• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

Social Networks and Labour Market Outcomes: The Non-Monetary Benefits of Social Capital

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "Social Networks and Labour Market Outcomes: The Non-Monetary Benefits of Social Capital"

Copied!
16
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

source: https://doi.org/10.7892/boris.20104 | downloaded: 1.2.2022

Online publication 28 April 2006

© The Author 2006. Published by Oxford University Press. All rights reserved.

For permissions, please e-mail: journals.permissions@oxfordjournals.org

Social Networks and Labour Market Outcomes:

The Non-Monetary Benefits of Social Capital

Axel Franzen and Dominik Hangartner

We contrast Granovetter’s hypothesis (Granovetter, M. (1973). American Journal of Sociol- ogy, 78, 1360–1380; Granovetter, M. (1974). Getting a Job: A Study of Contacts and Careers. University of Chicago Press; Granovetter, M. (1995). Getting a Job: A Study of Con- tacts and Careers. University of Chicago Press) that social networks help individuals to find better-paid jobs with a new model, which predicts that networks are helpful with respect to non-pecuniary job characteristics but not concerning the monetary pay-offs. Following Montgomery (Montgomery, J. D. (1992) American Sociological Review, 57, 586–596), our model is a combination of classical job-search theory and the network hypothesis. First, concerning the monetary consequences, we test our hypotheses empirically by analysing the 2001 International Social Survey Programme on social relations and support systems.

We show that using social ties is a common job-search strategy in all countries. However, using social networks does not increase the monetary pay-off. Second, we use a sample of 8,000 Swiss university graduates who recently entered the labour market to show that informal job-search channels are beneficial with respect to important non-monetary job characteristics. Thus, graduates who received their jobs through social contacts tended to get jobs that are linked to their educational degree and offer better career perspectives.

Furthermore, using personal networks is related to lower search costs. Therefore, the results suggest overall that networks improve the non-pecuniary characteristics but not the monetary pay-offs.

Introduction

Since Granovetter’s (1974) Getting a Job, the question of how individuals find jobs and what effect social contacts have on the labour market has emerged to be one of the most interesting and controversial research questions in labour market research. Granovetter’s (1973, 1974) central ideas can be summarized as three hypotheses.

First, he proposed that many employees find their jobs through social contacts and not only through formal channels such as direct applications, employment agencies, or job advertisements. Second, according to Granovetter, the use of social networks allows job seek- ers to gather better information about the availability of jobs as well as job characteristics. This informational advantage should enable job seekers to select better

(2)

jobs. Hence a job found through the network should result in a better match, that is, higher wages and higher job satisfaction. Third, information about the labour market can best be generated through weak ties.

The advantage of weak ties as opposed to strong ties lies in the fact that the information in close-friendship circles is rather redundant and similar and that more new information is generated by networks whose members are dispersed and dissimilar.

Granovetter’s first proposition has been confirmed in many studies. Most empirical research shows that a sub- stantial proportion of individuals find their jobs via their contacts with friends, relatives, colleagues, or acquaint- ances. However, hypotheses two and three are contro- versial. Extensive reviews by Granovetter (1995) himself as well as others (Lin, 1999) suggest that most empirical studies were not able to confirm the wage bonus. This conclusion is nurtured by recent results presented by Mouw (2003) who concludes that contacts have no causal effect on labour market outcomes.

These results raise the question whether the social embeddedness of individuals has any consequences at all on labour market outcomes. We argue that they have consequences and will present theoretical arguments as well as empirical evidence, which support the notion that contacts matter. Jobs found through social contacts have non-monetary benefits, particularly a better match between employees’ education and the job require- ments. Furthermore, social networks reduce the search costs of finding jobs.

The remainder of the article is organized into four sections. Are Granovetter’s Hypotheses Refuted? starts with a brief review of existing findings, namely that most studies show that networks do not matter with respect to earnings. We then refer to job-search theory and to Montgomery (1992) in order to explain these non- findings. Moreover, we formulate an extension of his model and propose that job offers obtained through social networks are superior with respect to non-monetary characteristics. The ISSP 2001 describes our first data source and the results obtained. We analyse the ISSP 2001 data and show that jobs found through social con- tacts are not superior with respect to payment. In The Swiss Graduate Survey, we refer to another data source, a survey of university graduates who entered the labour market in 2001 to show that search strategies are related to the non-monetary job characteristics. In particular, we evaluate the outcomes of different job-search strate- gies with respect to earnings, educational adequacy, and search costs. Finally, the last section concludes and dis- cusses our findings and shortcomings.

Are Granovetter’s Hypotheses Refuted?

Granovetter’s (1974) original study is based on a sam- ple of 282 professionals, technical, and managerial workers1 living in Newton, Massachusetts, who were interviewed by him and partly surveyed by written questionnaires in 1969. Fifty-six per cent reported that they found their jobs through social contacts. This res- ult has been reconfirmed repeatedly in many studies in the United States (U.S. Department of Labor, 1975;

Corcoran et al., 1980; Marsden and Campbell, 1990;

Staiger, 1990) as well as in Great Britain, Japan, and The Netherlands (see Afterword in Granovetter, 1995).

Some differences between studies appear from the fact that sometimes only active job seekers are taken into account. However, there is evidence that social con- tacts also play an important part in those matches in which respondents received an offer from an employer without prior search. These respondents are often excluded from the analyses, a procedure that results in some biases as Granovetter convincingly argues. Stud- ies that also pay attention to the ‘non-seekers’ show that in about 80 per cent of these cases, a friend or rela- tive was involved. Hence, Granovetter’s proposal that networks are involved in about half of all job matches seems to be beyond doubt.

Granovetter’s second and third hypotheses, that jobs found through social contacts are better paid and more satisfying for employees and that weak ties are better than strong ties, are very controversial. Granovetter (1974) found that 54 per cent of those who found their jobs through contacts reported to be very satisfied with their work compared to 30 per cent who found their work through formal methods. Similarly, a larger pro- portion (ten percentage points) of the former is found in the higher income group. However, these findings were only replicated by a few studies (Corcoran et al., 1980;

Staiger, 1990; Wegener 1991; Coverdill, 1994; Jann, 2003), while many others could not detect a wage differ- ential (Lin et al., 1981; Bridges and Villemez, 1986;

Marsden and Hurlbert, 1988; Preisendörfer and Voss, 1988; Lin, 1999; Mau and Kopischke, 2001). Some stud- ies (De Graaf and Flap, 1988; Flap and Boxmann, 2001) even find a negative wage effect for social contacts. Fur- ther evidence against Granovetter’s hypothesis has also been presented recently by Lin (1999), and Mouw (2003) who concludes ‘I believe the weight of anecdotal evidence und intuition suggests that being “well connected” is an advantage in the labor market (...). At the moment,

(3)

intuition und anecdote aside, we have little empirical evidence that contacts matter’.

