• Keine Ergebnisse gefunden

The Paradox of Thrift in an Inegalitarian Neoclassical Economy

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Aktie "The Paradox of Thrift in an Inegalitarian Neoclassical Economy"

Copied!
22
0
0

Wird geladen.... (Jetzt Volltext ansehen)

Volltext

(1)

Munich Personal RePEc Archive

The Paradox of Thrift in an Inegalitarian Neoclassical Economy

Mabrouk, Mohamed

Ecole Supérieure de Statistiques et d’Analyse de l’Information (Tunis), 6 rue des métiers, Charguia 2, Tunis, Tunisia

12 December 2016

Online at https://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/76026/

(2)

The Paradox of Thrift in an Inegalitarian Neoclassical Economy

version December 12, 2016 Mohamed Mabrouk1 A bst r act

[Schilcht 1975] and [Bourguignon 1981] st udied t he case of a convex sav- ing funct ion in t he [St iglit z 1969] model. T hey have shown t hat if one of t he two proport ions of t he rich or t he poor is below a cert ain t hreshold, t here is a two-class equilibrium. However, t hey have only proved t he exist ence of t his t hreshold. We give here a syst em of equat ions t o calculat e t his t hreshold which we int erpret as t he maximum proport ion of rich for having a st able two-class con…gurat ion. If t he proport ion of rich exceeds t his t hreshold, t he economy en- t ers a phase of decline alt hough t he golden-rule capit al has not yet been reached.

T his decline is due t o a speci…c art iculat ion between t he rat e of decrease in t he product ivity of capit al and t he rat e of increase in t he depreciat ion of capit al.

T he mechanism of t his decline recalls t he descript ion given in [Keynes 1936], of t he decline which happens when t here is t oo much savings in an inegalit arian cont ext . T his is an example of what is known as t he " paradox of t hrift " . It is remarkable t hat t his paradox t akes place in a neoclassical set t ing t hat does not include key Keynesian element s such as sat urat ion of demand, monet izat ion of savings, short -t erm e¤ect s, expect at ion problems, involunt ary unemployment and rigidit ies. Numerical simulat ions are given t o illust rat e and analyze t he mechanisms involved.

Keywords : Paradox of T hrift , Inequality, Saving, Growt h.

1 I nt r oduct ion

[Schilcht 1975] and [Bourguignon 1981] st udied t he case of a convex relat ion- ship between savings and income in t he [St iglit z 1969] model. T he purpose of t he St iglit z model was t o show t he in‡uence of income and wealt h dist ribu- t ion on economic growt h and on t he convergence of social classes. Alt hough t here is no evidence of t he convex or non-convex nat ure of t he relat ionship be- tween savings and income at t he aggregat e level, at t he individual and st at ic level t he convexity hypot hesis is t he most likely [Dynan-Skinner-Zeldes 2004, Boushey-Hersh 2012]. T herefore, t he present st udy is based on t his hypot he- sis of convexity. [Schilcht 1975] has shown t hat if t his hypot hesis is adopt ed inst ead of t he concavity or linearity of t he relat ionship between individual sav- ings and income, and if t he proport ion of one of t he social classes is less t han a cert ain t hreshold, t he convergence of social classes no longer t akes place and

1Ecole Supérieure de St at ist iques et d’A nalyse de l’I nformat ion (Tunis), 6 rue des mét iers,

(3)

t he syst em evolves t owards an inegalit arian equilibrium wit h two social classes.

T herefore, t he spont aneous and generally observable t rend t owards a rich / poor social st ruct ure rat her t han an egalit arian st ruct ure is furt her con…rmat ion of t he convexity hypot hesis. [Bourguignon 1981] shows t hat under t his hypot hesis, inegalit arian equilibria Paret o-dominat e t he egalit arian equilibrium.

In t his paper we give a syst em of equat ions which allows calculat ing t his t hreshold and we int erpret it as t he maximum proport ion of rich t o have a st able two-class con…gurat ion. If t he proport ion of rich people exceeds t his t hreshold, t he economy ent ers a phase of decline.

T he purpose of t his paper is also t o examine in det ail t his decline in t he light of t he descript ion in [Keynes 1936] of t he economic decline caused by an excess of savings in a cont ext of inequality.

We begin in sect ion 2 by present ing t he charact erist ics of t he model and t he main result s obt ained by [Schilcht 1975] and [Bourguignon 1981]. We most ly keep t he not at ions and met hod of [Bourguignon 1981].

In Sect ion 3, we give t he equat ions for calculat ing t he maximal sust ainable proport ion of rich (MSPOR). We calculat e t he MSPOR from numerical values proposed for t he rat e of capit al depreciat ion and for product ion and saving funct ions. T he calculat ion is carried out for di¤erent values of t he propensity t o save. T hese numerical values are also used for t he following sect ions t o illust rat e t he …ndings.

In Sect ion 4, we analyze t he dynamics of t he decline. Given a cert ain re- semblance t o t he descript ion in [K eynes 1936], we refer t o it as t he " Keynesian decline" .

We t hen discuss t he following quest ions:

- How does t he equilibrium of t he economy behave according t o t he dist rib- ut ion of wealt h? (Sect ion 5) T his sect ion shows t hat a t iny proport ion of rich people makes it possible t o push a locked economy int o insu¢ cient savings and egalit arian poverty t owards a level close t o t he golden-rule. On t he ot her hand, it also shows t hat t he increase in t his proport ion is harmful.

