• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

A Note on Option Value and the Expected Value of Consumer's Surplus

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "A Note on Option Value and the Expected Value of Consumer's Surplus"

Copied!
11
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

NOT FOR QUOTATION WITHOUT P E R M I S S I O N O F THE AUTHOR

A NOTE ON O P T I O N VALUE AND THE

EXPECTED VALUE O F CONSUMER'S S U R P L U S

R o b e r t J . A n d e r s o n

S e p t e m b e r 1 9 8 0 W P - 8 0 - 1 3 3

Working P a p e r s a r e i n t e r i m r e p o r t s o n w o r k of t h e I n t e r n a t i o n a l I n s t i t u t e f o r A p p l i e d S y s t e m s A n a l y s i s a n d h a v e received o n l y l i m i t e d r e v i e w . V i e w s o r o p i n i o n s e x p r e s s e d h e r e i n do n o t n e c e s s a r i l y repre- s e n t t h o s e of t h e I n s t i t u t e o r of i t s N a t i o n a l M e m b e r O r g a n i z a t i o n s .

I N T E R N A T I O N A L I N S T I T U T E FOR A P P L I E D SYSTEMS A N A L Y S I S A - 2 3 6 1 L a x e n b u r g , A u s t r i a

(2)

PREFACE

Although environmental policy decisions frequently are based on other criteria, cost-benefit analysis plays an impor- tant role in the decision-making process. Questions concerning the costs and benefits of alternative courses of action are being explored in several of R E N 1 s studies of natural resource and en- vironmental management problems. This paper explores a general methodological problem that has arisen in applications of cost- benefit analysis of environmental resource decisions.

Several investigators claim that the usual methods of es- timating the benefits of environment preservation understate

systematically those benefits by an amount called "option value".

Loosely put., option value is the benefit that potential (but uncertain) users of environmental services derive from avoiding the risk that these services would be unavailable. A proof has been offered that these option value benefits are always non- negative. Other investigators have offered proofs that option value benefits may be either positive or negative and that, on a p r i o r i grounds, there is no way to determine whether or not usual benefits valuation methods systematically understate bene- fits of environmental preservation.

This paper attempts to reconcile these contradictory re- sults. Helpful comments and suggestions from Jesse Ausubel, Donald Erlenkotter, and Mark Pauly are acknowledged gratefully.

Nono of these kind individuals is to be held responsible for any errors, ambiguities, or other faults that may remain.

(3)

CONTENTS

INTRODUCTION

NOTATION, DEFINI'TIONS, AND ASSUMPTIONS DERIVATIONS

CONCLUSIONS REFERENCES

(4)

INTRODUCTION

In roughly contemporaneous papers, Schmalensee (1972) (here- after " S " ) and Krutilla, Cicchetti, Freeman and Russell (1972)

(hereafter "KC") reach apparently conflicting conclusions about the sign taken by option value.* Under the assumption that an individual's utility function is concave in income, S concluded that the sign of "option value depends on the details of individual preferences and circumstances and may be either positive or

negative."** In contrast, KC conclude that option value is always non-negative.

The practical siqnificance of these conclusions is enormous.

Analysts typically use the expected value of consumer's surplus as a measure of the uncertain future economic benefits of projects.

KC'S analysis implies that this practice will tend systematically to understate these benefits. S's analysis implies that while

the expected value of consumer's surplus is not an exact measure of future benefits, there is no reason to conclude that it is biased systematically either upward or downward.

*Option value is the difference between the maximum amount that an individual who maximizes expected utility would pay for an

option which guaranteed his/her right to consume at a stated set of prices, and the expected value of consumer's surplus from consuming at those prices. More rigorous definitions of option value are given in Section 2 of this paper.

**Schmalensee 1972:814.

- 1 -

(5)

Although the subsequent literature on option value reaffirms S's general conclusion, nowhere to my knowledge has an explicit explanation been offered for the contradictory result obtained by KC. Bishop and Cicchetti (1975) hint that: "By separating the problem the way he [i.e., Schmalensee] does, the uncertainty and trade-offs of the early literature are lost."* Bohm (1975) notes that in the special case employed in KC's analysis (i.e., a two state world in which the probability of each state is 0.5 and in which consumer's surplus associated with one of the states is 0), option value is positive if the marginal utility of in- come in the state in which consumer surplus is zero. Bohm and S also note many other specific cases in which option value is positive. However, neither explicitly diagnoses or states the source of KC's more definite and seemingly contradictory result.