However, this conclusion holds only with respect to the direct effect, that is, for wages of those jobs that were offered with the help of the social network. The litera- ture on social resources (see Lin, 1999) also demon- strated that individuals in high job positions are found to have a large social network as well. Hence, the two findings that on the one hand high levels of social capital are correlated with high-income jobs, but that using the network on the other hand does not affect the wage level constitute a paradox. Mouw (2003) suspects that high job positions and size (and quality) of social networks are merely associated and that both depend on unob- served individual characteristics. Hence, he speaks of spurious social capital. However, an alternative interpre- tation is given by Montgomery (1992) who offers an interesting combination of economic job-search theory and Granovetter’s network hypothesis.

The difficulty of choosing a job is that job offers do not arrive simultaneously but sequentially in time (e. g.

Lippman and McCall, 1976). Thus, a job seeker is con- fronted with the following decision problem: either to accept an offer and stop searching or to reject the offer and continue searching. Since searching is costly (direct costs and opportunity costs), a worker who maximizes lifetime earnings will accept an offer of wage wR (or higher) if this offer exceeds his value of leisure and if he does not expect to find a higher wage offer that compen- sates for the continued search costs (see Mortensen, 1986). wR is called the reservation wage. Obviously, the higher an individual’s reservation wage the longer his or her search time until he or she finds a wage offer that matches the reservation wage. Moreover, the reservation wage depends (among other things) on the arrival rate of job offers. The more offers an individual expects the higher is his or her reservation wage and the higher the probability of finding a better-paid job. Following Mont- gomery (1992), one way to interpret the effect of social capital on wages is via the reservation wage. Individuals with larger networks (or alternatively a higher propor- tion of weak ties) may expect to receive more job offers, which increases the reservation wage. This indirect effect of social networks on earnings is in line with empirical findings reported by Lin (1999) and Mouw (2003).2

Networks not only can affect the reservation wage but can also have direct implication via the job-search strat- egies. This is Granovetter’s crucial hypothesis who does not consider the indirect effect via reservation wages.

Montgomery (1992) interprets Granovetter in the way that weak ties elicit more job offers than strong ties and

shows that the expected wage from weak-tie offers may be, counter-intuitively, lower than the wage expected from strong-tie offers. We extend Montgomery’s argu- ment by applying them to the difference between formal and informal search channels instead of the difference between weak and strong ties. First, we assume that most individuals use both formal (direct applications, answer- ing job advertisements, placing an advertisement, using a labour office) and informal (social contacts) search channels. Second, we assume that the wage distributions of both channels are identical. Thus, at least in principle, most available jobs can be found by various search chan- nels and are not exclusively restricted to one specific search method. Third, we assume that the offer rate of informal channels is higher than the one from formal search methods. This assumption basically follows Granovetter who asserts that information about new job opportunities is particularly efficiently (fast) transported through network ties as compared with formal search modes. In order to receive a formal offer, a job seeker first has to find a job advertisement and has to issue a formal application. This procedure takes more effort and is more costly than receiving the information from a network tie and applying with the help of the tie. Thus, we assume that almost every person receives one or more offers through the social network channel and only fewer offers through the formal channel. The problem now is that most of the time the number and quality of job offers are unobserved. Instead what researchers (and we) observe is only the accepted job and the search channel through which it was found. Thus, it could be the case that an individual who accepted an offer received through the formal channel passed on other offers from the social network. Hence, we infer that a seeker who accepted a formal offer had on average more offers to choose from and was therefore better able to select the best offer. Those who accepted an offer from the social network are on average likely to have had fewer offers to choose from, which results in a lower expected wage.

Wages are of course not the only characteristics of jobs. This notion is well known and accepted by many researchers. Particularly, we assume that in addition to wages, workers consider how well they fit into a job in terms of their interests and qualifications. One indicator concerning the quality of the match is how well a worker’s education and qualifications fit the require- ments of the job. Let us call this the educational ade- quacy (a) of a job. We propose that among the jobs offered that are above the reservation wage, workers choose the one that best meets their qualifications.

(4)

While we assume that the wage distributions of the formal and the informal offer distributions are identical, the job adequacy distributions of both search channels are not. Our fourth and new assumption is that the ade- quacy distribution of jobs offered through social net- works should be stochastically superior concerning the first and third moment of the distribution (see Figure 1).

More specifically, jobs from the formal offer distribution might be right skewed with respect to adequacy, because on average more jobs have low than high adequacy. How- ever, the offer distribution from the social network should be skewed to the left side, since networks offer more ade- quate than inadequate jobs. The rationale behind this proposition is that the network is rather well informed about the job seekers’ interest and qualifications and selects jobs with higher adequacy. Alternatively, it could be argued that networks are usually homogenous, which might also result in more adequate job offers. Of course, information about the educational requirements of jobs is usually also transferred via formal channels. However, it seems reasonable to assume that the information available through networks is more detailed and more specific than information received through formal channels.

With respect to wages, jobs that are offered through the network should not be superior to the formal channel- offer distribution. When members of a network transmit information about jobs to a seeker, they are probably not very well informed about the wage of the job nor do they know a worker’s reservation wage. Wages are often the result of negotiations between employer and employee. However, the network is usually very well informed about the qualification and education of a worker, and it filters jobs in such a way that it offers what it believes to be a good match. Hence, our expecta- tion is that jobs do not differ in wages depending on whether they were found with the help of the net- work or not.

However, they differ in educational adequacy in such a way that workers who found their job through the net- work should have jobs that match their qualification better. Note that our argument that jobs found through the network have higher adequacy but no wage advant- age implies that adequacy and wages are not positively correlated (ceteris paribus, particularly human capital).

There is often a trade-off between initial wages when entering the labour market and adequacy. However, this counter-intuitive argument is in line with human capital theory (Becker, 1964; see also Acemoglu and Pischke, 1999). Thus, jobs that offer general on-the-job training should have relative low initial payment and steeper earning profiles since employees have to compensate employers for their training. Hence, the degree of gen- eral training and job adequacy should be positively cor- related. As will be shown below, the first implication (the non-positive correlation between wages and ade- quacy) can be tested with our data. However, we have no data to test the second implication, that is, the positive correlation between adequacy and general training.

The ISSP 2001

The ISSP 2001 was conducted on social relations and support systems in 28 countries.3 Next to some socio- demographic information (earnings, education, and work experience), the surveys contain questions about the number of respondents’ friends and how they found their present jobs. Thus, participants were asked to report the number of close friends at the work place and in their neighbourhood, and other close friends. Fur- thermore, they were asked ‘Please indicate how you first found out about work at your present employer’. We grouped the answers into strong ties if participants named family members, other relatives, or close friends as contacts. Answers were grouped into the category weak ties if respondents said acquaintance. Table 1 dis- plays the percentages of strong- and weak-network con- tacts as well as the number of valid cases for the participating nations of the ISSP 2001. Overall, we can observe a substantial degree of variance. Proportions of network contacts are comparatively high in the southern European countries (Italy, Hungary, and Cyprus) as well in some developing countries such as the Philippines and Brazil. Relatively low proportions are observable in the Scandinavian countries. The United States, Japan, and Germany are in the middle. With few exceptions (most eastern European countries) and contrary to expectation, the proportion of strong-tie contacts is Figure 1 Job offer distributions from networks and formal

channels. Note: a refers to job adequacy.

(5)

larger than that of weak-tie contacts. However, this might be partly due to our coding of other relatives into the strong-tie category. Nonetheless, the descriptive impression presented in Table 1 confirms Granovetter’s notion that on average a substantial amount of jobs are found through network contacts.

