaverageexpectationat

date t. Forexample, s

t

could be a signal aboutthe fraction ofchartists or

optimisticinformationtraderswhoareactive onthemarketinperiodtand

may be revealed by,e.g., a stock market index. Thus, itmakes immediate

sensetointroducean additionaldependenceon signalsabout\global prop-

erties"of thecurrentconguration, e.g.,a dependenceon signalsaboutthe

moodofthemarket, into theinteraction. The followingsimplevotermodel

illustratesthisapproach.

Example3.1 Let us put C = f0;1g. We assume that an inidividual in-

vestor reacts both to the currents states of his neighbors and to a random

signal s2 [0;1] about the average action throughout the entire population.

For any xed signal s, an agent chooses his next state according to a tran-

sitionlaw a

s

fromE

0

to C which is described by the convex combination

a

s

(x;1)=p(x a

)+m a

(x)+s: (15)

Here, p(x a

)measures the dependenceof agent a'snewstate on hiscurrent

one,andm a

(x)istheproportionof`1' intheneighborhood N(a). Moreover,

s 2 [0;1] denotes a commonly known random signal about the empirical

average

m(x):= lim

n!1 1

jA

n j

X

a2A

n x

a

associated with the conguration x 2 E

0

. The conditional law Q(m(x

t );)

of the signal s

t

given the average m(x

t

) is described by a signal kernel Q

on [0;1]. Due to the linear structure of the transition probabilities a

s , the

law of large numbers shows that, for any given signal sequencefs

t g

t2N , the

process fm(x

t )g

t2N

satises almost surelythe deterministicdynamics

m(x

t+1

)=u(m(x

t );s

t

):=fm(x

t

)p(1)+(1 m(x

t

))p(0)g+m(x

t )+s

t :

In this model, the sequenceof empirical averages fm(x

t )g

t2N

may therefore

be viewed as a Markov chain on the state space [0;1]. In Sections 4 and 5,

(12)

fm(x

t )g

t2N

andtheinducedpriceprocessfp

t g

t2N

convergeinlawtoaunique

equilibrium.

The next exampleshows thatthedynamics ofthesequence fm(x

t )g

t2N

typically cannotbedescribed byaMarkov chain.

Example3.2 Considerthefollowinggeneralizationofthevotermodel(15).

Forx2E

0

ands2[0;1],theindividualtransitionprobabilitiesaredescribed

by a measurable mapping g

s :C

jN(a)j

![0;1]in the sensethat

a

s

(x;1) =g

s

fx b

g

b2N(a)

: (16)

Typically,wecannotexpectthatthereexistafunctionu:[0;1][0;1]![0;1]

such that m(x

t+1

)=u(m(x

t );s

t

). Nevertheless,we will showthat the mood

of the marketsettles down in the longrun ifthe dependence of the mapping

g

s on x

b

(b2N(a)) isnot too strong; cf.Example 4.6.

Due to thelocal dependenceof theindividualtransition laws a

on the

current conguration, the dynamics of the mood of the market in general

cannot be described by a Markov chain. In order to analyze the long run

behaviour of aggregatebehaviourin ournancialmarket model,we need a

more general mathematical framework which we are now going to specify.

To start with,we introduce the familyof shift-transformations

a

(a 2A)

on E denedby(

a

x)(b) =x a+b

.

Denition 3.3 (i) Wedenote by M(E) the class of all probability mea-

sures on E. A probability measure 2 M(E) will also be called a

randomeld.

(ii) A random eld 2 M(E) is called homogeneous, if is invariant

underthe shift maps (

a )

a2A . By

M

h

(E):=f2M(E) : =Æ

a

for all a2Ag

we denote the class of all homogeneous random elds on E.

(iii) Ahomogeneousrandomeld2M

h

(E)iscalledergodic,ifsatises

a 0-1-law on the -eld of all shift invariant events. The class of all

ergodic probability measures on E isdenoted by M

e (E).

(13)

For agiven n2N we putA

n

:=[ n;n] \A; and denote byE

e

theset

ofall congurationx2E suchthat theempiricaleld R (x), denedasthe

weak limit

R (x):= lim

n!1 1

jA

n j

X

a2A

n Æ

a x

();

exists and belongs to M

e

(E). The empirical eld R (x) carries all macro-

scopic information carried in the conguration of individual states x =

(x a

)

a2A 2E

e

. In particular,theempiricaldistribution

%(x)= lim

n!1 1

jA

n j

X

a2A

n Æ

x a

();

i.e., the mood of the market associated with the conguration x 2 E

e , is

givenasthe one-dimensionalmarginaldistributionof R (x).

Considertheproductkernel

s

onE governedbythetransitionlaws a

s

in(16). Proposition4.1 below shows that the measure

s

(x;)(x 2E

e ) is

concentratedon theset E

e

and thatthe empiricalaverage satises

m(y)=u(R (x);s):=

Z

s

(x;1)R (x)(dz)

s

(x;)-a.s. (17)

Thus, we have to consider the full dynamics of the sequence of empirical

eldsfR (x

t )g

t2N

even if, as in Example3.2, the behaviour of agent a2 A

depends on R (x) only on the empiricalaverage m(x). Theorem 4.2 below

showsthat,incontrasttothesequenceofempiricaldistributionsf%(x

t )g

t2N ,

the dynamics of the sequence of empirical eld fR (x

t )g

t2N

can indeed be

described by a Markov chain. Our aim is to formulate conditions on the

transition laws a

, i.e., on the behaviour of individualagents, which guar-

antee thatthesequence ofempiricaleldsfR (x

t )g

t2N

converges inlawto a

unique equilibrium distribution. In case we will say that the mood of the

marketsettlesdown inthelongrun.