- How does equilibrium behave according t o t he propensity t o save, for a given dist ribut ion of wealt h? (Sect ion 6). T his sect ion highlight s t he phe- nomenon of " paradox of t hrift " alt hough t he model does not include st rict ly K eynesian element s, such as sat urat ion of demand, monet izat ion of savings, short -t erm e¤ect s, expect at ion problems, unemployment and rigidit ies.

Sect ion 7 concludes and present s possible direct ions for furt her st udy.

2 N ot at ion and m ain feat ur es of t he m odel

Wemainly use t he assumpt ions, not at ions, met hod and result s of [Bourguignon 1981].

T he economy is represent ed by a per capit a product ion funct ion() where

is t he average capit al per capit a.  is increasing, concave and twice di¤eren- t iable. Individual savings are assumed t o depend on income according t o t he

(4)

funct ion() where is t he income of t he individual concerned.  is convex, increasing, di¤erent iable and checks lim

! 10() = 1.

T he capit al undergoes depreciat ion at a rat e per unit of t ime and capit al.

T his depreciat ion plays t he same roleas populat ion growt h in [Bourguignon 1981].

We have t hought t hat it would be more appropriat e, in modern economic con- dit ions, t o speak of depreciat ion of capit al rat her t han demography. But t he int erpret at ion ofas a populat ion growt h rat e remains valid.

We assume t hat t he economy has a unique st able egalit arian equilibrium

0. Mat hemat ically, t his condit ion is equivalent t o saying t hat 0 is t he unique solut ion of t he equat ion(()) =  and t hat 0((0))0(0) .

We denot e by ¤ t he per capit a capit al of t he golden-rule de…ned by

0(¤) = 

T he society is composed of 2 classes: t he poor, in proport ion 1 and t he rich in proport ion2 = 1 ¡ 1. In a t heoret ical perspect ive, t his assumpt ion is not rest rict ive because t he convexity of saving implies t hat t he equilibrium has at most two classes [Bourguignon 1981]. In t he spirit of t he present st udy, t he concept of " poor class" includes t he middle class. Consequent ly, t he poor class is t he majority. So, we have2 1. We will assume t his for all t he following.

T he capit al st ock per capit a is1 for t he poor and2 for t he rich. T he average per capit a capit al t herefore sat is…es= 11+ 22.

As st at ed by t he neoclassical t heory of dist ribut ion, capit al is paid for ac- cording t o it s marginal product ivity. T he remunerat ion of per capit a capit al is t herefore: 0(). By deduct ion, t he per capit a wage is() ¡ 0(). All in- dividuals receive t he same payment in exchange for t heir cont ribut ions t o work, i.e. () ¡ 0(). For capit al, individuals are remunerat ed according t o t he shares of capit al t hey hold. T hus, an individual of class (wit h  = 1 or 2) receives0() in exchange for his cont ribut ion t o capit al. Moreover, he bears t he share of t he depreciat ion of t he capit al he owns: .

T he equat ion of capit al evolut ion for classis t herefore

¢= [() ¡ 0() + 0()] ¡ 

T he equilibrium is t hus charact erized by t he following 3 equat ions for t he 3 unknowns1 2 and:

[() + (1¡ )0()] ¡ 1 = 0 (1)

[() + (2¡ )0()] ¡ 2 = 0

 = 11+ 22

Denot e t he inverse funct ion of . We have

01 000 and

lim0() = 1

(5)

Let () be t he curve in t he space ( ) de…ned by t he equat ion :

[() + (¡ )0()] = 

or, equivalent ly:

() + (¡ )0() = ()

T he curve () int ersect s t he line ( = ) at t he point s sat isfying() =

(). By assumpt ion, t his equat ion is veri…ed only in0. T herefore t he curve () int ersect s t he line (= ) only in0.

[Bourguignon 1981] shows t hat a necessary condit ion for an equilibrium wit h two social classes is0 ¤. In t his case and for2 [0 ¤[ he est ablishes t hat t he equat ion() + (¡ )0() = () admit s two solut ions1() and2() such t hat 1() 6  and2()  . T hese two solut ions are candidat es for per capit a capit al values of t he two social classes at equilibrium.

All det ails and just i…cat ions concerning t he elaborat ion of t he curve (), t he phase plan and t he dynamics of t he syst em can be found in [Bourguignon 1981].

We have reproduced here t he not at ions of [Bourguignon 1981] in order t o facil- it at e t he consult at ion of t his reference at t he same t ime as t he present paper.

We assume for all t he following t hat t he condit ion0 ¤is checked because wit hout it all social classes would necessarily converge. Indeed, in cont inuity wit h t he work of [Schilcht 1975] and [Bourguignon 1981], our concern is t o st udy

(6)

t he consequences of a persist ent inequality, a pat t ern t hat seems t o be more realist ic.

If we consider t he product ion paramet ers as given (i.e. t he product ion func- t ion and t he depreciat ion coe¢ cient ) t hen t he posit ion of0 wit h respect t o¤ depends on t he saving behavior, t hat is, on t he funct ion. T he int uit ive eco- nomic int erpret at ion of t he condit ion0 ¤ is t hat t he poor class, if it where alone, would not have t he su¢ cient saving propensity t o reach t he golden-rule

2.