Next we analyse whether network size and job place- ment via social contacts are related to wages. Such analy- ses are presented in Table 2. The first model is a standard Mincer income OLS-regression model controlling for country-specific differences by country dummies. In order to compare the hourly incomes, we transformed the national wages into purchasing power parity (PPP) units. Since the transition from the original currencies into PPP units can be done much more reliably for OECD members, we restrict our analysis to these. Fur- thermore, some countries (e.g. Austria, Norway) have missing data with respect to some central variables (income, education, or network indicators).

We had to drop both countries from our analysis so that we end up with 15 remaining nations. The esti- mated coefficient for education in model 1 of Table 2 tells us that every additional year in education is rewarded on average by 7.9 per cent ((exp(0.076)–1) × 100) increase in hourly wages. Also, the other results, the pos- itive but concave effect for work experience, confirm the well-known results of the standard income regressions.

Next, in model 2, we introduce the network indicators and two dummy variables if respondents found their jobs through strong or weak ties as compared with formal methods (reference group). First, the more friends respondents have at work and the more other friends they report to have, the higher their hourly wage.

Thus, these results are in line with the hypothesis of Montgomery (1992) that those with more contacts on average expect more job offers, which raises their reserva- tion wage and finally also their realized wage. Counter- intuitive is the negative effect of the number of friends in Table 1 Job placement via social networks

NA, not available.

Data source: ISSP 2001, own calculations.

Strong ties (%) Weak ties (%) All (%) N

Finland 16.47 9.30 25.77 1269

Austria 26.35 NA 26.35 850

Denmark 16.68 11.38 28.06 1151

Norway 17.36 10.98 28.34 1457

Australia 20.33 10.58 30.91 1087

Great Britain 22.69 8.37 31.06 824

New Zealand 20.65 10.43 31.08 930

Northern Ireland 22.34 10.15 32.49 1025

Germany 21.17 12.68 33.85 1167

Canada 24.29 11.99 36.28 984

France 26.64 10.71 37.35 1186

Switzerland 21.68 17.42 39.10 752

Japan 25.95 15.34 41.29 1102

Poland 19.21 24.90 44.11 1036

USA 30.83 13.46 44.29 1077

Latvia 21.06 25.00 46.06 940

Slovenia 31.66 14.99 46.65 894

Czech Republic 22.69 24.38 47.07 1124

Spain 33.77 14.04 47.81 1140

Israel 37.13 11.88 49.01 1061

Russia 27.71 22.62 50.33 1061

Italy 32.51 18.53 51.04 966

Hungary 22.94 29.94 52.88 1286

Cyprus 44.27 17.51 61.78 811

Brazil 55.21 12.36 67.57 1699

Chile 44.50 23.71 68.21 1164

Philippines 69.39 13.46 82.85 1039

(6)

the neighbourhood. However, more wealthy people might live further apart from each other in suburban neighbourhoods, which may reduce their neighbourhood contacts. The data also confirm the second part of Mont- gomery’s (1992) argument, namely that respondents who accepted a job offered via a strong tie have on average a lower wage. This negative effect can also be observed for weak ties confirming our extension of Montgomery’s (1992) model. Thus, respondents who accepted an offer through the network (weak or strong) either had a lower search time or did not receive as many formal job offers.

Both causes lead to a lower number of total job offers, which has the consequence of reducing the realized wage.

Finally, model 3 in Table 2 is a multilevel model in which the country dummies are replaced by country-specific covariates that should affect wages, such as GDP per cap- ita, GDP growth, and the labour force participation of women (LFB). All three coefficients are positive and sta- tistically significantly related to wages. We also tested two cross-level effects between GDP growth and placements via strong and weak ties. Both interaction effects are not significantly related to wages. Overall, the ISSP 2001 data

confirm former empirical findings (Mouw, 2003) that job placement through social contacts is not positively associ- ated with higher wages. Furthermore, our analysis of the data confirms a hypothesis by Montgomery (1992) that the size of the social network is positively related to wages.

The Swiss Graduate Survey

Our second data source is a survey of all Swiss university graduates, which has been conducted biannually by the Swiss statistical office since 1977. This data is collected from university graduates one year after graduation via written questionnaires and is concerned with respondents’

entrance (first job) into the labour market. We analyse the newest available data of respondents who graduated in 2000.4 In this year, 12,447 graduates left the universities.

They were contacted about 12 months later via a written questionnaire. A total of 8,151 graduates returned the ques- tionnaire, constituting a response rate of 65 per cent.5

The data have some advantages that make them par- ticularly suitable for an analysis of our propositions.

Table 2 Extended Mincer-type wage regressions

P-values in parentheses, computed with Huber–White-corrected standard errors.

*Significant at 0.05; **significant at 0.01.

~Under control of country dummies.

Models 1 and 2 are estimated by ordinary least squares, model 3 is estimated by maximum likelihood. In all three models, the following OECD countries are included: Australia, Canada, Czech Republic, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Great Britain, Hungary, Japan, New Zealand, Poland, Spain, Switzerland, and the United States.

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Education 0.076** (0.000) 0.075** (0.000) 0.075** (0.000)

Experience 0.025** (0.000) 0.025** (0.000) 0.025** (0.000)

(Experience)2/100 −0.034** (0.000) −0.034** (0.000) −0.034** (0.000)

Sex (man = 1) 0.230** (0.000) 0.229** (0.000) 0.229** (0.000)

Marriage 0.127** (0.000) 0.129** (0.000) 0.129** (0.006)

Friends (other) 0.003** (0.001) 0.003* (0.022)

Friends (work) 0.012** (0.000) 0.012** (0.005)

Friends (neighbourhood) −0.007** (0.002) −0.007* (0.034)

Job (strong) −0.036* (0.028) −0.036* (0.017)

Job (weak) −0.036* (0.049) −0.037 (0.058)

GDP growth 95–01 0.162* (0.030)

GDP p.c. 0.052** (0.010)

LFP rate 0.051** (0.005)

Constant 1.178** (0.000) 1.179** (0.000) 0.846** (0.000)

Observations 7749 7749 7749

Adjusted R2 0.604 0.606

R2 level 1 0.311

R2 level 2 ~ ~ 0.078

Countries 15 15 15

(7)

Since all respondents are labour market entrances, they are at the start of their career, and the sample is homogeneous with respect to their working biography. Many other investigations into the effects of network contacts on job characteristics, such as our own of the ISSP, use cross- sectional data from the entire working population and have to control for career-specific effects, such as the last position before the present job was entered, the segment of the labour market, the level of on-the-job training, whether respondents changed employer, and so forth.

Such heterogeneity of individual working biographies makes it more difficult to isolate the effect of network contacts on the job in question. Also, Granovetter (1995:

154) discusses that past positions may have been found by network contacts but not necessarily the present one.

However, since the past position influences the charac- teristics of the present job, networks can have an indirect effect on present positions. This indirect effect of net- works is usually not taken into account so that the net- work effect is underestimated.