To this end, we shall now be more specic about the structure of the

transition probabilities a

. We assume that theinteractive inuenceof the

present conguration x 2E

e

on agent a is felt both throughthe local sit-

uation(x b

)

b2N(a)

inhis neighborhood,and througha randomsignal about

theaverage situationthroughout theentire population A. The average sit-

uationis describedbytheempiricaleldR (x)associatedwithx2E

e . The

(14)

Q(R (x);) (18)

of the signal s given the empirical eld R (x) is specied by a stochastic

kernelQfrom M

h

(E) to S,whereS isa nitesignal space.

1

ThekernelQ

willbe calledthesignal kernel.

We also assume that interaction between dierent agents is spatially

homogeneous. This means that all traders react in the same manner both

to theactions previously chosen bytheagents intheir reference groupand

to the signal about aggregate behaviour. Thus, for a xed signal s 2 S

andcongurationx2E,theprobabilitythatagent a2A switchesto state

c2C inthefollowingperiodis given by

a

s

(x;c)=

s (

a

x;c); (19)

where

s

(x;)is astochastickernelfrom ES to C.

Assumption 3.4 Theprobabilitylawsf

s (x;)g

x2E

satisfyaspatialMarkov

property of order l in their dependence on the present conguration:

s (

a

x;)=

s (

a

y;) if

a x=

a

y on N(a):

Economically,this condition meansthat, forany xed signalaboutthe mood

of themarket, the newstateof an agent onlydependson the previous states

of this neighbors.

Letusnowxasignal s2S and acongurationx2E. It follows from

ourAssumption3.4and from(19) that

s

(x;):=

Y

a2A

s (

a x;)

denes a Feller kernel on the conguration space E which is spatially ho-

mogeneous:

Z

E f(y)

s (

a

x;dy)= Z

E f(

a y)

s

(x;dy) (20)

1

Theassumption that S is nite merely simplies notation. Ouranalysis also goes

throughundertheassumptionthat(S;S)isanarbitrarymeasurablespace.

(15)

s

togetherwith thesignalkernelQ determinea stochastickernel

(x;):=

Z

S

s

(x;)Q(R (x);ds) (21)

from E

e

to E. Infact, Proposition4.1 below shows that may beviewed

as a stochastic kernel on the conguration space E

e

. In contrast to

s ,

however,thekerneltypicallydoesnothavetheFellerproperty,duetothe

macroscopic dependence on the present conguration x via the empirical

eldR (x). Thus,wecannotapplythemethodinVasserstein(1969)inorder

to study the long run behaviour of the processes fx

t g

t2N

and fR (x

t )g

t2N .

Instead, we will useresults about the asymptotic behaviour of locally and

globallyinteractingMarkovprocessesrecentlyreportedinFollmerandHorst

(2001) andHorst (2001a).

4 The Dynamics of Aggregate Behaviour

Inthissection we aregoing to formulate conditionson theindividualtran-

sition laws

s

and on the signal kernel Q which guarantee that the mood

of the market settles down in the long run.

2

In a rst step, we use a law

of largenumbersfor therandom elds

s

inorder to view asa stochas-

tic kernel on the conguration space E

e

. For the proof we refer to Horst

(2001a),Proposition3.1.

Proposition 4.1 For all congurations x2 E

e

, and for any signal s2 S,

we have

s (x;E

e

) = 1. For

s

(x;)-a.e. y 2 E

e

, the empirical eld R (y)

takes the form

R (y)=u(R (x);s):=

Z

E

s

(y;)R (x)(dy):

In view of the this Proposition, we use E

e

as the state space for our

microscopicprocessfx

t g

t2N

. WedenotebyP

x

thedistributionoftheMarkov

chainfx

t g

t2N

withinitialstatex2E

e

. Sinceacongurationx2E

e

induces

2

Theasymptoticsof the Markov chain is explicitly analyzedinHorst (2001a). In

ordertokeepthepresentpaperself-contained,wesummarizesomeoftheresults,butomit

theproofs.

(16)

t t2N x

a.s.the macroscopic process fR (x

t )g

t2N

with state space M

e

(E). The law

of the random variable R (x

t+1

) depends on the microscopic conguration

x

t

inperiodt onlythroughtheempiricaleldR (x

t

). Thus,itis easilyseen

thatthefollowingresult holdstrue.

Theorem 4.2 (i) Under the measure P

x

the macroscopic process is a

Markov chain on the state space M

e

(S) withinitial value R (x).

(ii) For any given initial conguration x 2 E

e

, and for each xed signal

sequencefs

t g

t2N

our macroscopic process satises

R (x

t+1

)=u(;s

t

)ÆÆu(;s

1

)Æu(R (x);s

0

) P

x

-a.s. (22)

for any t2N.

Since, conditioned on the environment fs

t g

t2N

, the macroscopic pro-

cess followsalmost surelya deterministicdynamics,we proposea \random

systemwithcompleteconnections" (henceforth RSCC)asa suitablemath-

ematical framework for analyzing the dynamics of aggregate behaviour in

ournancialmarketmodel. Letusrecall thenotionof aRSCC.