De…ning t he funct ion() by t he equat ion (1¡ ())1()+()2() = , [Bourguignon 1981] shows t hat  is posit ive and cont inuous over ]0 ¤[, t hat

(0) = 0 and lim

! ¤() = 0. It follows t hat() admit s a maximum on ]0 ¤[ denot ed , and t hat under t he condit ion 0  ¤, for a st able inegalit arian equilibrium t o exist , we must have inf (1 2)  . T his condit ion is also su¢ cient3 and t he inegalit arian equilibrium Paret o-dominat es t he egalit arian equilibrium.

Since we have assumed 2  1, t he necessary and su¢ cient condit ion be- comes2  . Let us observe t hat t he social class which was init ially poor will never be able t o surpass t he rich class. Indeed, assuming t hat t he syst em invert s t he sit uat ions along t he way, t hen, by cont inuity of t he st at e variables1

and2, it would be necessary t hat at a cert ain dat e t hese two variables become equal. Equat ions (1) show t hat t hese two variables would t hen always remain equal from t his dat e on.

We deduce t hat 2 const it ut es t he proport ion of t he rich class at t he begin- ning and at t he end. One can t herefore reformulat e t he necessary and su¢ cient condit ion for t he exist ence of a st able inegalit arian equilibrium by saying t hat t he proport ion of rich must be less t han.

3 T he m ax im al sust ainable pr opor t ion of r ich

If t he proport ion of rich exceeds, [Bourguignon 1981] shows t hat t here can be only an egalit arian equilibrium Paret o-dominat ed by t he inegalit arian equilibria achievable wit h proport ions of rich less t han. As soon as t he proport ion of rich exceeds, we will see t hat t he economy ends up being t rapped in a decline.

For t his reason we refer t o as t he maximal sust ainable proport ion of rich (MSPOR).

In t his sect ion we est ablish a syst em of equat ions for calculat ing. T hen, as example, di¤erent values of  corresponding t o di¤erent values of cert ain paramet ers are calculat ed.

2T his int uit ive int erpret at ion of0 ¤ ent ails t hat0 increases wit h t he saving propen- sit y, what is checked in all t he following. T he precise de…nit ion of t he saving propensit y is given in next sect ion.

3I n fact , Bourguignon assert s t hat inf (1 2) 6 is a necessary and su¢ cient condit ion, but if inf (1 2) = , t he st abilit y is lost .

(7)

To calculat e, we st art from t he syst em (1) replacing 2 by (). From now on, it is assumed t hat t he syst em (1) is smoot h enough for t he funct ions

1() 2() and() t o be di¤erent iable. T hen we derive t he 3 equat ions wit h respect t oand we writ e t hat  = 0.

We have

= (1 ¡ ())1+ ()2

Deriving wit h respect t o, we get : 1 = ()(2¡ 1)

 + (2¡ 1)

 + 1



We writ e t hat  = 0 at , which gives:

= 1 ¡ 1

2

 ¡ 1 (2)

Furt hermore, t he derivat ives of1 and2 wit h respect t o are obt ained by deriving t he …rst two equat ions of t he syst em (1):

1

 = " ()(1¡ )

0(1) ¡ 0() (3)

2

 = " ()(2¡ )

0(2) ¡ 0() (4) Last ly, t he t hird equat ion of t he syst em (1) provides:

= ¡ 1

2¡ 1

(5) We obt ain equat ions (2) t o (5) for t he unknowns: 12  and . By adding t he …rst two equat ions of t he syst em (1), we obt ain 6 equat ions for t he 6 unknowns1 212  and.

It is not ewort hy t hat t he value ofdepends only on t he product ion funct ion, t he rat e of depreciat ion and t he saving funct ion, and not on t he init ial st at e of t he economy (i.e. init ial capit al and wealt h dist ribut ion).

Since t here is no explicit formula for , we have t hought useful t o t ake numerical values for t hese 3 dat a (product ion funct ion, depreciat ion rat e and saving funct ion) t o illust rat e our point and get an idea of t he order of magnit ude of for t hese numerical values. It is not argued t hat t he following calculat ions express t he act ual sit uat ion of a part icular count ry4.

T he product ion funct ion is chosen so t hat t he marginal product ivity of cap- it al can decrease rapidly. T he choice is a Cobb-Douglas wit h a share of t he capit al income equal t o 0.3. T he paramet ers of t he product ion funct ion have been adjust ed so t hat t he capit al coe¢ cient is 2.5 for an average per capit a

4T he model is st ill at t he rudiment ary st age t o lend it self t o empirical work.

(8)

income normalized t o 1. Consequent ly, t he product ion funct ion per capit a is

() = 3403.