Another advantage of our data is that the survey took place 12 months or less (the median is 3 months) after respondents entered the labour market. Hence, biases due to memory problems that are usually present in ret- rospective questioning should be less of a problem in this data. Information about job searching can be inac- curate in representative surveys that contain a cross- section of the entire labour force for those respondents who have not experienced a job shift for a longer time period.

A further difficulty of analysing the effects of social capital is the dependence of the labour market on eco- nomic cycles. Granovetter (1995) supposes that strong ties are more important during economic recessions than weak ties because strong ties feel more obliged to help their friends or relatives in difficult times. Another possibility mentioned in Granovetter (1995) is that employers have more bargaining power during economic recessions than workers and may determine the job match weakening the influence of networks. Theories of labour market segmentation suggest that ‘social closure’

is stronger during recessive cycles, which would increase the importance of personal contacts (Preisendörfer and Voss, 1988). Some evidence of the dependence between the economic situation and the shape of the labour mar- ket was presented by Osberg (1993) with Canadian data.

He found that more unemployed used social networks during times of higher unemployment. However, at the same time, the proportion who found a job through the network decreased, possibly because a larger proportion of the network was also unemployed.

The results we present here concern the sample that entered the labour market in the second half of 2000 (which was a prosperous economic year in Switzerland).

However, we also analysed the interviews from 1995, 1997, and 1999 of graduates entering the labour market during more recessive periods. We did not find substantial differ- ences, which suggests that our results do not seem to depend on the specific economic situation in 2000.

The survey contains information on respondents’

search strategies, search costs, labour market outcome, and educational adequacy. Each of these variables is measured by several indicators. The labour market out- come is measured by wages and additionally by the occu- pational position (with managing responsibilities as opposed to without). Search costs are measured by the search time, the number of job applications, and the number of job interviews, and by a subjective measure of how difficult respondents perceived the job search to have been. Educational adequacy is measured by four indicators, most importantly by the specificity of the degree that the employer required. Additionally, the questionnaire contains a few subjective measures, that is, whether respondents believe that the job is a long-term engagement, which offers career perspectives, the extent to which respondents can use their ability, how they per- ceive the possibility to exert influence, and how well the wages correspond to their qualifications. Hence, the data allow for an analysis of the effects of search strategies on the labour market outcome, the search costs, and the non-monetary job qualities.

For the analysis of wages, we restrict the analysis to those graduates who received their first university degree in 2000 and had entered the labour market by the time of the interview.6 The questionnaire distinguishes 12 dif- ferent job-search strategies: for example, graduates may have applied directly, asked different employment agencies (official employment office or one from the university), responded to job advertisements in the media, or placed an advertisement themselves. Graduates may also have contacted friends, relatives, or colleagues or have looked for jobs by asking professors and former employers they know personally.

In 2001, 25.2 per cent of the graduates reported that they received a job offer without prior search. The most common job-search strategy among the graduates in Switzerland is direct application (50.2 per cent) followed by formal search strategies (46.9 per cent) and the help of personal networks (40.5 per cent).7 More important than the question which strategies were employed is the question which ones were successful. Figure 2 shows that about a quarter of the graduates found a job through

(8)

each of the search channels, that is, formal, informal, and direct applications. Moreover, these proportions remain fairly constant over time. Comparing 1995 with 1999, the importance of social contacts decreased a little.

However, in 2001, the search via social networks was the decisive route into the labour market for 19.6 per cent of the graduates. Calculating the success ratio by dividing the number of individuals who found a job by the number who used a given strategy reveals no substantial differences (direct application 44.8 per cent, formal search 49.5 per cent, and social contacts 45.3 per cent).

Summarizing the first part of our descriptive analysis again confirms Granovetter’s (1974, 1995) first hypothe- sis. A substantial proportion of individuals find their jobs due to the help of their personal networks. This res- ult replicates that of studies conducted in the United States (Young, 1974; Sagen et al., 1999).

The interesting question is whether job matches through social networks are beneficial as compared with other strategies. Table 3 shows the results of an OLS regression of the logarithm of the hourly wages. Presented are the effects of different search strategies controlling for other mostly socio-demographic influences such as respond- ents’ age, sex, or nationality. The analysis also controls for the effects of different universities and subjects of study.

However, we do not show the latter effects to keep the table readable. As is usual, wages for subjects such as

business administration or economics are higher than the ones from social sciences, history, or language. Fur- thermore, the highest wages are observed among gradu- ates from universities in the German-speaking part as compared with the French and Italian part, which depends on the shape of the regional labour markets and has little to do with the quality of the universities.8

First of all, the results reveal that searching is rewarded. Respondents who searched for a job receive a 4 per cent wage bonus as compared with those who accepted an offer by an employer without prior search (see Table 3, model 1). However, wages do not increase with increasing search time. This finding is not consist- ent with job-search theory, which assumes that individ- uals with a higher reservation wage should search longer and realize a higher wage. However, job-search theory makes the (highly unrealistic) assumption that job searchers know the offer distribution (see Mortensen, 1986). The zero effect could be the result of the mixture of two types of individuals in our sample: those who search and find the better-paid jobs and those whose reservation wage is higher than what the market is will- ing to offer and who, therefore, have difficulties finding a job that meets their reservation wage. More important with respect to our hypothesis is the negative effect on wages if the job was found with the help of social net- works. Jobs that were found through social contacts pay Figure 2 Proportion of successful search strategies, 1995–2001.

Notice: The question wording was: „Which of the strategies you used was decisive in finding the job?“.

21.1 22.3 24.1 24.9

25.3 26.0 20.2 19.6

26.5 25.2

22.9 24.1

21.5 20.6 28.3 27.0

5.6 5.9 4.5 4.4

0%

20%

40%

60%

80%

100%

1995 1997 1999 2001

formal search strategies search via social contacts direct application received offer from employer other

(9)

on average 5 per cent less as compared with jobs found through formal search channels. Thus, also our results show that searching via social contacts has no monetary advantage (Mouw, 2003) and, moreover, might even have negative effects (see De Graaf and Flap, 1988; Flap and Boxmann, 2001).9

Also, the number of different strategies people use to find a job does not affect wages. This finding is also inconsistent with job-search theory. A more intensive search should increase the number of job offers, which in turn should increase the chance of finding a better- paid job. However, this again might be due to the mix- ture of two groups of individuals, namely, those who find well-paid jobs by searching and those whose chances are worse to begin with and who are therefore forced to use all channels.

In addition to the effects of search strategies, model 1 also controls for educational adequacy and certain socio-demographic effects. First, as hypothesized, job adequacy is negatively correlated with wages. Hence,

jobs for which the employer demands a specific degree as compared with more general university degrees are on average paid 5 per cent less. The results also show that women have a 4 per cent wage disadvantage in the labour market.10 Children increase the wage by 7 per cent, which can be explained with social benefit pay- ments employers have to make. A small positive effect of 2 per cent can also be observed for the graduates’ age and a 3 per cent income advantage for work experience acquired during university enrolment. The education of a respondent’s father or mother does not affect a gradu- ate’s wage level at labour market entrance. Hourly wages are also not affected if respondents work only part-time as compared with full-time.