Denition 4.3 Let (M

1

;d

M

1

) be a metric space and (M

2

;M

2

) be a mea-

surable space. Let Z denote a stochastic kernel from M

1 to M

2

, and let

v : M

1

M

2

! M

1

be a measurable mapping. Following Iosefescu and

Theodorescu (1968), we call the quadruple

:=((M

1

;d

M1 );(M

2

;M

2 );Z ;v)

arandomsystem withcompleteconnections.

3

(i) Given an initial value 2 M

1

, a RSCC induces two stochastic pro-

cessesf

t g

t2N

andf

t g

t2N

onthecanonicalprobability space(

^

;

^

F;

^

P

)

takingvalues in M

1

and in M

2

, respectively, by

t+1

=v(

t

;

t ) and

^

P

(

t 2j

t

;

t 1

;

t 1

;

t 2

;:::)=Z(

t

;):

3

Werefer the readertothe books ofIosefescu andTheodorescu (1968) and Norman

(1972) for adetaileddiscussionof RSCCs. Underthe dierentname \iteratedfunction

systems", this class of processes is also studied in, e.g., Barnsley, Demko, Elton, and

Geronimo(1988)andLasotaandYork(1994).

(17)

Here,

0

= P

-a.s. These processes arecalled the associatedMarkov

process and the signalsequence, respectively.

(ii) Wesay thata randomsystemwithcompleteconnections isadistance-

diminishingmodel, if the transformation v :M

1

M

2

!M

1

satises

the contraction condition

d

M

1

(v(;);v(

^

;))d

M

1 (;

^

)

for some constant <1.

Let f

t g

t2N

be a Markov chain associated with a random system with

completeconnections=((M

1

;d

M1 );(M

2

;M

2

);Z ;v). Foranyxed signal

sequence f

t g

t2N

,we have that

t+1

=v(;

t

)ÆÆv(;

1

)Æu(;

0 )

^

P

-a.s. (23)

Letusnowxaninitialcongurationx2E

e

. Inviewof (20)and(23), our

macroscopicprocessmaybeviewedastheMarkovchainwithstartingpoint

R (x)associated withtherandomsystem withcompleteconnections

:=((M

h

(E);d);(S;S);Q;u); (24)

wherethemapping u:M

h

(E)S !M

h

(E) is denedby

u(R ;s):=

Z

E

s

(x;)R (dx);

and where d denotes the metric introduced in Follmer and Horst (2001)

whichinducestheweaktopologyonM

h

(E);seealso(2.53)inHorst(2000).

4

Indeed,letusdenoteby(f

t g

t2N

;(

^

P

% )

%2M

h (E)

)theMarkovchainonM

h (E)

N

associated with

. Aneasy inductionargumentshowsthat

P

x [fR (x

t )g

t2N

2B]=

^

P

R(x) [f

t g

t2N

;2B] (25)

forallB inB N

,theBorel--eldonM

h (E)

N

. Inorderto guaranteeasymp-

totic stability of our macroscopic process, it is therefore enough to state

4

ObservethatwearegoingtoviewthemacroscopicprocessasaMarkovchainonthe

compactmetricspace(M

h

(E);d)eventhoughR (x

t )2M

e

(E)forallt2N . Wereferto

Horst(2001a)foradetaileddiscussionofthisissue.

(18)

t 2N

auniqueequilibrium. Dueto Theorem4.1.2 inNorman(1972), theprocess

f

t g

t2N

converges inlawwhenevertherandomsystem

isdistancedimin-

ishingin thesenseof Denition4.3 (ii), and given thatthe signalkernel Q

satisesthefollowingconditions.

Assumption 4.4 (i) The signal kernel Q from M

h

(E) to S satises a

uniformLipschitz condition in the sense that

sup

s2S;6=

^

jQ(;s) Q(

^

;s)

d(;

^

)

L<1: (26)

(ii) Wehave that inf

;i Q(;s

i )>0.

Remark 4.5 Economically, our Assumption 4.4 (ii) states that the agents

receiveevery signal withsmall butpositiveprobability, regardless of the pre-

vailingmood of the market. Both parts (i) and (ii) of the above assumption

exclude situations where the traders have complete information about the

aggregate behaviour throughout the entirepopulation.

Let usnow state a conditionon theindividualtransition laws

s which

guarantees that the random system

is distance diminishing. To this

end, we dene, for any pair (a;s) 2 A S, a vector r s

a

= (r s

a;b )

b2A with

components

r s

a;b

=sup

1

2 k

s

(x;)

s

(y;)k:x=y oa b

(b2A);

wherek

s

(x;)

s

(y;)k denotesthetotal variationdistanceof thesigned

measure

s

(x;)

s

(y;)onthesetC. Sinceweassumethattheinteraction

betweendierentagents isspatiallyhomogeneous, itis easilyseen that

r s

a;b

=r s

a b;0

(a;b2A) :

Economically, the quantity r s

a;0

measures, fora xed signal s2 S, the de-

pendenceofthenewstateofagent0onthecurrentstateofagenta. Inorder

to ensure convergence of the mood of the market, we place a quantitative

(19)

Weak SocialInteractionprevailsif

:=sup

s X

a r

s

a;0

<1; (27)

i.e., if the dependence of an agent's action on the current conguration is

nottoo strong. Our weak socialinteractionassumptionexcludessituations

where an agents imitates with probability one the behaviour of any of his

neighbors.

Beforewe provethemainresultofthissection,weconsider asimpleex-

ample,whereourweaksocialinteractionassumptioncanindeedweveried.