An analyt ic form has been adjust ed for t he individual saving funct ion t o ensure t hat it is increasing, convex and t hat t he limit of t he marginal propensity t o save equal t o 1:

() = + 1

2(1 + )(¡ ) + 1 ¡  1 +  s

0+

· 1

2(1 + )(¡ )

¸2

T his form checks t he request ed condit ions. T he coe¢ cient s  and0are adjust ed t o have t he following values for individual savings rat es at di¤erent levels of income:

income 0.1 1 1.5 2

savings rat e 7% 15% 20% 30%

By minimizing t he sum of t he absolut e values of t he deviat ions, t he adjust ed values for  and0are:

 = 17105249

 = 00255809

 = 00677230

0 = 01889504

T he t erm " social propensity t o save" is used hereaft er t o indicat e t he general st at e of mind of society about t he willingness t o save. If funct ion represent s t he saving behavior, t he change in t he level of t he social propensity t o save can be obt ained by t he form:

() = 1

()

T he variat ion of t he coe¢ cient t hus represent s t he variat ion of t he overall willingness t o save of society (see t he following graph). If  increases, t he willingness t o save increases. is referred t o as t he " social propensity t o save" . It is obvious, however, t hat t he variat ion of t he coe¢ cient  can not in it self represent all t he possibilit ies of modifying t he pro…le of t he willingness t o save.

For example, one can t hink of an increase in t he willingness t o save among t he poor at t he same t ime as a decrease among t he rich. Such a change is not capt ured by t he paramet erand is not considered in t he present st udy.

If   1 t he propensity t o save increases for all incomes. It decreases if

 1:

income 0.1 1 1.5 2

savings rat e wit h= 12 7.8% 16.7% 25.3% 37.1%

savings rat e wit h= 08 5.8% 13.6% 16.7% 21.8%

(9)

We obt ain t he following curves t hat give t he individual savings rat e as a funct ion of income for = 08 = 1 and = 12:

S( y ) S( 1 . 2 y ) / 1 . 2

S( 0 . 8 y ) / 0 . 8

Last ly, t he annual capit al depreciat ion rat e is set at 3.7%.

Wit h t he various paramet ers speci…ed above, t he following result s for  as a funct ion ofare obt ained by comput er:

1 1.2 1.1 0.9 0.8

5.44% 1.33% 4.45% 5.35% 4.85%

We see t hat t he MSPOR decreases quit e sharply if t he social propensity t o save increases from t he reference sit uat ion= 1.

For each value of and wit h a proport ion of rich equal t o, values of per capit a and per class capit al and out put at inegalit arian equilibrium are given as well as per capit a capit al and out put at egalit arian equilibrium:

1 1.2 1.1 0.9 0.8

average per capit a capit al 8.89 11.75 9.89 8.29 7.86

average per capit a income 1.44 1.57 1.49 1.41 1.39

per capit a capit al of t he poor 6.51 10.73 7.98 5.62 5.01 per capit a capit al of t he rich 50.2 87.5 50.86 55.53 63.72 per capit a income of the poor 1.33 1.53 1.41 1.28 1.24 per capit a income of the rich 3.46 4.61 3.35 3.83 4.36 per capit a capit al at egalit arian equilibrium 6.25 10.66 7.77 5.35 4.75 per capit a income at egalitarian equilibrium 1.30 1.53 1.39 1.24 1.2 per capit a capit al at t he golden-rule 13.18 13.18 13.18 13.18 13.18

(10)

We see t hat t he best sit uat ion for bot h t he poor and t he rich is t he sit uat ion

 = 12, where t he social propensity t o save is high and t he proport ion of wealt hy low. T he most damaging sit uat ion for t he poor is t he sit uat ion= 08 where t he social propensity t o save is low and t he proport ion of rich is quit e high.

We now give t he savings rat es()at equilibrium by social class and for society as a whole, for each value of.

1 1.2 1.1 0.9 0.8

savings rat e of the poor 18.1% 26% 21% 16.3% 15%

savings rat e of the rich 53.7% 70.2% 56.2% 53.6% 54%

aggregat e savins rat e 22.7% 27.7% 24.5% 21.7% 20.9%

We see t hat , apart from t he case = 12, t he aggregat e savings rat es are relat ively close. However, t he social propensit ies t o save, individual savings rat es and equilibrium incomes di¤er signi…cant ly. In fact t he aggregat e savings rat e is a paramet er which, considered alone, does not re‡ect t he saving behavior.

Ot her charact erist ics are import ant such as t he level of average income, t he dist ribut ion of wealt h and income, or t he posit ion in t he accumulat ion process (more or less close t o equilibrium). For example, t he aggregat e savings rat e may increase due t o a higher concent rat ion of income while t he average income falls. T his may explain t he inconclusive result s of t he st udies on t he relat ionship between aggregat e savings rat es and income [Dynan-Skinner-Zeldes 2004]. But it should not be concluded t hat at t he individual level, t he savings rat e does not increase as income increases.

4 T he K eynesian decline

We are int erest ed here in what happens when t he proport ion of rich exceeds

. Aft er a period of growt h, t he economy declines t owards t he egalit arian con…gurat ion which happens t o be Paret o-dominat ed by inegalit arian equilibria, as showed by [Bourguignon 1981]. We t ry t o see t he mechanisms of t his decline t hrough a numerical example.