What, then, led KC to reach the conclusion they did? The question is an important one. If it could be shown, as Bishop and Cicchetti allege, that KC'S formulation better reflects actual conditions of choice under uncertainty, then their con- clusions concerning option value would have to be taken seri- ously.

The purpose of this note is to show exactly why KC reach a different conclusion than does S concerning the sign of option value. The reason has nothing to do with the particular values of probabilities of states of nature, the number of states, the values assumed for consumer surplus in any of the states, or the relative values of marginal utilities of income. I will show that KC'S conflicting conclusions stem from two assumptions (one of which is not made explicit) that in all cases impose stronger conditions on individual "preferences and circumstances" than are imposed by S.

*Bishop and Cicchetti 1975:111. Footnote 4.

(6)

N O T A T I O N , DEFINITIONS, AND ASSUMPTIONS

To f a c i l i t a t e c o m p a r i s o n o f t h e S a n d KC f o r m u l a t i o n s a n d r e s u l t s , l e t u s a d o p t t h e f o l l o w i n g n o t a t i o n , d e f i n i t i o n s , a n d b a s i c a s s u m p t i o n s :

n = number o f s t a t e s

n = p r o b a b i l i t y t h a t s t a t e i o c c u r s i

ui

= i n d i r e c t u t i l i t y f u n c t i o n c o n d i t i o n a l o n t h e o c c u r r e n c e o f s t a t e i , w h i c h i s assumed t o b e t w i c e c o n t i n u o u s l y d i f f e r e n t i a b l e a n d s t r i c t l y c o n c a v e

p* = v e c t o r o f p r i c e s

>

P = a l t e r n a t i v e v e c t o r o f p r i c e s s u c h t h a t P = P*

Y i = i n c o m e , c o n d i t i o n a l on t h e o c c u r r e n c e o f t h e i t h s t a t e OPC = o p t i o n p r i c e , t h e amount t h a t a c o n s u m e r would b e

w i l l i n g t o p a y t o s e c u r e p r i c e v e c t o r P* i n s t g a d o f p r i c e v e c t o r P i n t h e f u t u r e , i . e . ,

SCi = c o n s u m e r ' s s u r p l u s i n s t a t e i when p r i c e s a r e I?* i n s t e a d

i i

o f P ; i . e . , U (P*,Yi-SCi) = U ( P , Y . )

1

OV = o p t i o n v a l u e =

n

O P C

-

L 7TiSCi i= 1

The d e f i n i t i o n s and a s s m p t i o n s s p e l l e d out above are adopted by both KC and S . I n a d d i t i o n t o t h e s e b a s i c a s s u m p t i o n s , KC a d o p t two a d d i t i o n a l a s s u m p t i o n s . T h e s e a r e b e s t e x p l a i n e d by r e f e r e n c e t o a d i a g r a m . I n F i g u r e 1 , i n d i f f e r e n c e c u r v e s f r o m two p r e f e r e n c e m a p s , c o r - r e s p o n d i n g t o two d i f f e r e n t s t a t e s o f n a t u r e , a r e d r a w n . The c u r v e s l a b e l e d

u1

a n d U: r e p r e s e n t i n d i f f e r e n c e c u r v e s f r o m t h e i n d i v i d -

1

u a l ' s p r e f e r e n c e map i f s t a t e 1 o c c u r s ( t h e s u b s c r i p t s i n d e x

2 2

d i f f e r e n t u t i l i t y l e v e l s ) a n d t h o s e l a b e l e d U1 a n d U2 r e p r e s e n t d i f f e r e n t u t i l i t y l e v e l s i n s t a t e 2 . The two g o o d s whose quan- t i t i e s a r e shown o n t h e a x e s o f F i g u r e 1 a r e " H i c k s - M a r s h a l l "

money ( d e n o t e d by Y ) and some o t h e r good X . The b u d g e t l i n e Y O A i s drawn a s s u m i n g t h a t t h e p r e f e r r e d p r i c e v e c t o r , P * , o b t a i n s .