Example4.6 Let us x a conguration x 2 E

e

and a signal s 2 S, and

assume that the probability that an agent switches to state `1' is given by

(16). Suppose that the mapping g

s : C

jN(a)j

! [0;1] is dierentiable, and

denote the partial derivative withrespect tox b

by g b

s . If

max

s X

a2N(0) max

n

g a

s

(x b

)

b2N(0)

: x b

2C o

<1;

then our weaksocial interactioncondition (27) is satised.

We shallnowstateconditionsonthebehaviourofindividualagentsand

on thesignal kernelQ which guarantee asymptotic stabilityon thelevel of

aggregate behaviour.

Theorem 4.7 Suppose that our Assumption 4.4 holds true, and that the

weak social interaction condition (27) is satised. Then the macroscopic

process fR (x

t )g

t2N

converges in law to a unique stationary distribution

.

Here

isa probability measures on M

h (E).

Proof: Due to Lemma 4.9 in Horst (2001a), our weak social interaction

conditionyields

ju(;s) u(

^

;s)jd(;

^

) (;

^

2M

h

(E); s2S):

Thus, therandomsystemwith completeconnections

introducedin (24)

is distance diminishingin the sense of Denition 4.3 (ii). In view of (25),

our assertion therefore follows from Theorem 4.1.2 in Norman (1972) as

(M

h

(E);d)is acompact metricspace. 2

(20)

Wearenowgoingtoanalyzethelongrunbehaviourofstockpricesinour-

nancialmarketmodel. Inordertosimplifynotation,andinviewof(25),we

shallfromnowon assumethattherandomenvironmentf~% g

t2N

fortheevo-

lution of the asset price process fp

t g

t2N

is generated by the Markov chain

(f

t g

t2N

;(

^

P

)

2M

h (E)

) associated with the random system with complete

connections

introducedin(24). More precisely,we considera pricepro-

cessfp

t g

t2N

whichisdenedbytherecursiverelation(14),butassumethat

theconditional law

~

Q(

t

;) (28)

oftherandomvariable%~

t

giventherandomeld

t

isdescribedbyastochas-

tic kernel

~

Q from M

h

(E) to M(C). Throughout this section, we assume

thattheassumptionsstated inTheorem4.7aresatised.

In Section5.1we consideran ergodicreference model. We shall assume

thattheinitialdistributionoftheMarkovchainf

t g

t2N

isgivenbyitsunique

invariantdistribution

. Underthelaw

^

P

()

:=

R

^

P

()

(d)theprocess

f

t g

t2N

is stationary and ergodic. In economic terms this amounts to a

situationwherethemoodofthemarketisalready inequilibrium. Imposing

asuitablemean-contractionconditiononthetransformationF weshowthat

the sequence fp

t g

t2N

governed by (14) converges pathwise to a stationary

process fP

t g

t2N

inthesensethat

^

P

[lim

t!1 jp

t P

t

j=0]=1: (29)

Nonetheless, the price uctuations in our nancial market model may be

highly volatile. Consider, for example the log-linear dynamics (12) and

assume that c

c

> 1. In periods where the fraction of chartists who are

involved in the formation of equilibrium prices comes close to the critical

value 1

c

c

, the process fp

t g

t2N

may become highly unstable. Economically,

this feature can be interpreted as the temporary occurrence of bubbles or

crashesina nancialmarketmodel whoseoverallbehaviouris ergodic.

In Section 5.2, we concentrate on a nancial market model where the

sequenceoftemporarypriceequilibriaisgoverned byalog-linearstochastic

dierenceequation oftheform

logp

t+1

=f(~%

t+1 )logp

t +g(~%

t+1

) (t2N):

(21)

butsettlesdowninthelongrun. Westate conditionsonthenon-stationary

randomenvironment f~%

t g

t2N

whichensurethat thepriceprocess converges

to astationary regime.

5.1 EquilibriumPrices in a Stationary Environment

Letusanalyzethelongrunbehaviouroftheassetpriceprocessinanergodic

referencemodel. WeassumethattheMarkovchainf

t g

t2N

whichdescribed

the stochastic evolution of the aggregate behaviour already starts in its

probabilistic equilibrium

; see Theorem 4.7. In this case, the sequence

of temporaryprice equilibriafp

t g

t2N

is driven by a stationary and ergodic

random environment f%~

t g

t2N

, and so we can apply a result provided in

Borovkov(1998)inordertostudytoasymptotics oftheassetpriceprocess.

We denote by p the initial price at time t = 0, put %~ 0

n := (%~

1

;:::;%~

n )

andassume thatthe followingconditionsconcerningtheiterates

F(%~ 0

n

;p):=F(%~

n

;)ÆÆF(%~

2

;)ÆF(%~

1

;p) (n2N):

aresatised;see also Borovkov(1998), Chapter2, Section8.

Assumption 5.1 (i) For some p

0

2 R and for each Æ > 0, there exists

N =N(Æ) such that, for all n1, we have

^

P

[jp

0 F(%~

0

n

;p

0

)j>N]<Æ:

Thus,the sequence fp

t g

t2N

isassumed to bebounded in probability.

(ii) ThefunctionF =F(% ;~ p)iscontinuousinpandthereexistsaninteger

r1, a number >0, and a measurable function c:R r

! R

+ such

that

jF(%~ 0

r

;p

1

) F(%~ 0

r

;p

2

)j c(%~ 0

r )jp

1 p

2

j (p

1

;p

2 2R)

1

r

^

E

logc(%~ 0

r

) ;

where

^

E

denotes the expectation with respect to the measure

^

P

.