In addition to wages, we also analysed the occupa- tional position at which graduates entered the labour market. The questionnaire contains a dichotomous variable that indicates whether individuals received a position with or without management responsibilities. Assuming that management positions have more occupational Table 3 The influence of social networks on hourly wages, occupational position, and educational adequacy

*Significant at the 5% level; **significant at the 1% level.

Depicted in model 1 are the unstandardized coefficients from OLS regression. Numbers in parenthesis denote the standard errors of the estimates.

Model 1 is an OLS regression with the logarithm of hourly wages as the dependent variable. The model controls for university dummies and for subject dum- mies, which are not displayed due to place restrictions. The university dummies consist of Basel, Berne, Fribourg, Geneva, Lausanne, Neuchâtel, St. Gallen, Ticino, ETH Zurich, EPF Lausanne with the University of Zurich as the reference. Subjects are distinguished into Theology, Language, History, Social Sciences, Law, Natural Science, Medicine, and technical subjects. Economics is used as the reference category.

Model 2 is a logistic regression. The dependent variable is coded as 1, if graduates received a job with management responsibilities, and 0 otherwise.

Model 3 is an ordered-probit model. The dependent variable is the educational adequacy coded as 1 if employer did not require any university degree, 2 with only a general university degree, 3 if a university degree from similar subjects were also accepted, and 4 if the employer required a specific degree.

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3

Income regression Managing position Educational adequacy

Constant 3.30** (0.07) −5.91** (0.78) —

Search (0 = no, 1 = yes) 0.04** (0.02) −0.14 (0.18) 0.16** (0.07)

Duration of search (in months) −0.001 (0.002) −0.01 (0.02) 0.004 (0.01) Social network contact (0 = no, 1 = yes) −0.05** (0.01) −0.14 (0.15) 0.20** (0.06) Direct application (0 = no, 1 = yes) −0.01 (0.01) −0.40** (0.15) 0.14** (0.05) Number of different search strategies

(if searched)

−0.003 (0.004) −0.04 (0.04) −0.07** (0.02) Adequacy (0 = no specific degree,

1 = specific degree)

−0.05** (0.01) — —

Gender (0 = male, 1 = female) −0.04** (0.01) −0.14 (0.12) 0.03 (0.04)

Age (in years) 0.02** (0.002) 0.16** (0.02) −0.01 (0.01)

Nationality (0 = Swiss, 1 = non-Swiss) −0.001 (0.02) 0.32 (0.18) 0.05 (0.07) Work experience (0 = no, 1 = yes) 0.03** (0.01) 0.18 (0.11) 0.13** (0.05) Children (0 = none, 1 = one or more) 0.07** (0.02) −0.11 (0.24) −0.02 (0.10) Education of father (in years) −0.001 (0.001) 0.001 (0.02) 0.01 (0.01) Education of mother (in years) −0.003 (0.002) −0.001 (0.02) −0.03** (0.01) Part-time employed (0 = no, 1 = yes) 0.02 (0.01) −0.53** (0.13) 0.38** (0l.05)

N 3120 3556 3501

Adjusted R2/pseudo R2 0.15 0.07 0.10

(10)

prestige, it is expected that offers from the network should lead to management positions more often. Since we deal with a dichotomous variable, model 2 in Table 3 shows the logistic-regression coefficients. However, only direct applications lead to jobs that start in a managing position significantly less often. Apart from this, two further significant effects emerge from the model: man- aging positions are more often obtained by older gradu- ates and less often open for part-time employment.

Thus, model 2 in Table 3 echoes the results obtained for the wages regression.

Finally, in model 3 in Table 3, we attend to the ques- tion whether network contacts increase the probability of receiving a job with higher educational adequacy.

Graduates were asked whether their current employer required no university degree at all, only a general degree, one from a related subject, or a specific university degree.

We assume that jobs that do not require a university degree or only an unspecific one are less adequate for graduates and less preferred by them. Since the depend- ent variable has four categories that can be ordered, model 3 in Table 3 presents the results of an ordered- probit model. The results suggest that search strategies matter. Respondents who searched (coefficient of 0.16), received a job through social networks (coefficient of 0.20), or applied directly (coefficient of 0.14) report to have jobs that more often required an adequate degree as compared with respondents who found jobs through formal search channels.11 This result confirms our hypothesis that friends, relatives, and colleagues seem to pay attention to a graduate’s educational qualifications when informing about job opportunities.

The adequacy of jobs that were found through social networks is also better in the respondents’ own percep- tion. The participants of the survey were asked whether they view their current job as a temporary means to earn money or as a long-term career investment, as well as how well they are able to exert influence and apply their abilities on the job. Clearly, jobs that are more adequate to individuals’ interest and education should be viewed more often as long-term investments and should offer better opportunities for personal influence and ability.

The results of the analysis are displayed in Table 4. The logistic regression (model 1 in Table 4) shows that grad- uates who found their job through the network (as well as direct applicants) have a higher chance of finding jobs with a long-term career perspective (the odds increase by exp(0.43) = 1.54). Models 2 and 3 contain the results of exerting influence and using their abilities at the work place. In both models, the non-standardized OLS-regression coefficients are significantly positive (0.17 and 0.07 on a

0.05 and 0.10 significance level), indicating that jobs found via the network are perceived to offer more opportunities for personal influence and ability.12

Network jobs, however, are negatively associated with the perceived adequacy of payment (model 4 in Table 4).

Thus, this finding corresponds rather well to the com- paratively lower hourly wages reported in Table 3. Also, noteworthy are the positive effects of the work experi- ence graduates acquired during their study. Graduates who worked while still enrolled at the university have a better chance of finding a job that is related to their sub- ject of study. Obviously, this work experience also increases graduates’ knowledge of where to find ade- quate jobs.

Finally, we will take a look at the search costs. If Granovetter’s (1974, 1995) and our models are correct, graduates who use networks for job searching should receive job offers more often and sooner. Thus, the search time should be reduced for all those who use their networks. This hypothesis is supported by our analysis of the search time. We analysed the search time until respondents found a job by event-history analysis (more particularly we use a Weibull model), which takes right- censored cases (respondents who were still looking for a job at the time of the interview) into account. Model 1 in Table 5 shows the effects on the hazard rate of leaving the stage of search and entering employment. Thus, graduates using the network have an increased hazard rate of 17 per cent ((exp(0.16)–1) × 100) as opposed to those who use formal job-search strategies. Moreover, we analysed two more indicators of the search costs, namely, the number of applications and the number of job interviews individuals went through before accept- ing a job. Since these variables are count data, we analyse them using negative-binomial models (see Cameron and Trivedi, 1998).13 The estimation results suggest that graduates who used the network wrote 11 per cent fewer applications and went through 11 per cent fewer job interviews. Thus, models 2 and 3 confirm the results we obtained through our analysis of the search time.

Our fourth model (in Table 5) contains the analysis of respondents’ perception whether they encountered diffi- culty during the job search. This indicator also reflects the results we already obtained from models 1 through 3 of Table 5. Respondents who used the network have a lower chance (the odds are reduced by 0.66) to report difficulties. Models 1 through 4 in Table 5 also control for a number of socio-demographic effects that are pos- sibly associated with the search costs. A few systematic and crucial results emerge from the control variables. Thus, women and academics who are looking for part-time

(11)

employment seem to encounter higher search costs. Obvi- ously, the number of search strategies respondents used increases the number of applications and job interviews.