T he paramet ers of t he sect ion 3 are used again: product ion funct ion, saving funct ion wit h= 1 and depreciat ion rat e. T he following …gure shows t he phase plan if we t ake a proport ion of rich of 3%, less t han t he MSPOR which is 5.44%

for  = 1. T he init ial per capit a capit al of t he rich class is given t he values

02 = 5 and 6 t hen 100, and t he init ial per capit a capit al of t he poor class t he value01= 06. T he following t raject ories (in green) are obt ained:

(11)

c

1

c

2

0

2

c

1

 0

c

0

100

2

c

0

6

2

c

0

5

2

c

%

2  3 a

We observe t hat if 02= 6, t he economy is freed from from t he pat h t o t he poor egalit arian equilibrium and grows t owards t he rich inegalit arian equilib- rium. Whereas if one begins wit h02 = 5, t he income of t he rich class is not su¢ cient t o allow a saving capable t o release t he economy from t he pat h of egalit arian poverty. T his conclusion is not surprising. It is consist ent wit h t he int uit ion t hat capit al weakness can t rap t he economy int o poverty.

It is less immediat e t o admit t hat an excess of capit al can lead t o t rapping t he economy in poverty. Yet , if we t ake a proport ion of rich above t he MSPOR, t his is what we observe. T his is t he case t hat is int erest ing t o analyze.

We t ake2= 6%. T he curves n ¢

1= 0 o

and n ¢

2= 0 o

int ersect only in t he poor egalit arian equilibrium. T he following t raject ory is obt ained for 02 = 50 and01= 08:

(12)

2

 0

c c

1

0

c

2

c

1

%

2

 6 a

In t his set t ing, t he rich begin wit h a per capit a capit al of 50. T hey t hen climb t o more t han 90 t o …nally plummet t o 625 which is t he capit al per capit a of t he poor egalit arian equilibrium. T he poor also experience a drop at t he end of t he t raject ory from 690 t o 625. But t his decline is less marked and t he overall balance is posit ive for t hem: from 08 t o 625.

To underst and t he reason for t his decline, we are int erest ed in what governs t he capit al dynamics for t he rich, t hat is, t heir savings on t he one hand and t he depreciat ion of t heir capit al on t he ot her.

(13)

time axis (years) capit al depreciat ion

of t he rich savings of t he rich

At t he st art , bot h classes t ake advant age of t he exist ence of inequality. In- deed, t he poor bene…t from a good level of product ion made possible by t he capit al of t he rich, whereas t he rich pro…t from a good product ivity of t heir capit al t hanks t o t he labor of t he poor, or in ot her words, t hanks t o a st ill modest macroeconomic capit al per capit a rat io. T he economy is growing con- siderably.

T his st rong growt h has t he e¤ect of an increase in t he capit al st ock and a rapid decline in capit al marginal product ivity. T his decline doubly a¤ect s t he income of t he rich in comparison wit h t he case of an equal dist ribut ion of wealt h.

Indeed, it curbs t he increase in product ion, as is also t he case in an egalit arian society where capit al st ock is growing. But in addit ion t o t his, it diminishes t he income share of t he wealt hy acquired t hrough t he exist ence of inequalit ies.

In t he above graph, t he income and savings of t he rich begin t o decline aft er about 20 years. However, t heir savings remain abundant . T heir capit al t herefore cont inues t o rise and it begins t o fall only aft er about 50 years of t he dat e of t he decline in income. T his discrepancy is t he cause of an excessive accumulat ion which leads t o a sit uat ion where it is no longer possible t o cover t he depreciat ion of capit al by saving. T he decline t hen begins and it is no longer recoverable. In fact , t his dynamic depends on t he comparison between

(14)

t he decline in t he product ivity of capit al and t he increase in t he depreciat ion of capit al. It should be not ed t hat at t he macroeconomic level, average per capit a capit al does not reach t he golden-rule st age beyond which capit al product ivity falls below depreciat ion rat e. T hus, inequality makes t he economic growt h st op before reaching t he golden-rule st age. But it will be seen below (sect ion 5) t hat inequality can also make it possible t o approach t he golden-rule by compensat ing t he weakness of t he savings of t he poor class.

T hus t he init ial abundance of wealt h is t he very cause of subsequent decline.

A smaller proport ion of rich in t he beginning could have delayed capit al growt h and marginal product ivity decline so t hat t he economy st abilizes wit hout t um- bling int o poverty, as t he case2= 3% shows.

T hemechanism of t hisdecline remindsone of t hedescript ion in [Keynes 1936], of t he decline t hat occurs when t here is t oo much unevenly dist ribut ed wealt h.

T hat ’s what he calls " t he paradox of poverty in t he midst of plenty, where exces- sive wealt h and saving of t he rich can lead t o a decline in bot h aggregat e wealt h and savings" [Keynes 1936, chapt er 3, sect ion I I]. In t his regard, he assert s t hat :

“ . . . t he richer t he community, t he wider will t end t o be t he gap between it s act ual and it s pot ent ial product ion; and t herefore t he more obvious and out rageous t he defect s of t he economic syst em.

For a poor community will be prone t o consume by far t he great er part of it s out put , so t hat a very modest measure of invest ment will be su¢ cient t o provide full employment ; whereas a wealt hy commu- nity will have t o discover much ampler opport unit ies for invest ment if t he saving propensit ies of it s wealt hier members are t o be compat - ible wit h t he employment of it s poorer members. If in a pot ent ially wealt hy community t he inducement t o invest is weak, t hen, in spit e of it s pot ent ial wealt h, t he working of t he principle of e¤ect ive de- mand will compel it t o reduce it s act ual out put , unt il, in spit e of it s pot ent ial wealt h, it has become so poor t hat it s surplus over it s con- sumpt ion is su¢ cient ly diminished t o correspond t o t he weakness of t he inducement t o invest .”