(iii) Thesequenceflogc(%~

jr

;::: ;%~

jr+r )g

j2N

satisesthestronglawoflarge

numbers.

(22)

condition for the sequence fp

t g

t2N

governed by (14). The next theorem

follows from Theorem 12.2 in Borovkov (1998). In the case of a linear

transformationF,itreduces to Theorem1 inBrandt(1986).

Theorem 5.2 SupposethatAssumption5.1issatised. Thenthereexistsa

stationaryprocessfP

t g

t2N

suchthat, foranystarting pointpofthesequence

fp

t g

t2N

, we have

^

P

[lim

t!1 jP

t p

t

j=0]=1:

If the initial value p has the same distribution as the random variable P

0 ,

then the price process fp

t g

t2N

is stationary.

Forournancialmarketmodel,andundertheassumptionthatthemood

of the market is already in equilibrium,Theorem 5.2 provides a boundfor

the aggregate eect of interaction between dierent traders which ensures

that the inducedprice uctuations are asymptotically stationary. Beyond

this bound the price process may become highly transient. A continuous-

timeanalogueofTheorem5.2isformulatedinFollmerandSchweizer(1993),

whereitisshownthatthetrajectoriesinasimplelog-linearmodelmayeither

tendto zeroorgooto innitywithpositiveprobabilityifthedestabilizing

eectsof theenvironmentare onaverage too strong.

Example5.3 Consider the log-linear demand structure described by (5)

together with(6)and(7). Inthiscase,themarketclearingconditionimplies

the log-linear price dynamics of the form

logp

t+1

=f(%~

t+1 )logp

t +g(%~

t+1 );

where the mappings f;g:M(C)!R aregiven by (13). If the conditions

^

E

logjf(%^

0

)j<0 and

^

E

(logjg(%^

0 )j)

+

<1

are satised, then the price process converges pathwise to a stationary pro-

cess. Such a log-linear pricedynamics isanalyzed in detail in Section 5.2.

Example5.4 (Generalized auto-regression) Suppose that the sequence of

equilibrium prices fp

t g

t2N

obeys the recurrence relation

p

t+1

=G(f(%~

t+1 )

^

G(p

t

)+g(%~

t+1 ));

(23)

where G;G:R !R areLipschitz continuous functions, i.e.,

j

^

G(p

1 )

^

G(p

2 )j

^

kjp

1 p

2

j; jG(p

1

) G(p

2

)jkjp

1 p

2 j:

As a result of Theorems 8.4 and 12.2 in Borovkov (1998), the sequence

fp

t g

t2N

satises parts (i) and(ii) of our Assumption5.1 if

logj

^

kkj+

^

E

logjf(%~

0

)j<0 and

^

E

(logjg(~%

0 )j)

+

<1:

5.2 EquilibriumPrices in a Non-Stationary Environment

Let us now concentrate on a nancial market model where both the indi-

vidual excess demands functions and the reference levels take a log-linear

form; see for instance (5) together with (6) and (7). In such a situation,

thedynamicsofourpriceuctuationsisdescribedbyastochasticsequence

fp

t g

t2N

whichobeys thelog-linearrecursiverelation

logp

t+1

=f(~%

t+1 )logp

t +g(~%

t+1

) (t2N): (30)

Our goal is to analyze the asymptotic behaviour of asset prices under the

assumptionthatthe moodof themarketis outofequilibriumbutbecomes

stationary inthelongrun.

In order to make this more precise, note rst that the environment

f~%

t g

t2N

fortheevolutionofthepriceprocessisstationaryandergodicunder

thelaw

^

P

. Next, we introducethe -elds

^

F

t

:=(%~

s

:st)

anddenoteby

^

T :=

T

t2N

^

F

t

thetail-eldgeneratedbythesequencef~% g

t2N .

We saythat theprocess f~% g

t2N

has anice asymptoticbehaviour,if

lim

t!1 sup

k

^

P

^

P

k

^

Ft

=0: (31)

Here,k

^

P

^

P

k

^

Ft

denotesthetotalvariationofthesignedmeasure

^

P

^

P

on

^

F

t

. Since the total variation distance is continuous along decreasing -

algebras,we have

lim

t!1 k

^

P

^

P

k

^

Ft

=k

^

P

^

P

k

^

T :

(24)

Thus, (31)impliesthat P

=P

on T,and sotheasymptoticbehaviour of

anicedrivingsequence f~%

t g

t2N

isthesameunder

^

P

andunder

^

P

. Inthis

sensethesequence f~%g

t2N

becomesstationary inthe longrun.

Lemma 5.6belowshowsthat theprocess f%~

t g

t2N

has anice asymptotic

behaviour wheneverthe Markovchainf

t g

t2N

converges inlawto a unique

equilibriumandifthestochastickernel

~

Qintroducedin(28)satisesamild

regularity condition. Using this result, we show in Theorem 5.7, that our

nancialpriceuctuations behave asymptoticallyina stablemanner ifthe

destabilizingeectsoftherandomenvironmentonthedynamicsoftheprice

process areon average not toostrong.

Assumption 5.5 The stochastic kernel

~

Q from (M

h

(E);d) to M(C) in-

troduced in (28) satises a uniform Lipschitz condition:

k

~

Q (;)

~

Q(

^

;)kLd(;

^

):

Letusnowestablishthefollowingresultabouttheasymptoticbehaviour

ofthedrivingsequence f%~

t g

t2N .