Summary and Discussion

This article tries to demonstrate that social networks matter for finding a job. First, we test some implications of Granovetter’s (1974, 1995) and Montgomery’s (1992) hypotheses by analysing the ISSP 2001 data. Three basic findings emerge from this analysis. First, a substantial proportion of individuals report that they found their job through network contacts. Second, individuals with a larger number of friends (particularly friends at the work place) indeed report to have a higher income. The effect can be explained by Montgomery’s (1992) assumption that a larger network increases respondents’

reservation wage and consequentially their income.

Third, however, jobs that are directly found with the help of a network tie are not better paid. This result,

which may at first seem counter-intuitive, might stem from the fact that those who accepted an offer through network contacts could have overall received less offers or, alternatively, had a shorter search time, which conse- quentially results in a lower realized wage.

Furthermore, we extended Montgomery’s (1992) model by assuming that the distribution of job offers from networks is superior to the distribution of job offers due to formal channels with respect to educational adequacy. We tested our hypotheses by using the Swiss Graduate Survey. Overall, four results emerge from this analysis: First, also in this survey, a substantial propor- tion of individuals report that they found their first job by network contacts. Second, we analysed the hourly wages and were not able to discover a wage bonus for individuals who had accepted an offer through the net- work. More specifically, controlling for the search time those who accepted an offer through the network had even a monetary disadvantage. Thus, our analysis con- firms other findings (De Graaf and Flap, 1988; Flap and Boxmann, 2001).

Table 4 Social networks and subjective indicators of job adequacy

†Significant at the 10% level; *significant at the 5% level; **significant at the 1% level.

Numbers in parenthesis denote the standard errors. The regressions contain but do not show dummies for universities and dummies for the subject of study.

Model 1 is a logistic regression. The dependent variable is coded with 1 = long-term employment intention with possibility of upward mobility and 0 = short- term employment with no upward mobility.

Model 2 is an OLS regression. The dependent variable measures respondents’ rating of the adequacy of job concerning the possibility of using their knowledge and ability.

Model 3 is an OLS regression. The dependent variable is the perceived adequacy concerning the possibility of having an impact on the job.

Model 4 is an OLS regression; the dependent variable contains the rating of the perceived adequacy of payment. Same results were obtained for models 2 through 4 if an ordered-probit was applied instead of an OLS regression.

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4

Career investment Apply ability Exert influence Perceived payment

Constant 3.04** (0.97) 2.46** (0.21) 2.72** (0.22) 2.36** (0.26)

Search (0 = no, 1 = yes) 0.33 (0.22) 0.03 (0.05) −0.04 (0.05) 0.18** (0.06) Search duration (in months) −0.01** (0.003) −0.001 (0.001) 0.00 (0.001) −0.01 (0.01) Social contacts (0 = no, 1 = yes) 0.43** (0.17) 0.17** (0.04) 0.07† (0.04) −0.16** (0.05) Direct application (0 = no, 1 = yes) 0.57** (0.19) 0.10** (0.04) −0.06 (0.04) −0.02 (0.04) Number of search strategies −0.19** (0.04) −0.05** (0.01) −0.04** (0.01) −0.01 (0.01) Gender (0 = male, 1 = female) 0.04 (0.14) −0.01 (0.03) −0.02 (0.03) 0.04 (0.04)

Age (in years) −0.004 (0.03) −0.001 (0.01) −0.02* (0.01) −0.01 (0.01)

Nationality (0 = Swiss, non-Swiss = 1) 0.59* (0.29) 0.04 (0.05) −0.07 (0.05) 0.01 (0.06) Work experience (0 = no, 1 = yes) 0.18 (0.15) 0.11** (0.03) 0.10** (0.03) 0.09* (0.04) Children (0 = no, 1 = yes) 0.27 (0.31) 0.05 (0.06) 0.03 (0.07) 0.25** (0.08) Education of father (in years) 0.01 (0.02) 0.00 (0.00) 0.00 (0.01) 0.00 (0.01) Education of mother (in years) −0.04 (0.03) 0.00 (0.01) −0.01 (0.01) 0.00 (0.01) Part-time employed (0 = no, 1 = yes) −0.54** (0.14) 0.07* (0.03) 0.03 (0.03) −0.24** (0.04)

N 3513 3557 3522 3527

Pseudo R2/adjusted R2 0.08 0.05 0.03 0.05

(12)

Third, our results suggest that jobs found with the help of friends, colleagues, or relatives have a higher educational adequacy. Thus, employers more often require a specific university degree for jobs that are found by network contacts. Moreover, respondents more often view jobs found over the network as long- term engagements compatible with their career plans versus short-term employment that has little or no rela- tion to career plans. The notion that educational job adequacy is higher is also supported by respondents’

evaluation of job characteristics. Thus, network jobs are more often perceived as offering the opportunity to exert influence and apply ability.

Fourth, the analyses show that searching via the net- work saves search costs. Hence, respondents who found their job through the network did so faster, applied less often, and went through a lower number of job inter- views. Therefore, searching via the network has some monetary benefits regarding individual’s lifetime earn- ings. However, these benefits are small (on average search time is about two weeks shorter) given an indi- vidual’s lifetime of work.

As discussed above, labour market outcomes may depend on the business cycle. Some research suggests that networks become more important during reces- sions since the market is more closed towards new

entrances. Other results suggest that the influence of net- works should decrease, since during recessions a larger proportion of an individual’s network should be unem- ployed as well. In order to exclude the possibility that our results depend on the good health of the economy in 2000, we also analysed the data of graduates who entered the job market during recessive times in 1995, 1997, and 1999. However, we obtained almost identical results from the other three data sets as well.

To summarize, the acceptance of a job offer through the network seems to have non-monetary advantages for labour market entrances. The help of the network increases the chance of an appropriate match concern- ing respondents’ education and the type of work. At the same time, our results replicate that finding a job through the network has no monetary benefit. Thus, the results support Montgomery’s (1992) model as well as our extension of it that the distribution of job offers from the network is stochastically dominant with respect to educational adequacy. Our results also suggest that graduates face a trade-off between adequacy and wages.

Higher adequacy is associated with lower entrance wages. Employers who look for specific university degrees seem to provide general on-the-job training more often, which is associated with a steeper wage–age profile.

Table 5 Search strategies and the cost of job search

†Significant at the 10% level; *significant at the 5% level; **significant at the 1% level.

Numbers in brackets denote the standard errors. The regressions contain but do not show dummies for universities and dummies for the subject of study.

Model 1 is a Weibull model of the hazard rate to enter employment.

Models 2 and 3 are negative-binomial models with the number of applications and the number of job interviews as dependent variables.

Model 4 is a logistic regression analysis, the dependent variable indicating whether respondents report difficulties in finding a job.