(7)

A s c a n b e s e e n i n t h e d i a g r a m , i f s t a t e 2 o c c u r s , t h e q u a n t i t y demanded o f X i s 0 a n d t h e r e s u l t i n g l e v e l o f u t i l i t y i s U 1 ; 2 i f s t a t e 1 o c c u r s , t h e q u a n t i t y demanded o f X i s X1 a n d t h e r e s u l t i n g l e v e l o f u t i l i t y i s U 1 . 1

The f i r s t a d d i t i o n a l a s s u m p t i o n made by KC p r o v i d e s a means f o r r e l a t i n g t h e l e v e l s o f u t i l i t y i n d i f f e r e n t s t a t e s o f n a t u r e . T h i s a s s u m p t i o n , a s e x p l a i n e d b y KC, i s a s f o l l o w s :

F o r a n y g i v e n l e v e l o f income ( s a y Y i n F i g u r e 1 1 , 0

i f t h e i n d i v i d u a l d i d n o t demand good X , h e / s h e w o u l d c h o o s e a p o i n t o n t h e Y a x i s a n d e x p e r i e n c e a c e r t a i n l e v e l o f u t i l i t y ( U 1 2 i n F i g u r e 1 ) ; i f h e / s h e w e r e t o demand t h e good ( a s s u m i n g t h a t i t i s a v a i l a b l e ) , h e / s h e would c h o o s e a t a n g e n c y p o i n t o n t h e b u d g e t l i n e a s s o c i a t e d w i t h i n c o m e Y a n d e x p e r i e n c e a g i v e n l e v e l

0

o f u t i l i t y

(u:

i n F i g u r e 1 ) . Assume t h a t t h e a l t e r - n a t i v e o u t c o m e s h a v e t h e same u t i l i t y . T h a t i s ,

2

*

U1 = U , '

P u t s u c c i n c t l y , K C ' s a s s u m p t i o n i s t h a t i f income i s i d e n t i c a l i n a l l s t a t e s , u t i l i t i e s i n a l l s t a t e s o f n a t u r e a r e e q u a l a t t h e p r e f e r r e d p r i c e v e c t o r . I n t e r m s o f t h e n o t - a t i o n s e t f o r t h a b o v e , t h i s a s s u m p t i o n r e q u i r e s t h a t

f o r a l l s t a t e s o f n a t u r e i a n d j .

The s e c o n d a d d i t i o n a l a s s u m r ~ t i o n made by KC i s n o d h e l e e x - p l i c i t l y s t a t e d . R a t h e r i t i s i r r , p l i c i t i n t h e d e r i v a t i o n o f t h e i r c o n c l u s i o n . I t a r i s e s i n t h e i r c o n s t r u c t i o n o f t h e r e l a t i o n s h i p b e t w e e n u t i l i t y a n d i n c o m e , a n d t h e i r u s e o f t h i s c o n s t r u c t e d r e l a t i o n s h i p t o d e r i v e r e s u l t s on t h e s i g n o f o p t i o n v a l u e . K C ' s a s s u m p t i o n i s t h a t i n c o m e i s t h e same i n a l l s t a t e s o f n a t u r e . * *

* S e e KC 1 9 7 2 : 1 0 3 . I h a v e p a r a p h r a s e d t h e i r s t a t e m e n t s l i g h t l y t o a c c o m o d a t e t h e n o t a t i o n I h a v e a d o p t e d .

* * S e e KC 1 9 7 2 : 1 0 4 - 1 0 5 .

(8)

F i g u r e 1 . R e l a t i o n s h i p b e t w e e n u t i l i t i e s o n d i f f e r e n t p r e f e r e n c e maps.

(9)

DERIVATIONS

It is relatively easy to show how KC, given all of these as- sumptions (i.e., the basic assumptions and the two additional as- sumptions), reach the conclusion that option value is non-negative.