Lemma5.6 Suppose that ourAssumptions4.4and 5.5aresatised. Then

the random environment f%~

t g

t2N

forthe evolution of the assetpriceprocess

has a niceasymptotic behaviourin the sense of (31).

Proof: Letusdenote byB theBorel--eldon(M

h

(E);d). Ina rststep,

we aregoing to establishtheexistence of aconstant L<1 such that

^

P

[f~%

0

;:::;%~

t g2B]

^

P

~

[f~%

0

;:::;%~

t g2B]

Ld(;

~

) (32)

for all t 2 N and B 2 t

i=1

B. To this end, we denote by L

Q

and L

~

Q the

Lipschitz constants for the stochastic kernels Q and

~

Q, respectively, and

introduce thequantity

t

:=sup

B sup

6=

~

^

P

[f~%

0

;%~

2

;:::;%~

t g2B]

^

P

~

[f~%

0

;%~

2

;::: ;%~

t g2B]

d(;

~

)

:

Dueto thecontraction propertyofthetransformationuestablishedinThe-

orem 4.7 and because of the uniform Lipschitz conditions imposed on the

(25)

stochastickernelQ and Q, we havethat

^

P

[f~%

0

;:::;%~

t+1 g2B]

^

P

~

[f~%

0

;:::;%~

t+1 g2B]

sup

B

^

P

[~%

0 2B]

^

P

~

[~%

0 2B]

+sup

B

^

Q(;B)

^

Q(

~

;B)

sup

B;s

^

P

u(;s) [f~%

0

;:::;%~

t g2B]

^

P

u(

~

;s) [f~%

0

;:::;%~

t g2B]

(L

~

Q +L

Q

+

t )d(;

~

);

and so

t (L

~

Q +L

Q )

X

i2N

i

L

~

Q +L

Q

1

:

Inparticular,(32) holdswithL= L

~

Q +L

Q

1 .

Let us denote by U t

the t-fold iteration of the transition operator U

associated withtheMarkov chain f

t g

t2N . Since

k

^

P

^

P

k

^

Ft

=sup

B

(U

t

^

P

[f~%

t g

t2N

2B])() Z

P

~

[f~%

t g

t2N 2B]

(d

~

)

and because the mapping 7! P

[f~%

t g

t2N

2 B] from M

h

(E) to [0;1] is

Lipschitz continuous withLipschitz constant L<1,wecan applyLemma

2.1.57inIosefescuandTheodorescu(1968): Thereareconstants

L<1and

<1 such that

sup

;B

(U

t

^

P

[f~%

t g

t2N

2B])() Z

M

h (E)

P

~

[f~%

t g

t2N 2B]

(d

~

)

L t

:

Thisyieldsourassertion. 2

Inourpresentsetting,thelogarithmicstockpriceprocessisdescribedby

alinearrecursive stochasticequation ina non-stationaryenvironment. Un-

dertheassumption that theenvironment has a niceasymptotic behaviour,

the asymptotics of such processes is analyzed in Horst (2001b). These re-

sults allow us to introduce a bound for the aggregate eect of interaction

betweendierent traderswhichensuresthatthepriceprocessisdriveninto

equilibriumwheneverthemoodofthemarketitselfsettlesdowninthelong.

(26)

t t2N

linear relation (30) and that our Assumptions 4.4 and 5.5 are satised. If

the random variables f(%~

0

) and g(%~

0

) satisfy

^

E

logjf(%~

0

)j<0 and

^

E

(log

jg(%~

0 )j)

+

<1; (33)

then there existsa unique probability measure on R N

such that the shifted

sequencefp

t+T g

t2N

convergesin distributionto as T !1.

Proof: Due to (31) and (33), thesequence f(f(%~

t );g(%~

t ))g

t2N

is \nice" in

the sense of Denition 2.1 in Horst (2001b). Thus, our assertion follows

fromTheorem2.4 inHorst(2001b). 2

6 Continuous-Time Asset Price Processes

Inthissection,weshall againassume thatthe dynamicsof thelogarithmic

priceprocesscanbedescribedbylinearrecursivestochasticequation. Under

mild technical assumptionson the drivingsequence f%~

t g

t2N

we willobtain

a continuous-time assetprice process fP

t g

t0

by passageto the limit from

thediscrete-timeequilibriumpriceprocess fp

t g

t2N

denedrecursivelyby

logp

t+1

logp

t

=f(%~

t+1 )logp

t +g(%~

t+1

) (t2N): (34)

TheconvergenceconceptweuseisweakconvergenceontheSkorohoodspace

D d

ofallR d

-valuedright-continuousfunctionswithleftlimitson[0;1), en-

dowed with the weak topology. A similar approach was carried out by

Follmerand Schweizer(1993) whopassedto a continuous-time model from

a sequence of suitably specied discrete-time processes evolving in an ex-

ogenously given stationary and ergodic random environment. We extend

the Follmer-Schweizer model by (i) analyzing a situation were the driving

sequence is derived endogenously, and (ii)byreplacingthe stationarity as-

sumptiononthe moodof themarketbyan asymptoticstabilitycondition.