T he decline in invest ment opport unit ies in t his paragraph of K eynes corre- sponds in t he present model t o declining product ivity as capit al accumulat ion progresses. However, t here is no quest ion of capit al depreciat ion in t his para- graph of K eynes, but of underemployment .

Ot her element s generally present in Keynesian economics, such as demand- driven economy, monet izat ion of savings, short -t erm e¤ect s, expect at ion prob- lems and rigidit ies, are not included in t he present model of neoclassical essence.

It is remarkable t hat , despit e t his, t he decline does occur anyway.

(15)

5 T he pr opor t ion of r ich and t he aggr egat e sav- ings r at e

A number of economist s share t he view t hat great er inequality, by shift ing in- come t oward more saving agent s, increases t he aggregat e savings rat e, t hus accelerat ing capit al accumulat ion and growt h. T his idea can be found, for ex- ample, in [Barro 2000].

On t he cont rary, more recent opinions reconnect wit h t he vision expressed in K eynes‘s quot e (sect ion 4) and at t ribut e a less posit ive role t o inequalit ies wit h respect t o t heir impact on t he economy and consequent ly saving [St iglit z 2011, Ost ry-Berg-T sangarides 2014].

It should be not ed t hat what is generally referred t o as " inequality" is meant t o describe a sit uat ion wit h a large income gap between rich and poor. T his con- cept of inequality is not only dependent on t he proport ion of rich. It can evolve even in t he opposit e direct ion t o t he proport ion of rich if one keeps personal in- comes const ant and if one measures inequality by t he Gini index. However, t his sect ion only examines t he relat ionship between t he proport ion of rich and t he ag- gregat e savings rat e, what is nevert heless a t opical issue as t he number of billion- aires has doubled since 2008 …nancial crisis [Oxfam report “ Even It Up” 2014].

Wit hin t he present framework, we show t hat if we st art from an egalit arian sit uat ion and int roduce a t iny proport ion of rich people, t he aggregat e savings rat e at equilibrium improves signi…cant ly. But if we st art from a sit uat ion where t here are already some rich people, t he addit ion of new rich people det eriorat es t he income and t he aggregat e savings rat e at equilibrium.

[Bourguignon 1981] shows t hat , for a given proport ion of rich 2 sat isfying 0 2 , t he possible equilibria are pairs (1 2) each consist ing of an un- st able equilibrium1and a st able equilibrium2 wit h2 1. We deduce t hat t he equilibrium det ermined by (2) = sup f() = 2g is a st able equilib- rium. As st at ed in [Bourguignon 1981], t he equilibriumParet o-dominat es all t he ot her equilibria where t he proport ion of rich is2.

Let us show t hat t he equilibrium capit al (2) and t he aggregat e savings rat e are decreasing as funct ions of2 as long as20:

At equilibrium, aggregat e savings are necessarily equal t o t he depreciat ion of t he t ot al capit al:

= 

T he aggregat e savings rat e as a funct ion of  is t herefore() = 

(). It is easily checked t hat() is an increasing funct ion ofbecause is concave and posit ive. We now prove t hat (2) is a decreasing funct ion of 2, which will est ablish t he decrease of t he aggregat e savings rat e as a funct ion of2.

Suppose not . T here would be two real numbers in ]01[ such t hat   , which would check ()  () or () = (). Suppose()  (). De…ne t he funct ion () = () ¡  on t he int erval £

() ¤¤

. T he funct ion () is

(16)

assumed t o be cont inuous on [0 ¤] (by set t ing(¤) = 0 - for t he de…nit ion and propert ies of A, see sect ions 2 and 3).

We have(()) = (()) ¡ = ¡  0 and(¤) = (¤) ¡ = ¡  0.

T he funct ion  being cont inuous, t here would exist  in £

() ¤¤

such t hat

() = 0. We would have() ¡ = 0, wit h> () (). T his cont radict s t he de…nit ion of() = sup f() = g. We t hus have() > (). In fact , we have()  (). Indeed, since is cont inuous, we have(()) = . If we suppose() = (), t hen (()) = (()), which implies =  and cont radict s  . QED

We now show t hat t he limit of (2) when2! 0 is¤:

Since t he funct ion() is decreasing, it has a limit when2! 0. We show t hat t his limit is¤. Consider an increasing sequence which t ends t o¤from t he left . Denot e = (). T he funct ion  being posit ive on ]0 ¤[ and cont inuous on [0 ¤], t he sequence is posit ive and t ends t o 0. Moreover

() > . So() ! ¤, what shows t hat t he limit of  when2 t end t o 0 from t he right is¤. QED

T herefore, when t he proport ion of rich decreases, t he average per capit a capit al t ends t o t he golden-rule level, where t he average net income is maximum.

T he limit of t he aggregat e savings rat e is t he golden-rule’s savings rat e(¤) =

¤

(¤). In t he Cobb-Douglas case, t his rat e is equal t o t he share of capit al, which is 03 in our numerical simulat ion.