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4

Duration of search

Number of applications

Number of job interviews

Difficulties in job search

Constant 0.45 (0.28) 0.66** (0.24) 0.37 (0.26) −4.29** (0.84)

Social contacts (0/1) 0.16** (0.04) −0.11** (0.04) −0.11** (0.05) −0.42** (0.14) Direct application (0/1) 0.02 (0.04) 0.70** (0.04) 0.44** (0.04) 0.03 (0.15) Number of strategies −0.18** (0.01) 0.53** (0.01) 0.41** (0.01) 0.82** (0.04)

Gender (0/1) 0.02 (0.04) 0.10** (0.04) −0.18** (0.04) 0.38** (0.13)

Age (in years) −0.01 (0.01) 0.00 (0.01) −0.01 (0.01) −0.01 (0.03)

Nationality (0/1) −0.06 (0.06) 0.02 (0.06) 0.01 (0.06) 0.21 (0.20)

Work experience (0/1) 0.03 (0.04) −0.07* (0.04) −0.13** (0.04) −0.25 (0.14)

Children (0/1) −0.07 (0.07) 0.05 (0.07) −0.20** (0.08) 0.33 (0.23)

Education of father 0.001 (0.01) −0.00 (0.01) 0.01 (0.01) 0.02 (0.02)

Education of mother 0.0021 (0.01) −0.02* (0.01) −0.01 (0.01) −0.06* (0.03) Part-time employed (0/1) −0.27** (0.04) −0.12** (0.04) −0.02** (0.04) 0.26* (0.13)

N 3511 3819 3834 3801

Chi-square/pseudo R2 433.81 0.09 0.09 0.26

(13)

Both of our data sources have particular advantages but also some disadvantages. Thus, our analysis of the Graduate Survey does not allow for a test of the weak-tie versus strong-tie hypothesis. The Graduate Survey has no information concerning what type of contacts are best with respect to finding adequate jobs. Furthermore, it contains no information on the size or other features of individuals’ networks. We can also not exclude the pos- sibility that individuals using the network for their job search have some unobserved characteristics that deter- mine the outcome of the search instead of the used search strategy. However, the data at hand do not support this possibility. Thus, none of the graduates reported to have only used a single strategy, and estimating one’s chance to use the network was only significantly related to the number of strategies used, as well as to gender (men use networks more often than women). However, overall the McFadden R2 of a probit model was too low (0.04) to corroborate the obtained estimate into a treat- ment-effect model (Greene, 2000: 933). Thus, clarification of the problem of possible unobserved heterogeneity as well as the question to which extent the results can be generalized to a larger proportion of the labour market has to be left to further research. However, we believe that the analyses presented here draw attention to the non- monetary benefit of social networks on the labour market.

Notes

1. Most of the people interviewed did have a university degree.

2. Note that Mouw (2003) calls this ‘spurious social capital’. This term implies that it cannot be inter- preted causally. However, the argument via the res- ervation wage implies a causal explanation. It does not need to be either the one or the other but may well be a mixture of a spurious relation and a causal effect via wage expectations. Networks could also increase the reservation wage by increasing the value of leisure.

3. The data are available from the Swiss Information and Data Archive Services for the Social Sciences (SIDOS) in Neuchâtel (http://www.sidos.ch).

4. Switzerland has 12 universities, 6 in the German- speaking part (Universities of Basel, Berne, St. Gallen, Lucerne, Zurich, and the Swiss Federal Institute of Technology in Zurich), 5 in the French-speaking part (Universities of Fribourg, Geneva, Lausanne, Neuchâtel, and the Swiss Federal Institute of Tech- nology in Lausanne), and 1 in the Italian-speaking part (University of Ticino).

5. The data are available from the Swiss Statistical Office in Neuchâtel, Switzerland (http://

www.admin.bfs.ch).

6. This excludes graduates who received a second degree (e.g. a dissertation) and those 4.1 per cent graduates who were still looking for a job at the time of the interviews in Spring 2001.

7. These proportions correspond closely to those reported by Young (1974), which are based on a sur- vey of 750,000 university graduates in the United States. For a similar result concerning direct applica- tion, see also Ports (1993).

8. The detailed results of universities and subjects’

hourly wages can be obtained from the authors.

9. Note that the estimated effect of the use of social networks on wage might be biased if those who found their jobs via social networks are different in some characteristics not controlled for in the regres- sion equation from individuals who did not use social contacts. One possible procedure to correct for this possible bias is the estimation of a switching regression model (Wooldridge, 2002). However, in our case, the estimation of the selection equation (probit model) did not show any fundamental dif- ferences between the two groups. The detailed results can be obtained from the authors.

10. If women have a lower labour market participation than men, the analysis needs a correction (Heckit corrections; Heckman, 1979) to obtain an unbiased estimator. However, female participation in our sample is about 90 per cent, so that such a correction is of lesser concern here.

11. The calculation of the exact change in probabilities would require further transformations of the coeffi- cient, which we do not report here.

12. The extent to which respondents believe that they can apply their ability or exert influence on the job was measured on a four-point-rating scale varying from very much to not at all. Our OLS regression assumes interval measurement. However, the results remain robust even if we apply ordered-probit mod- els to those variables as well.

13. Usually count data require the analysis via Poisson regressions. In our case, the so-called assumption of equidispersion is not fulfilled so that we apply the negative-binomial model. The assumption of equid- ispersion is fulfilled if a = Var(y|x)/E(y|x) does not significantly deviate from 1. In model 2 a = 1.5 and in model 3 a = 1.2 indicating over-dispersion.

However, the estimation results do not differ sub- stantially between the Poisson model and the negative-binomial model used here.

(14)

Acknowledgements

We are indebted to Norman Braun, Cedric El-Idrissi, Josef Hartmann, and Peter Preisendörfer for their help- ful comments on an earlier version.

References

Acemoglu, D. and Pischke, J. S. (1999). The Structure of Wages and Investment in General Training. Journal of Political Economy, 107, 539–572.

Becker, G. S. (1964). Human Capital. A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to Educa- tion. New York: Columbia University Press.

Bridges, W. P. and Villemez, W. J. (1986). Informal Hiring and Income in the Labor Market. American Sociological Review, 51, 574–582.

Cameron, C. A. and Trivedi, P. K. (1998). Regression Analysis of Count Data. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.

Corcoran, M., Datcher, L. and Duncan, G. (1980). Infor- mation and Influence Networks in Labor Markets.

In Duncan, G. J. and Morgan, J. N. (Eds), Five Thou- sand American Families: Patterns of Economic Progress. Ann Arbor, MI: Institute for Social Research, pp. 1–37.

Coverdill, J. (1994). Personal Contacts and Post-Hire Job Outcomes. Manuscript, Department of Sociology, University of Georgia.

De Graaf, N. and Flap, H. (1988). With a Little Help from My Friends: Social Resources as an Explana- tion of Occupational Status and Income in West Germany, The Netherlands, and the United States.

Social Forces, 67, 452–472.

Flap, H. and Boxmann, E. (2001). Getting Started: The Influence of Social Capital on the Start of the Occupational Career. In Lin, N., Cook, K. S. and Burt, R. S. (Eds), Social Capital: Theory and Research.

New York: Aldine de Gruyter, pp. 159–181.

Granovetter, M. (1973). The Strength of Weak Ties.

American Journal of Sociology, 78, 1360–1380.

Granovetter, M. (1974). Getting a Job: A Study of Con- tacts and Careers. Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press.