To this end, we consider in Section 6.1 a sequence of discrete-time

stochastic processes fP n

g

n2N , P

n

= fP n

t g

t2N

, dened recursively by the

linearrelation

P n

t+1 P

n

t

= 1

p

n A

t P

n

t +

1

p

n B

t

(t;n2N)

(27)

t t t2N

non-stationary driving sequence f(A

t

;B

t )g

t2N

which allow us to derive a

convergence result for the processes fP n

g

n2N

. This will be achieved by

applyinganinvarianceprincipletothenon-stationary continuous-time pro-

cessesX n

and Y n

which arespeciedby

X n

t :=

1

p

n [nt]

X

i=0 A

i

and Y n

t :=

1

p

n [nt]

X

i=0 B

i

: (35)

Armedwith these results, we establish in Section6.2 a Black-Scholes type

approximationfortheassetpriceprocess(34)inasituationwherethemood

ofthemarketsettlesdownin thelongrun.

In the sequel itwill be convenient to denote byLaw(X;P) the lawof a

randomvariableX under themeasure P.

6.1 AFunctionalCentralLimitTheoremfor Non-Stationary

Sequences

Letf(A

t

;B

t )g

t2N

asequenceofR 2

-valuedrandomvariablesdenedonsome

probability space (;F;P). For any n 2 N, we consider a discrete-time

process fP n

t g

t2N

given bythelinearrelation

P n

t+1 P

n

t

= 1

p

n A

t P

n

t +

1

p

n B

t

: (36)

IffZ n

t g

t2N

isanydiscrete-timeprocess,weidentifyZ n

withthecontinuous-

time process Z n

t

:= Z n

[nt]

(t 0) whose paths are right-continuous. In

termsofthequantitiesX n

and Y n

denedin(35), ourstochasticdierence

equation (36)is equivalentto thestochastic dierentialequation

dP n

t

=P n

t dX

n

t +dY

n

t

: (37)

If the driving sequence f(A

t

;B

t )g

t2N

is stationary and ergodic under the

law P, and under what Follmer and Schweizer (1993) call \standard as-

sumptions"onthetwosourcesofrandomnessfA

t g

t2N

andfB

t g

t2N

,onecan

applyan invariance principleto thesequences X n

and Y n

(n2N) dened

by (35)and assume that theprocess f(X n

;Y n

)g

n2N

is \good" in thesense

ofthefollowingdenition.

(28)

Denition 6.1 (DuÆe and Protter (1992)) A sequence fZ g

n2N

of semi-

martingales dened on probability spaces ( n

;F n

;P n

) is called \good" if,

for any sequence fH n

g

n2N

of c adl a g adapted processes, the convergence

Law((Z n

;H n

);P n

) w

!Law ((Z ;H);P) (n!1)

implies the convergence

Law

Z n

;H n

; Z

H n

dZ n

;P n

w

!Law

Z ;H;

Z

H dZ

;P

:

Here w

! denotes weak convergenceof probability measures.

Letussummarizes some resultsfrom Follmerand Schweizer(1993).

Proposition 6.2 (i) Suppose that the driving sequence f(A

t

;B

t )g

t2N is

stationary and ergodic and that EA

0

= EB

0

= 0. Under \standard

assumptions"on thetwo sourcesofrandomness fA

t g

t2N

andfB

t g

t2N ,

thesequencef(X n

;Y n

)g

n2N

introduced in (35)convergesin lawtothe

Gaussian martingale (X;Y) = V W. Here, W = (W

1

;W

2

) denotes

a two-dimensional standard Brownian motion and V isa suitable de-

terministic 22 dispersion matrix.

(ii) Ifthesequencef(X n

;Y n

)g

n2N

is\good"inthesenseofDenition6.1,

the process f(X n

;Y n

;P n

)g

n2N

converges in law to (X;Y;P). Here,

P =fP

t g

t0

is the uniquestrong solutionof the stochastic dierential

equation

dP

t

=P

t dX

t +dY

t

: (38)

Thatis, P =fP

t g

t0

is the pathwise solutionof a SDEof the form

dP

t

=P

t dW

t +d~

~

W

t

whereW,

~

W arestandard Brownianmotionswithcorrelation %. If >

0, then the diusion limit fP

t g

t0

converges to a stationary process,

andits invariant distribution can begiven in closed form.

We arenowgoingto establisha\non-stationary" versionofProposition

6.2. We obtain a convergence result for the processes fP n

g

n2N

given that

the driving sequence f(A

t

;B

t )g

t2N

is out of equilibrium, but has a nice

asymptoticbehaviour.

(29)

Assumption 6.3 (i) There exists a probability measure P on (;F)

such that the environment f(A

t

;B

t )g

t2N

is stationary and ergodic un-

derthe law P

.

(ii) Theasymptoticbehaviouroftheenvironmentf(A

t

;B

t )g

t2N

isthesame

underP and underP

, i.e.,

kP P

k

T

= lim

t!1

kP P

k

^

F

t

=0

where

^

F

t

:=((A

s

;B

s

):st) andT :=

T

t2N

^

F

t

isthe tail-eld gen-

erated by the sequence f(A

t

;B

t )g

t2N .

(iii) We have E

A

0

= E

B

0

= 0, where E

denotes the expectation with

respect to the law P

.

(iv) UnderthelawP

aninvarianceprinciplecanbeappliedtothesequence

f(X n

;Y n

)g

t2N

given by (35).

Below, wewillshowthatthedrivingsequencef(f(%~

t );g(%~

t ))g

t2N

forthe

assetpriceprocessdenedby(34)satisesparts(i),(ii)and(iv)oftheabove

assumptionwheneverourAssumptions4.4and5.5aresatised. Inthiscase

thedrivingsequence also satisesone ofthe \standardassumptions". This

allowsustoobtainadiusionapproximationfortheassetpriceprocess(34).