It is remarkable t hat t his result does not depend on t he saving funct ion, provided it is increasing and convex. It should be not ed t hat in our inegali- t arian economy, t his rat e does not correspond t o t he individual savings rat es.

T he poor save less and t he rich save much more. But it happens t hat capit al is dist ribut ed mechanically during t he growt h process so t hat t he equilibrium approaches spont aneously t he golden-rule.

However, while it is t rue t hat t he decline in t he proport ion of rich increases t he aggregat e savings rat e and brings t he economy closer t o t he golden-rule, t he t ot al suppression of t he rich reduces t his rat e and drops t he economy in a sit uat ion Paret o-dominat ed by all t he inegalit arian sit uat ions.

In t he case  = 1, t he following graphs represent t he aggregat e savings rat e, t he rat ios of income and capit al between rich and poor as funct ions of t he proport ion of rich2:

(17)

a2

aggregat e savings rat e at equilibrium as a funct ion of a2

a2

rat io of income between rich and poor at equilibrium as a funct ion of a2

(18)

a2

rat io of capit al between rich and poor at equilibrium as a funct ion of a2

T he relat ionship between t he aggregat e savings rat e at equilibrium and t he proport ion of rich is t hus cont rary t o t he immediat e impression t hat wealt h increases savings. T his …nding support s t he idea, suggest ed by K eynes’s quot e (sect ion 4), t hat excessive wealt h creat es poverty. However, it does not advocat e egalit arianism since it also shows t hat a su¢ cient ly small proport ion of rich makes it possible t o approach t he level of savings of t he golden-rule and t o rescue t he economy from egalit arian poverty.

6 T he par adox of t hr ift

What has been called " Keynesian decline" presupposes t hat above a cert ain point , saving plays a count erproduct ive role. T his phenomenon is known as t he

" paradox of t hrift " . According t o [K eynes 1936, Chapt er 23, Sect ion VI I], t he exist ence of t his paradox has been t he subject of cont roversy between econo- mist s. Indeed, it is not easy t o admit t hat abundance can creat e scarcity when one is accust omed t o reasoning in t erms of supply-demand balance.

[Keynes 1936, Chapt er 23, Sect ion VI I] present s t he fable of t he bees of Mandeville where he sought t o explain t he count erproduct ive e¤ect of an excess of savings, as well as t he host ile react ions of some English aut hors of t he 18t h cent ury. St ill according t o [Keynes 1936], cont roversy cont inued in t he 19t h cent ury between Ricardo and Malt hus in t he form of a debat e on t he possibility of a sit uat ion of overproduct ion, which amount s t o a debat e on t he paradox of t hrift . Indeed, if t here is overproduct ion, t here is under-consumpt ion t herefore over-saving. Aft er t he First World War, Hayek and Schumpet er st ood up against

(19)

st ill seem t o be divided. On t he side of t he paradox, we …nd for example [Krugman 2009] and t he sept ic side we …nd [Barro 2000].

In t his sect ion we examine numerically t he relat ionship between t he social propensity t o save and t he average income at equilibrium, t he proport ion of rich being …xed. T he social propensity t o save varies from 08 t o 12. T he proport ion of rich is2= 3%. We obt ain t he following graph for t he equilibrium net income= () ¡ :

social propensity to save net income at equilibrium

income increases with the propensity to save

income decreases with the propensity to save

inequality equality

We observe t hat t here is an opt imal value for t he social propensity t o save

¤ = 1064 (wit h a maximum error of 10¡ 3). T he net equilibrium income for

 = ¤ is t hen  = 11356. T his income is slight ly less t han t he net income of t he golden-rule¤ = 11380. But it is much higher t han t he egalit arian net income for= ¤, which is0(¤) = 10880.

Beyond ¤and before reaching  = 1155 net income declines alt hough t he economy remains in t he inegalit arian and rich part . At  = 1155, t he economy crashes sharply in t he egalit arian and poor area. It looks like t he Marxist t ransit ion from capit alism t o socialism, but wit hout t he class st ruggle!

To recover once in t he egalit arian st ruct ure, it would require a social propensity t o save of about  = 126, what means an increase in aggregat e savings rat e

(20)

from 23% t o 30%. Also observe t hat t he decline in t he inegalit arian sit uat ion begins at (¤) = 11652, whereas in t he egalit arian sit uat ion it begins only when t he economy is overaccumulat ed, i.e. when capit al exceeds t he golden- rule level ¤= 13182

To sum up, if t he social propensity t o save is not very high (less t han¤), t he int roduct ion of a proport ion of rich by 3% makes it possible t o signi…cant ly exceed t he egalit arian net income and t o approach t he net income of t he golden- rule. But t his gain may quickly vanish if t he social propensity t o save increases.