To do this, let us first relate our mathematical definition of option price to our mathematical definition of consumer's surplus (see the definitions of option price and consumer's surplus in Section 2). Carrying out the required substitution, we obtain

n n

i i

C IT.U (P*,Yi-OPC) = C n . U (P* v -SCi)

1 1

i= 1 '-i i=l

Approximating U ("*rYi-SCi) by expanding to the first-order i about Yi-OPC, and making use of the fact that the 'U are concave

(by assumption), we obtain

where

ui

is the derivative of

ui

with respect to Yi, the so-called Y

"marginal utility of income." Substituting this relationship into equation (1) and collecting terms, we obtain

Equation (2) is (one of) the fundamental equations obtained by S in his analysis of option value. He demonstrates that,

making use only of the basic assumptions spelled out in Section 2, one cannot conclude from this relationship whether opticn

value is positive or negative.

Now let us impose the two additional assumptions made by KC.

Taken jointly, these assumptions imply that the utilities in all states of nature are equal. It follows that the derivatives of utilities in all states of nature with respect to income are equal, i.e., that U i = U' for all i and j . Inspection of equation (2)

Y Y

reveals immediately the conclusion that follows in this case.

Option value is always non-negative under these circumstances.

(10)

CONCLUSIONS

I t i s c l e a r t h a t t h e a d d i t i o n a l a s s u m p t i o n s made by KC a r e s t r o n g e r t h a n m o s t a n a l y s t s would w a n t t o a d o p t . I n e f f e c t , t h e o p t i o n o f f e r e d i n t h e KC a n a l y s i s g u a r a n t e e s t h e p u r c h a s e r t h a t a s p e c i f i e d u t i l i t y l e v e l w i l l b e o b t a i n e d i n a l l f u t u r e s t a t e s . Very few p r a c t i c a l i n v e s t m e n t o p t i o n s a r e o f t h i s s o r t . Under t h e more g e n e r a l f o r m u l a t i o n s a d o p t e d by S , p u r c h a s e o f a n op- t i o n e n t i t l e s i t s h o l d e r o n l y t o a g i v e n e x p e c t e d u t i l i t y l e v e l . K C ' S c o n c l u s i o n , a l t h o u g h i m p e c c a b l y c o r r e c t g i v e n t h e assump- t i o n s u n d e r w h i c h i t was d e r i v e d , i s t h e r e f o r e o f l i m i t e d p r a c - t i c a l s i g n i f i c a n c e .

(11)

REFERENCES

Bishop, J., and C. Cicchetti. 1975. Some Institutional and Conceptual Thoughts on the Measurement of Indirect and Intangible Benefits and Costs. Pages 105-126 in: Cost Benefit Analysis and Water Pollution Policy, edited by H.M. Peskin and E.P. Seskin. The Urban Institute.

Bohm, Peter. September 1975. Option Demand and Consumer's Surplus: Comment. American Economic Review:733-739.

Krutilla, J.V., C.J. Cicchetti, A.M. Freemann 111, and C.S.

Russell. 1972. Observations on the Economics of Irreplace- able Assets. P a ~ e s 69-112 in: Environmental Quality Analysis, edited by A.V. Kneese and B.T. Bower. Johns Hopkins Univer- sity Press.

Schmalensee, R. December 1972. Option Demand and Consumer's Surplus: Valuing Price Changes Under Uncertainty. American Economic Review: 813-824.

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

With Grammatical Notes, henceforth the Ndau Vocabulary, can be used as a basis for modern Ndau lexicography and the general intellectualization of Ndau.. The term

We take the whole of this body of work as read, in what we present here, for the simple reason that we do not have the time to repeat it. We do not repeat it also because we have

Likewise equation 13 can only hold true in a society which reproduces itself equally perfectly and unchangingly (as Sraffa himself remarks) but with a fully

Bereanu, The continuity of the optimum in parametric programming and applications to stochastic programming, J.Optim.Theory Applic. Robinson, A characterization of stability

(7), when the prey and the predator are asymmetric with respect to their valuations, the type of equilibrium depends both on the effectiveness of their armies and on the ratio of

Potentially, a change in divorce legislation can impact on the age at marriage or, equivalently, the probability of transition from singlehood to marriage, both by directly changing

They show that: independence of directors has been relevant and involved a positive effect on the creation of value in the crisis period; gender diversity in corporate

Specifically, if there is pressure to force the domestic currency's exchange rate to be depreciated because the demand of domestic currency will be exceeded by