Theorem 6.4 If the driving sequence f(A

t

;B

t )g

t2N

satises Assumption

6.3, then the sequence of processes fZ n

g

n2N

= f(X n

;Y n

)g

n2N

converges

in distribution to the Gaussian martingale (X;Y) = V W. Here, W =

(W

1

;W

2

) is a 2-dimensional standard Brownian motion under the law P

and V isa deterministic volatility matrix.

Proof: Inorder to verify ourassertion, we proceedinseveral steps.

1. Dueto ourAssumption6.3, we knowthat

Law(Z n

;P

) w

!Law(V W;P

) (n!1):

2. We shall now use the assumption that the asymptotic behaviour of

the driving sequence f(A

t

;B

t )g

t2N

is the same under P

and under

theoriginal measure P inorder to show that the sequencesfX n

g

n2N

(30)

andfY g

n2N

satisfyaninvarianceprincipleP. Moreprecisely,we are

goingto verify that

Law (Z n

;P) w

!Law(V W;P

) (n!1): (39)

To this end, let f

n g

n2N

be a sequence of real numbers such that

n

" 1 and such that

n

= p

n ! 0 as n ! 1. For a given \time

horizon"T >0,andforeachn2N, weintroducethetwo-dimensional

process f e

Z n

t g

0tT

given by

e

Z n

t :=

(

1

p

n P

[nt]

i=

n (A

i

;B

i ) if

n

p

n

tT

0 otherwise.

We denotebyd

0

(;)and B

D

theSkorohood metric 5

and theBorel--

eldon thespace D

R

2[0;T],respectively. Notethat

d

0 (Z

n

; e

Z n

)

n

p

n

1

n n

X

i=0 jA

i j;

1

n n

X

i=0 jB

i j

!

: (40)

SinceP=P

onthetail-eldgenerated bythesequence f(A

t

;B

t )g

t2N

and because the environment f(A

t

;B

t )g

t2N

is ergodic under the law

P

;theseries

1

n

n

X

i=0 jA

i j and

1

n

n

X

i=0 jB

i j

areP-andP

-almostsurelyconvergentasn!1. Sincelim

n!1

n

p

n

=

0weobtainthat

lim

n!1 d

0 (Z

n

; e

Z n

)=0 P-a.s.and P

-a.s. (41)

Observe now that the event f e

Z n

2 Bg (B 2 B

D

) belongs to the -

algebra

^

F

n

. Since theenvironment has a nice asymptoticbehaviour

inthesenseof(31), there existsasequence fc

n g

n2N ,c

n

#0asn!1

such that

sup

B

P[

e

Z n

2B] P

[ e

Z n

2B]

c

n

: (42)

5

Forthedenitionofd0see, e.g.,Billingsley(1968),p.113.

(31)

3. Let us now denote by Q the law of the Gaussian martingale V W

underthemeasure P

and xaQ

-continuousset B 2B

D

. ByStep 1

above we know that

lim

n!1 P

[Z n

2B]=Q

[B]:

Thus, due to (41) and due to Theorem 4.2 in Billingsley(1968), we

havethat

lim

n!1 P

[ e

Z n

2B]=Q

[B]:

Using(42)we see that

lim

n!1 P[

e

Z n

2B]=Q

[B]:

Therefore,(41) and Theorem4.2inBillingsley(1968) implythat

Law (Z n

;P) w

!Law(V W;P

) (n!1): (43)

2

Remark 6.5 It is straightforward to extend the above theorem to the case

E

A

0 6=0,E

B

0

6=0. For notational convenience,however,weshallrestrict

our attentionto the caseE

A

0

=E

B

0

=0.

Let us assume that the non-stationary driving sequence f(A

t

;B

t )g

t2N

dened on (;F;P) is \good" in the sense of DuÆe and Protter (1992)

and satises our Assumption6.3. In this case it follows from Theorem 6.4

andProposition6.2thatthesequenceofprocessesfP n

g

n2N

denedby(37)

converges in distribution to the unique strong solution of the stochastic

dierentialequation

dP

t

=P

t dX

t +dY

t :

Armedwith these results we are now readyto show how the discrete-time

assetpriceprocessfp

t g

t2N

inanancialmarketmodelwithlog-linearexcess

demandfunctionscanindeedbeapproximatedinlawbyadiusionprocess.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

We test our model using a data base from a German bank’s tick-by-tick end-user order flow and respective quotes and find that financial customers exert massive market power

The intuition is simple: while e¤ective valuations are not equalized when there are more than two bidders, but (as we saw above) the e¤ective valuation of a weak (strong) bidder

Because our analysis uses the same variables as those of Henriques and Sadorsky (2008) but includes approximately three more years of data, the results of the VAR model without

Jako ropné společn různých společností s celo z různých geograficky odli Konkrétně to byly společ (USA), Chevron (USA (USA), BP (Spojené králo Shell (Spojené

Takaendesa (2006) specifies that if IRF of a variable to an exogenous variable’s shock is strictly increasing (or decreasing), one can conclude that such a shock

A decentralised long$run equilibrium model is proposed, based on the costly search activity which characterises the housing market, where the formal distinction between

In short, within a closed monetary economy of production, the logical sequence is: (1) banks grant credit to the industrial firms, enabling them to start the process

Метою статті є аналіз довгострокових трендів впливу іноземних фондових бірж на динаміку українського фондового ринку через