7 Conclusion

T his st udy highlight ed one aspect of t he consequences of inequality on t he macroeconomic relat ionship between savings and income in a basic neoclassical model. Inequality is at t he same t ime useful and harmful. It is useful because it makes it possible t o achieve an aggregat e income out of reach if t he savings of t he majority class is insu¢ cient . It is harmful in t he sense t hat it renders t he economic equilibrium t hat it has achieved fragile. Indeed, t he economy risks a great decline if t he size of t he rich class or t he social propensity t o save exceeds cert ain t hresholds. T his decline is due t o a speci…c art iculat ion between t he rat e of decline in t he product ivity of capit al and t he rat e of increase in t he de- preciat ion of capit al. T he dynamics of such a decline reminds one of Keynes’s descript ion of t he consequences of excess savings in a cont ext of inequality. It is not ewort hy t hat t his decline t akes place in a neoclassical model t hat does not include key Keynesian element s such as sat urat ion of demand, monet izat ion of savings, short -t erm e¤ect s, expect at ion problems, involunt ary unemployment and rigidit ies. It is remarkable t hat t he decline does occur anyway.

T he following direct ions should be furt her explored: t aking int o account t axat ion, t echnical progress, imperfect compet it ion and rent seeking behavior.

R efer ences

[Barro 2000] Barro R.J. (2000), “ Inequalit ies and

Growt h in a Panel of Count ries” , R.J.

Journal of Economic Growt h 5(1) 5-32, doi:10.1023/ A:1009850119329

[Boushey-Hersh 2012] Boushey H., Hersh A.S. (2012), “ T he American Middle Class, Income In- equality and t he St rengt h of Our Econ- omy” , Cent er for American Progress, ht t ps:/ / www.americanprogress.org/ issues/

(21)

economy/ report s/ 2012/ 05/ 17/ 11628/ t he- american-middle-class-income-inequality- and-t he-st rengt h-of-our-economy/

[Bourguignon 1981] Bourguignon F. (1981), “ Paret o-Superiority of Unegalit arian Equilibria in St iglit z’

Model of Wealt h Dist ribut ion Wit h Con- vex Saving Funct ion” , Economet rica, vol.

49, N±6

[Dynan-Skinner-Zeldes 2004] Dynan K.E., Skinner J. , Zeldes S.P. (2004),

“ Do T he Rich Save More?” , Journal of Po- lit ical Economy, vol 112, n±2, 397-444

[Earley 1994] Earley J.S. (1994), “ Schumpet er and

Keynes, Dissimilar T win Revolut ion- ist s” , Hist ory Economics Review, vol 21, issue 1, 21-33, ht t p:/ / dx.doi.org/

10.1080/ 10370196.1994.11733147

[Keynes 1936] Keynes J.M. (1936), " General T heory of Employment , Int erest and Money" , ht t p:/ / cas.umkc.edu/ economics/ peo- ple/ facultypages/ kregel/ courses/ econ645/

wint er2011/ generalt heory.pdf

[Krugman 2009] Krugman P. (2009), “ T he Paradox of T hrift - for Real” , New York T imes 7/ 7/ 2009 [Ost ry-Berg-T sangarides 2014] Ost ry D. J., Berg A., T sangarides C.

G. (2014), “ Redist ribut ion, Inequal- ity and Growt h” , IMF discussion not e, ht t p:/ / www.imf.org/ ext ernal/ pubs/ ft / sdn/

2014/ sdn1402.pdf

[Oxfam report “ Even It Up” 2014] Oxfam report (2014), “ Even It Up” , ht t p:/ / oxfamilibrary.openreposit ory.com/

oxfam/ bit st ream/ 10546/ 333012/ 43/ cr- even-it -up-ext reme-inequality-291014- en.pdf

[Schilcht 1975] Schilcht E. (1975), “ A Neoclassical T heory of Wealt h Dist ribut ion” , Jahrbücher für Na- t ionalökonomie und St at ist ik, 189, 78-96 [St iglit z 1969] St iglit z J. (1969), “ Dist ribut ion of Income

and Wealt h Among Individuals” Economet - rica, 37, 382-3997

(22)

[St iglit z 2011] St iglit z J. (2011), “ To Cure t he Economy” , Project Syndicat e, ht t ps:/ / www.project syndicat e.org/ print / t ocuret heeconomy

[Hayek 1931] Von Hayek F. A. (1931), “ T he Paradox of Saving” , Economica, n±32, 125-169

Referenzen

ÄHNLICHE DOKUMENTE

Die große Chance der naturwissenschaftlichen Fächer in und die erarbeiteten Resultate und Techniken werden der Schule besteht darin, dass naturwissenschaftliche Ar­

The independent, non-governmental Human Rights Commission of Pakistan (HRCP) and Ahmadi community leaders told Human Rights Watch that they had repeatedly brought these threats to

The result, as we shall see, is that the Sunni/Salafi neo-fundamentalists who have pressed these arguments have focused on an ever wider range of religious and sectarian groups who

For the presentation I would start with the Scientific Members of the SIAC, two of whom, emeritus professors of international re- nown, have studied Antiquity through

3 Attempting to balance remedies for many of the grievances of Macedonia’s ethnic Albanian population with the preservation of the state’s territorial integrity,

In October 1994, Senate Resolution 78 and House Resolution 308 urged the Russian Federa- tion “to adhere to the provisions of the agreement initiated on August 10, 1994, to provide for

Following the outbreak of a major Arab revolt against British rule and against Zionism, a Royal Commission, headed by Earl Peel, recommended that Palestine be divided into a

at the same time, the discourse has given relatively little discussion to some proven technologies, particularly dry cask storage, that can provide South Korea ways to manage