Granovetter, M. (1995). Getting a Job: A Study of Con- tacts and Careers, 2nd edn. Chicago and London:

University of Chicago Press.

Greene, W. H. (2000). Econometric Analysis, 4th edn.

London: Prentice Hall International.

Heckman, J. (1979). Sample Selection Bias as a Specifi- cation Error. Econometrica, 71, 153–167.

Jann, B. (2003). Old Boy Network. Militärdienst und ziviler Berufserfolg in der Schweiz. Zeitschrift für Soziologie, 32, 139–155.

Lin, N. (1999). Social Networks and Status Attainment.

Annual Review of Sociology, 25, 467–487.

Lin, N., Vaughn, J. C. and Ensel, W. M. (1981). Social Resources and Occupational Status Attainment.

Social Forces, 59, 1163–1181.

Lippman, S. and McCall, J. (1976). The Economics of Job Search: A Survey. Economic Inquiry, 14, 155–189, 347–368.

Marsden, P. and Campbell, K. (1990). Recruitment and Selection Processes: The Organization Side of Job Searches. In Breiger, R. (Ed.), Social Mobility and Social Structure. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp. 59–79.

Marsden, P. and Hurlbert, J. (1988). Social Resources and Mobility Outcomes: A Replication and Exten- sion. Social Forces, 66, 1038–1059.

Mau, W.-Ch. and Kopischke, A. (2001). Job Search Meth- ods, Job Search Outcomes, and Job Satisfaction of Col- lege Graduates: A Comparison of Race and Sex. Journal of Employment Counselling, 38, 141–149.

Montgomery, J. D. (1992). Job Search and Network Com- position: Implications of the Strength-of Weak-Ties Hypothesis. American Sociological Review, 57, 586–596.

Mortensen, D. T. (1986). Job Search and Labor Market Analysis. In Ashenfelter, O. and Layard, R. (Eds), Handbook of Labor Economics. New York: Elsevier Science, pp. 849–919.

Mouw, T. (2003). Social Capital and Finding a Job: Do Con- tacts Matter? American Sociological Review, 68, 868–898.

Osberg, L. (1993). Fishing in Different Pools: Job-Search and Job-finding Success in Canada in the Early 1980s. Journal of Labor Economics, 11, 348–386.

Ports, M. (1993). Trends in Job Search Methods, 1970–92.

Monthly Labor Review, 116, 63–37.

Preisendörfer, P. and Voss, Th. (1988). Arbeitsmarkt und soziale Netzwerke. Die Bedeutung sozialer Kon- takte beim Zugang zu Arbeitsplätzen. Soziale Welt, 39, 104–119.

Sagen, B., Dallam, J. and Laverty, J. (1999). Job Search Techniques as Employment Channels: Differential Effects on the Initial Employment Success of College Graduates. The Career Development Quarterly, 84, 74–85.

Staiger, D. (1990). The Effect of Connections on the Wages and Mobility of Young Workers. Cambridge, MA:

MIT Press.

U.S. Department of Labor. (1975). Job Seeking Methods Used by American Workers. Bureau of Labor Statis- tics, Bulletin No. 1886.

Wegener, B. (1991). Job Mobility and Social Ties: Social Resources, Prior Job, and Status Attainment. Ameri- can Sociological Review, 56, 60–71.

Wooldridge, J. M. (2002). Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

Young, A. (1974). Labor Market Experience of Recent College Graduates. Monthly Labor Review, 97, 33–40.

(15)

Authors’ Addresses

Axel Franzen (to whom correspondence should be addressed), Institute of Sociology, RWTH Aachen, Eilfschornsteinstr. 7, D-52062 Aachen, Germany.

Email: axel.franzen@soziologie.rwth-aachen.de.

Dominik Hangartner, Institute of Sociology, Univer- sity of Bern, Lerchenweg 36, CH-3012 Bern, Switzerland. Email: hangartner@soz.unibe.ch

Manuscript received: September 2005

Appendix 1

Table A1 Measurement of variables, means, and proportions of the Swiss Graduate Survey

Minimum Maximum Mean

Job found via social network 0 1 0.20

Search for a job 0 1 0.75

Job found via direct application 0 1 0.24

Number of used search strategies 0 10 2.15

University of Basel 0 1 0.07

University of Berne 0 1 0.12

University of Fribourg 0 1 0.07

University of Geneva 0 1 0.11

University of Lausanne 0 1 0.09

University of Neuchâtel 0 1 0.04

University of St. Gallen 0 1 0.05

University of Ticino 0 1 0.01

Swiss Institute of Technology in Zurich 0 1 0.17

Swiss Institute of Technology in Lausanne 0 1 0.06

University of Zurich 0 1 0.21

Theology 0 1 0.01

Language 0 1 0.11

History 0 1 0.09

Social Sciences 0 1 0.15

Other subjects of study 0 1 0.03

Law 0 1 0.08

Natural Science 0 1 0.12

Medicine 0 1 0.08

Technical subjects 0 1 0.15

Economics 0 1 0.18

Gender (1 = female) 0 1 0.45

Age (in years) 22 55 28.57

Nationality (1 = foreigner) 0 1 0.08

Work participation during study 0 1 0.28

Children (1 = yes) 0 1 0.08

Education of father 9 17.5 13.18

Education of mother 9 17.5 11.55

Part-time employed 0 1 0.36

Search duration (in months) 0 18 2.68

Position with managing responsibilities 0 1 0.17

Adequacy of university degree concerning job 1 4 2.86

Long-term employment vs. short-term job 0 1 0.89

Opportunity to apply abilities 0 3 2.30

Opportunity to exert influence 0 3 2.19

continued

(16)

Table A1 (continued)

The category History also includes Philosophy, Archaeology, History of Art, Ethnology, Music, Theatre, and Film. Social Sci- ences include Psychology, Pedagogic, Sociology, Social Work, Political Science, and Media Science. Other subjects include Ecol- ogy, Sport, and Military Science. Natural Sciences include Mathematics, Astronomy, Physics, Computer Science, Geography, Chemistry, and Biology. Economics also includes Business Administration.

Minimum Maximum Mean

Perception of payment 0 3 2.00

Number of applications 0 50 8.54

Number of job interviews 0 40 2.84

Perception of difficulties during the search 0 1 0.16

Logarithm of hourly wage 2.82 4.38 3.68

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

I argue that there is an opportunity for performative social science research to remember the ethical conse- quences of analysis and representation and to take responsibility for

The royal family, so it seems, has been preparing for Defense Minister Prince Salman, 77, Nayef's full brother, to take over power in the Kingdom.. On November 2011, the

Tilburg University, Royal Institute of Technology, Sweden, Tilburg University.

[r]

1.3 The influence of generalized trust and membership in voluntary associations on IEO: Conceptions, research, causal issues After having defined collective social capital CSC to

storico tra economisti e filosofi, che ha sancito l'utilità di continuare a impostare il discorso sul lavoro distinguendo nel problema marxiano del valore un

This has the advantage that the single parameters for regional inequality are based on a solid data basis since the complete number of cases from the 2005 Mi- crocensus (almost

The analysis, of the books selection social network analysis, shows that most of the books are edited volumes, which focus on specific approaches or introductory texts, focusing on